Title: Trade Growth and Inequality
1Trade Growth and Inequality
- Professor Christopher BlissHilary Term
2004Fridays 10-11 a.m.
2Ch. 4 Convergence in Practice and Theory
- Cross-section growth empirics starts with Baumol
(1986) - He looks at ß-convergence
- ß-convergence v. s-convergence - Friedman (1992)
- De Long (1988) sampling bias
3Barro and Sala-i-Martin
- World-wide comparative growth
- Near complete coverage (Summers-Heston data)
minimizes sampling bias - Straight test of ß-convergence
- Dependent variable is growth of per-capita income
1960-85 - Correlation coefficient between growth and
lnPCI60 for 117 countries is .227
4Table 4.1 Simple regression result N117
F6.245
5Correlation and Causation
- Correlation is no proof of causation
- BUT
- Absence of correlation is no proof of the absence
of causation - Looking inside growth regressions perfectly
illustrates this last point
6The spurious correlation
- A spurious correlation arises purely by chance
- Assemble 1000 crazy ordered data sets
- That gives nearly half a million pairs of such
variables - Between one such pair there is bound to be a
correlation that by itself will seem to be of
overwhelming statistical significance
7Most correlations encountered in practice are not
spurious
- But they may well not be due to a simple causal
connection - The variables are each correlated causally with
another missing variable - As when the variables are non-stationary and the
missing variable is time
8Two examples of correlating non-stationary
variables
- The beginning econometrics students consumption
functionct a ßyt et - But surely consumption is causally connected to
income - ADt a ßTSt etwhere TS teachers
salaries AD arrests for drunkeness
9Regression analysis and missing variables
- A missing variable plays a part in the DGP and is
correlated with included variables - This is never a problem with Classical Regression
Analysis - Barro would say that the simple regression of
LnPCI60 on per capita growth is biassed by the
exclusion of extra conditioning variables
10Table 4,2 Growth and extra variablesSources
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1985) Barro-Lee data
set
11Table 4.3 Regression resultN 73 F 8.326
R2 .4308
12Table 4.4 Regression with One Conditioning
Variable
13Looking Inside Growth Regressions I
- g is economic growth
- ly is log initial per capita income
- z is another variable of interest, such as I/Y,
which is itself positively correlated with
growth. - All these variables are measured from their
means.
14Inside growth regressions II
- We are interested in a case in which the
regression coefficient of g on ly is near zero or
positive. So we have - vgly0
- where v is the summed products of g and ly
-
15Inside Growth regressions III
- Thus vgly is N times the co-variance between g
and ly. - Now consider the multiple regression
- gßly?ze (3)
-
16Inside Growth Regressions IV
17Inside Growth Regressions V
- So that
- vglYßvgg ?vgz (5)
- Then if vglY 0 and vg gt 0, (5) requires
that either ß or ?, but not both, be negative. If
vglY gt 0 then ß and ? may both be positive, but
they cannot both be negative. One way of
explaining that conclusion is to say that a
finding of ß-convergence with an augmented
regression, despite growth and log initial income
not being negatively correlated, can happen
because the additional variable (or variables on
balance) are positively correlated with initial
income.
18A Growth Regression with one additional variable
19Growth Regression with I/Y
20One additional variable regression
- From (5) and the variance/covariance matrix
above - .00384 .82325ß .05216?
- Now if ? is positive, ß must be negative
- This has happened because the added variable is
positively correlated with g
21Adding the Mystery Ingredient L
- gßly?Le (7)
- The correlation matrix is
22Growth Regression with L
23Correlation and Cause
- The Barro equation is founded in a causal theory
of growth - The equation with L cannot have a causal basis
- What is causality anyway?
- Granger-Sims causality tests. Need time series
data. Shocks to causal variables come first in
time
24Causality and Temporal Ordering
- An alarm clock set to ring just before sunrise
does not cause the sun to rise. - If it can be shown that random shocks to my alarm
setting are significantly correlated with the
time of sunrise, the that is an impressive puzzle - Cause is a (an optional) theory notion
25Convergence Theory
26Solow-Swan Model II
- The model gives convergence in two important
cases - Several isolated economies each with the same
saving share. Only the level of per capita
capital distinguishes economies - There is one integrated capital markets economy
and numerous agents with the same saving rate.
Only the level of per capita capital attained
distinguishes one agnet from another.
