Title: Energy Security and Climate Change
1Energy Security and Climate Change
Methodologies on risk assessment and cost
estimates of supply disruptions
Anil Markandya Bath, May 12, 2006
2Overview
- Definition of Energy Security and Main Concerns
- Risk Assessment Methodologies
- Assessment of risks (can we define probabilities
of disruption events)? - Estimation of costs of disruption
- Estimation of degree of internalization
- Estimation of risk premium
- Social costs of energy supply disruptions
- Social costs of oil supply disruptions looking
at past shocks - Some quantitative estimates for European Union
- Social costs of electricity shortage qualitative
assessment
- Conclusions and areas for research
3Definition of Energy Security
- Availability of regular supply of energy at a
reasonable price (IEA)
- Physical availability and price dimensions
- Long term and short term dimensions
- Long term will there be enough energy available
at an affordable price? - Short term the unanticipated cut in supply and
sharp increase in price
- Definition suggests that any measure of ES should
be linked to welfare, but measures are not
linked. - We focus here on short term insecurity. Data
analyzed elsewhere suggest that long term supply
is not an issue at global level.
4Measures of Energy Security
- Stress dependence and vulnerability
- Dependence measures include imports of energy and
share of imports in total - Vulnerability measures include
- Days supply of stocks
- Diversity and concentration indices of supply
(e.g. Shannon Weiner Index) - Fuel used per capita, per of GDP
- Indices are monotonically related to welfare
effects of ES, but precise link has not been
established and welfare definition of ES has not
been made
5ES An Important Dimension of Energy Policy
- Measures taken under rationale of ES include
- Maintenance of strategic reserves
- Diversification of sources
- Incentives to reduce imports and increase
domestic production beyond competitive levels - Support for RD to make domestic sources more
competitive - Incentives to increase energy efficiency
- Treaties and use of force to secure supplies
- But theoretical foundations of ES policy remain
weak
6Theoretical Justification for Public Policy on ES
- Individual decisions on production, consumption
and import of energy do not take account of full
social costs (externality) - Disruption of supply has macroeconomic impacts
that individual do not take into account - Producers and importers cannot accommodate the
risks for competitive reasons (e.g. holding of
stocks) - Individuals underestimate the risks of disruption
(We dont know if this is the case)
7Dependence Vulnerability Indicators for OECD
Europe
- The following table derived from WETO, IEA,
US-DEA and IIASA Scenarios, shows a wide
divergence of views on dependence, but more
agreement on supply concentration (increases) and
GDP efficiency (also increases) (() Figures are
only for oil) -
8Overview
- Risk Assessment Methodologies
9Cost of oil disruptions
10Cost of oil disruptions Dimensions of past
shocks
- Typologies of oil disruptions
- Quantity shocks, related to physical constraints
(political and military conflicts, strikes) - Price shocks, related to producers decision
(OPEC) or economic factors (Asian crisis) - Technology shocks, related to new concepts and
ideas, or to new constraints (i.e., an
unanticipated technical advantage of nuclear over
oil with the discovery of the climate change
problem) (rare)
- Dimensions oil disruptions looking at the past
- Magnitude of supply shortfall absolute value (4
mb/d limit value of main shocks, 3.2 mb/d IEA
reference value for Emergency Response System) - Magnitude of supply shortfall relative value
(7 reduction in oil supply, as IEA reference
value for Emergency Response System) - Variation of oil price (increase of 100)
- Duration of shocks (maximum 9 months)
11Cost of oil disruptions Impacts of past shocks
- Factors that affect the magnitude of economic
costs - Capacity to anticipate shocks
- Level and duration of the shortfall (and price
increase) - Response of the oil markets (increase of
production elsewhere, price volatility) - Internal oil production and dimensions of
strategic stocks - Specific characteristics at macroeconomic level
for immediate impacts
- Oil intensity of industrial sectors or transport
sector - Degree of flexibility of the energy sector
(fuel-switching capacity)
- Specific characteristics at macroeconomic level
for indirect impacts
- Monetary and fiscal policies (in order to reduce
inflation) - Level of petroleum products taxation
- Degree of flexibility of labour market
- Specific institutional mechanisms
12Cost of oil disruptions Impacts of past shocks
- Main direct economic impacts of oil disruptions
- Losses of GDP due to general increasing cost of
energy - Losses via negative balance of payments due to
increasing import price - Rise of inflation and interest rates
- Main indirect economic impacts of oil disruptions
- Reduction in tax revenues with an increase in
budget deficit, consequently - Reduction in welfare expenditure and (DIRECT
SOCIAL COST???) - Increase of interest rate (due to rigidities of
government expenditure) - Increase of inflation rate with upward pressure
on nominal wage levels - Higher unemployment (due to wage pressure and
reduced demand) (DIRECT SOCIAL COST???) - Reduced real incomes of consumers (regressive
effects due to short-term inelasticity of oil
demand) (DIRECT SOCIAL COST???)
13Cost of oil disruptions Assessment for EU
- Some estimates of main direct economic impacts of
oil disruptions - Reduction of GDP growth rate with 1-2 years lag
- Negative balance of payments with maximum 1 year
lag - Reduction of negative effects (especially for GDP
growth rate) after 1973 oil shock due to
- More appropriate policy responses
- Consistent reduction of oil consumption (demand
restraint policies)
14Cost of oil disruptions Assessment for EU
- Some estimates of main indirect impacts of oil
disruptions - Increase of inflation rate with 1 year lag
- Increase of unemployment rate with 1-3 years lag
- Progressive reduction of negative effects for
inflation rate - Small progressive increase of unemployment rate
due to
- Structural conditions of European labour market
15Cost of oil disruptions Some general estimates
- Some factors influencing future economic effects
of oil price increase - How far has it been possible to anticipate price
increase? - Elasticity of GDP with respect to oil price for
estimation of economic losses - The higher the elasticity the higher the negative
impacts
- EU estimates an oil price increase of 10 per
barrel would reduce economic growth in the
industrialized countries by 0.5 - IMF estimates an oil price increase of 10 per
barrel would reduce economic growth in the
industrialized countries by 0.6
- Estimates could be substantially different within
different industrialized regions because
elasticity of GDP respect to oil price could be
reduced due to
- Higher oil reserves
- Lower import dependence
16Cost of electricity shortage
17Cost of electricity shortage Impacts of
blackouts
- Factors that affect the magnitude of economic
costs - Extension of the disruption in terms of people
and area affected (and demographic density of the
territory) - Presence of alternative energy sources that could
replace the missing energy - Duration (time) and the continuity of the
disruption - The specific moment of the day (morning,
afternoon, night) - The season, climate factor is very important both
on the consequences side, and on the magnitude of
the disruption (usually summer black outs are
more serious due to air conditioning) - Availability of advance warning and information
(I.e. anticipation of shortage)
18Cost of electricity shortage Impacts of
blackouts
- 1. Expenditure for military, police and emergency
actions (excluding health) - Cost of activating the counter-terrorism machine,
due to lack of immediate warning about black out - Cost for emergency requests to police and public
order forces (arrests, etc.) - Cost for emergencies for fire workers (i.e.,
elevators, closing doors, subway, fires, etc.)