27Solow-Swan Model III
- If convergence is conditional on various
additional variables, how precisely do these
variables make their effects felt? - For country I at time t income is
- AiFKi(t),Li(t)
- A measures total factor productivity, so will be
called TFP
28(No Transcript)
29Determinants of the Growth Rate
- The growth rate is larger
- The larger is capitals share
- The larger is the saving share
- The larger is the TFP coefficient
- The smaller is capital per head
- The smaller is the rate of population growth
30Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992)
- 80 of cross section differences in growth rates
can be accounted for via effects 2 and 5 by
themselves - The chief problem for growth empirics is to
disentangle effects 3 and 4
31Convergence The Ramsey Model
- Ramsey (1928) considered a many-agent version of
his model (a MARM) - He looked at steady states and noted the
paradoxical feature that if agents discount
utility at different rates, then all capital will
be owned by agents with the lowest discount rate
32Two different cases
- Just as with the Solow-Swan model the cases are
- Isolated economies each one a version of the same
Ramsey model, with the same utility discount
rate. The level of capital attained at a
particular time distinguishes one economy from
another - One economy with a single unified capital market,
and each agent has the same utility function. The
level of capital attained at a particular time
distinguishes one agent from another
33Isolated Economies
- Chapter 3 has already made clear that there is no
general connection between the level of k and
(1/c)(dc/dt). - The necessary condition for optimal growth is
- -c(du/dc)/u(1/c)(dc/dt)F1k(t),1-r (
20) - Where u is U1c(t)
34Determinants of the Growth of Consumption
- The necessary condition for optimal growth is
- -c(du/dc)/u(1/c)(dc/dt)F1k(t),1-r When
k(t) takes a low value the right-hand side of
(20) is relatively large. If the growth rate of
consumption is not large, the elasticity of
marginal utility - -c(du/dc)/u
- Must be large.
- The idea that ß-convergence follows from optimal
growth theory is suspect.
35Growth in the MARM
- With many agents the optimal growth condition
(20) becomes - -d(du/dc)/dt/uF1Skii(t)),1-r (23)
- In steady state (23) becomes
- F1Skii(t)),1r
- Note the effect of perturbing one agents capital
holding -
36A non-convergence result
- In the MARM
- Non-converging steady states are possible
- Strict asymptotic convergence can never occur
- Partial convergence (or divergence) clubs are
possible depending on the third derivative of the
utility function
37What does a MARM maximize?
- Any MARM equlibrium is the solution to a problem
of the form - Max SN1?08Uci(t)dt
- Non-convergence is hsown despite the assumptions
that - All agents have the same tastes and the same
utility discount rate - All supply the same quantity of labour and earn
the same wage - All have access to the same capital market where
they earn the same rate of return - All have perfect foresight and there are no
stochastic effects to interfere with convergence
38Asymptotic and ß-convergence
- For isolated Ramsey economies we have seen that
we need not have ß-convergence, but we must have
asymptotic convergence - On the other hand we may have ß-convergence
without asymptotic convergence - lnyI aI - b/t2 lnyII aII - b/t1
- aIlt aII
- Country I has the lower income and is always
growing faster
39Strange Accumulation Paths can be Optimal
- In the Mathematical Appendix it is shown that
- Given a standard production function and a
monotonic time path k(t) such that k goes to k,
the Ramsey steady state value, and the implied c
is monotonic, there exists a well-behaved
utility function such that this path is Ramsey
optimal
40Optimal Growth with Random Shocks
- Bliss (2003) discusses the probability density of
income levels when Ramsey-style accumulation is
shocked each period with shocks large on absolute
value - Two intuitive cases illustrate the type of result
available - Low income countries grow slowly, middle income
countries rapidly and rich countries slowly. If
shocks are large poverty and high income form
basins of attraction in which many countries will
be found. Compare Quah (1997) - If shocks are highly asymmetric this will affect
the probability distribution of income levels,
even if the differential equation for income is
linear. Earthquake shocks.
41The BMS Model
- Barro, Mankiw and Sala-i-Martin (1995)
- Human capital added which cannot be used as
collateral - One small country converges on a large world in
steady state (existence is by exhibition). - A more general case is where many small countries
have significant weight. Then if they differ some
may leave the constrained state before others and
poor countries may not be asymptotically
identical
42Concluding Remarks
- There is no simple statistical association
between initial income and subsequent growth,
hence no support for ß-convergence from a basic
two-variable analysis - With multivariate analysis the hypothesis of a
causal connection between initial income and
subsequent growth on an other things equal basis
is not rejected - Theoretical models with common technology often
confirm the ß-convergence hypothesis - Surprisingly the literature neglects catching-up