- 2. Expenditures for public transportation
- Costs for public railway due to interruption
reduced revenues, increased emergencies, delays
(both effects on public system and on consumers),
risk of accidents (computers failures in the
traffic system) - Cost for subway interruptions reduced revenues,
increased emergencies, risk of accidents, delays
(both effects on public system and on consumers) - Cost for flights, increased emergencies, delays
(effects on consumers), risk of accidents
19Cost of electricity shortage Impacts of
blackouts
- 3. Health and Sanitary Expenditures
- Immediate costs into sanitary structures
(hospitals, emergencies, laboratories) emergency
surgery, emergency medical-service calls lost of
medicines, organs, blood and analysis (and
experiments) due to reduced refrigerating
capacity (prolonged shortage) - Post blackout health expenditure (for violence,
for intoxications due to fires or food poisoning,
for panic attack, for uncomfortable temperature
inside buildings)
- 4. Sanitation and Waste disposals
- Immediate costs for interruption in sanitation
services and waste disposal, as recycling systems
or composting/incinerator disposals - Further costs due to excessive waste accumulation
into deposits - Possible sanitary costs due reduced capacity of
wastewater treatment disposals
20Cost of electricity shortage Impacts of
blackouts
- Other Public services
- Costs of interruption of classes and lessons into
public schools (and university) - Costs of damaged food losses due to reduced
refrigeration capacity in all public
administrations - Costs for illness (reduced work capacity)
- Cost of loss of leisure time, personal injury,
fear and panic - Costs for interruption of other public
administrative services (Councils, assistance,
etc.) - Losses of museum revenues
- Political fallout
- 6. Human life values
- Costs for deaths (human life value)
- Costs for illness (reduced work capacity)
- Costs for loss of leisure time, personal injury,
fear and panic
21Risk Assessment Some conclusions
- Oil disruption costs are partly macroeconomic and
partly microeconomic
- Should we convert into a single measure?
- In adding up we need to avoid double counting
- In electricity shortage categories overlap
- E.g. Health expenditures and costs of illness
- E.g. Sanitary costs and costs of illness
- In both cases how much of the cost is
internalized? (E.g. via insurance for loss)?
22Risk Assessment Some conclusions
- For both kinds of shocks we should also include
risk aversion
- Calculate expected value of losses as laid out
here - Then add a premium for the aversion society has
to such events
- How to measure this risk aversion?
- Direct questionnaires on HH and enterprises
- Implicit values from government measures to avoid
shocks
23Other Thoughts
- The issue of anticipation is also relevant. Not
all shocks are equally unanticipated. - How to parameterize anticipation?
- How does cost decrease with anticipation?
- What measures can we take to increase level of
anticipation? - The issue of anticipation is also related to the
issue of internalization.
24A Simple Energy Model Under Uncertainty
- To evaluate measures for ES and analyze links
between ES and CC policies we need to put ES into
more of a theoretical framework - The following is a very simple model for ES, in
which social goal is to maximize Expected Utility
of Consumer Surplus generated by energy
consumption - We assume a given probability of disruption and a
consequence that can be translated into a higher
unit cost of energy
25A Simple Energy Model Under Uncertainty
 U(.) Von-Neumann Morgernstern concave utility
function P(x) Inverse demand function for energy
(P(x) lt 0) C(x0) Total cost of domestic energy
(C(x0) gt 0, C(0) lt c1a) c1a Normal cost per unit
of imported energy c1b Cost per unit of imported
energy with disruption x0 Quantity of domestic
energy produced and consumed x1 Quantity of
imported energy produced and consumed 1-p
Probability of a disruption in supply Â
26A Simple Energy Model Under Uncertainty
For an interior solution we have Â
- Equation (1) states that at the optimum the MC of
domestic production equals the consumer price
(I.e. there are no specific subsidies or taxes
on domestic production) - Equation (2) states that the expected marginal
utility from an additional unit of imports is
equal to zero. - The following figure shows how the optimum
compares with a solution that ignores the risk.
X0 is higher and X1 is lower
27A Simple Energy Model Under Uncertainty
MC(x0)
P(x)
Optimal
Domestic Price
c
0
x
x
1
0
x
28A Simple Energy Model Under Uncertainty
- To see how optimal quantities vary with p and the
parameters of the utility and demand functions we
use the following forms
- ß lt 1 (1- ß) is coefficient of relative risk
aversion - µ gt 0, is price elasticity of demand. B gt 0
- a gt 0, b gt 0 are parameters of unit elastic cost
function
29Parameter Values
30Some Results Sensitive to Cost of Disruption
- Even with cost of 1.5 demand is restrained by20
- Total consumption falls further 38, implying
substantial demand restraint - Energy dependence declines substantially Imports
fall 90 - Domestic production increases 48
- Tax on energy goes from 12 to 45
31Results Sensitivity to Probability of Disruption
- With 0.1, demand is restrained 20
- Demand falls by 36, implying substantial demand
restraint - Energy dependence declines substantially
- Imports fall 46
- Domestic production increases 30
- Tax on Imports goes from 20 to 30
32Some Results Sensitivity to Price Elasticity
- Domestic production is unchanged
- Imports increase with elasticity 35 and total
demand increases - Taxes are not sensitive to elasticity
- Total demand is restrained 25 at high elasticity
and 50 at low elasticity
33Some Results Sensitivity to Risk Aversion
- Total varies little with risk aversion in range
considered. - Taxes are not sensitive to aversion coefficient
- Demand is restrained 33 - 35
34Conclusions From the Simple Model
- In all cases demand restraint is a key adjustment
for ES. - To the extent this has not been done, CC policies
that reduce demand will also move us in the right
direction w.r.t. ES - Energy security implies some increase in domestic
production and a reduction in imports relative to
a solution that ignores risks. - But domestic production is not subsidized
35Conclusions From the Simple Model
- A tax is needed to raise domestic prices above
world prices. Tax can vary from 12 to 45 and is
most sensitive to cost of disruption followed by
probability of disruption. Demand elasticity and
risk aversion are not that important. - Domestic output will be increased by having
domestic prices above world prices. Based on
assumed supply elasticity of one output can be
30 higher than in no risk case. Imports can be
as much as 90 lower.
36Implications of Climate Change for ES
- With CC coming as an additional issue, all fossil
energy becomes more expensive as costs of carbon
constraint are translated into higher energy
prices. - For ES, we assume higher energy costs for both
domestic and foreign producers. If tax increase
is same, the adjustment in consumption for ES
reasons becomes smaller, although total tax goes
up gt carbon constraint does some of the work for
ES. Table below is for mean values of all
parameters
37Implications of Climate Change for ES
- With CC, incentives increase for development of
renewable and cost of renewable energy sources
relative to fossil fuel declines. Since renewable
sources are less tradable, CC polices should
reduce ES needs.Table shows what happens if
domestic production is all renewable.
38Implications of ES for Climate Change
- Model shows that ES policy measures should depend
critically on how probability of disruption and
costs of disruption change in the future. On the
cost side we have seen some decline over the
1990s and in this decade. If this continues ES
adjustments will be less gt lower demand
restraint, more imports and less domestic
production. These will all increase carbon
emissions - As far as probability of events is concerned,
there is no clear indication of how things are
changing. Some forecasts show increasing
dependence (see next table), which would imply
greater demand restraint, less imports and more
domestic production. One negative possibility
for CC is increased development of domestic coal
to replace imported oil. - Link between dependence and probability of
disruption have not been modeled. - Following table shows some decrease in
concentration is expected but dependence as of
total energy can go either way.
39Dependence Vulnerability Indicators for OECD
Europe
- The following table derived from WETO, IEA,
US-DEA and IIASA Scenarios, shows a wide
divergence of views on dependence, but more
agreement on supply concentration (increases) and
GDP efficiency (also increases) (() Figures are
only for oil) -
40Further Developments
- Analysis started here is very rudimentary. To
make progress we need to - Model risk and costs more realistically as joint
probability distribution for the two - Take account of measures that reduce costs of
disruption but have a cost themselves (e.g.
holding of stocks) (Stock levels are not
calculated in this way at present) - Integrate ES modeling with CC modeling. Bring in
renewable energy as an explicit option. - Develop links between measures of dependence and
vulnerability and parameters such as risk of
disruption. - Assess more carefully exactly how much ES is an
externality how much of the risk has been
internalized.
41 THANK YOU!
corso Magenta 63 20123 Milano - Italy tel 39
02 5203.6975 fax 39 02 5203.6946 web http/
/www.feem.it