Title: Labor Markets, Globalization and Poverty
1Labor Markets, Globalization and Poverty
- Ann Harrison
- UC Berkeley and NBER
- World Bank
- March 23, 2006
2Two Issues Addressed Today
- Labor market policies affect the linkages between
globalization and poverty - Trade reforms what impact on the poor?
- Labor markets determine HOW reforms affect the
poor - Direct labor market interventions and their
impact on wages and employment - Labor market interventions (minimum wages)
- Anti-sweatshop movements
3Issue 1
- What is the relationship between globalization
and poverty? - How do labor market institutions affect that
relationship?
4First issue addressed by forthcoming NBER study
under my direction
- Definition of globalization
- trade (tariffs/trade shares)
- capital flows (foreign investment, aid, capital
flows) - 15 papers
- Theory (from Globalization to Poverty)
- Cross-country evidence
- Country case studies based on micro data
- Concerns of globalizations critics (Aisbett)
- Policy Implications
- See Globalization and Poverty, University of
Chicago Press, available on the web at
www.nber.org/books/glob-pov
5Country Case Studies Using Household Data
- India (Topalova)
- Colombia (Goldberg and Pavcnik)
- Ethiopia (McMillan and Levinsohn)
- Mexico (Ashraf, McMillan, Peterson-Zwane Hanson)
- Zambia (Balat and Porto)
- South Africa (Levinsohn)
- China (Ligon)
- Poland (Goh and Smarzynska)
- Indonesia (Thomas)
6Key Results from Case Studies
- Simple conclusions misleading
- Heterogeneity in responses
- BUT generally true that poor in expanding sectors
gain - Poor in previously protected sectors lose
- Financial Integration DFI and Aid help the poor,
while currency crises hurt the poor - Bundling trade reform with complementary policies
is key
7Why are conclusions based on HO models wrong?
- HO Orthodox view in countries with a
comparative advantage in exporting
unskilled-intensive goods, unskilled or poor will
gain more from trade than skilled workers (Anne
Krueger, Jagdish Bhagwati) - Why is this framework incorrect? Violation of
assumptions behind the Heckscher-Ohlin model - Workers cannot easily relocate to expanding
sectors - Countries protect sectors more that use unskilled
labor - Exporters/foreign firms use skilled labor even in
unskilled-labor rich countries - Getting goods produced by poor (or using their
labor) to global markets requires many
complementary policies (infrastructure, human
capital development etc)
8What do we mean by heterogeneity in responses ?
- Mexico large corn farmers gain, small corn
farmers lose (from US corn imports) - India tariff reductions associated with slower
rate of poverty reduction BUT - Only true in regions with restrictive labor laws
- No impact on poverty reduction in regions with
mobile labor
9BUT generally true that poor in expanding sectors
gain
- Unskilled in countries with a comparative
advantage in exporting unskilled intensive goods
to rich countries (Poland) - Poor wage earners in sectors receiving DFI
(Mexico, India, Poland) - Poor wage earners in sectors with export growth
10Poor in previously protected sectors lose
- The poor in urban sectors with tariff reductions
(Colombia) - Small farmers competing with higher imports
(small corn farmers in Mexico) - Rural agricultural labor restricted from
relocating due to rigid labor laws (India)
11Lack of labor mobility documented in these
studies suggests poor may lose from trade
liberalization
- Fact that poor in expanding sectors gain (export
sectors) and poor in contracting sectors lose
(importing sectors) suggests that - Traditional trade models which suggest that labor
gains from trade liberalization in poor countries
are inappropriate - Right model is specific sector model
- Lack of labor mobility is critical for
understanding impact of trade reform on the poor.
12Two Illustrative Case Studies (see www.nber.org)
- India and Colombia
- Outcomes different poverty and inequality
measures - Policy focus trade reforms
- Results trade reforms only hurt the poor IF
labor markets are inflexible
13Study on India (Petia Topalova)
- Regress district level outcome on a
district-level measure of trade exposure, defined
as the average of industry-level tariffs weighted
by the workers employed in that industry in 1991 - Ydt a bTariffdt cFDIreforms dt ed
edt - Outcomes Ydt include proportion of population
below poverty line, poverty gap, and inequality. - Author finds negative and significant coefficient
b, implying tariff declines increase poverty in
rural areas - BUT negative coefficient on tariffs ONLY in
regions with inflexible labor markets. - Coefficient on FDI lt 0, implying FDI helps the
poor.
14Study on Colombia (Penny Goldberg and Nina
Pavcnik)
- Use household data
- They measure the impact of changes in
globalization (measured as tariffs or imports and
exports) on the following outcomes for urban
workers - Movements into the informal market
- Poverty incidence
- Skilled-unskilled wage gap
- Unemployment
15Typical estimating equation
- Outcome aTAR ßTARLABREG µZ
- Outcome unemployment/informality/ poverty
- TAR tariff in sector where individual
employed, instrumented using initial
period tariffs. - LABREG Extent of labor regulations
- Z Age, experience, education
16Results for Colombia (Goldberg and Pavcnik)
- Tariff Protection associated with less
informality, less poverty, less unemployment - Import competition associated with more
informality, more poverty - Export activity associated with less
informality, less poverty
17Goldberg and Pavcniks approach to labor markets
and poverty
- Allow impact of tariffs (or import penetration
and export activity) to vary depending on labor
market regulations - Tariffs only protect workers from informality
prior to the reforms - After the labor reforms, export activity has a
bigger positive impact in moving workers out of
the informal sector - Importance of interaction term (TARLABREG)
suggests that relationship between globalization
and labor market outcomes depend on labor
institutions
18Policy Implications of NBER Study
- Bundling trade reforms with complementary
policies more likely to produce gains for the
poor - Lack of labor mobility impedes adjustment
- Lack of complementary inputs inhibits movement
from subsistence agriculture to cash crops for
export - Lack of domestic institutions, rule of law,
capital market development restricts gains from
access to international capital markets - Since poor in import competing sectors lose from
trade reform, income support programs needed - Since poor in export sectors gain, access to
developed country markets is critical
19Issue 2
- What about direct labor market interventions to
combat poverty? (minimum wages, anti-sweatshop
movements) - Is there a trade-off between wage gains and
unemployment?
20Indonesian Case Study
- In Indonesia, US threats to withdraw GSP status
due to violations of worker rights led to
enormous minimum wage increases (800 percent)
during the1990s. - The anti-sweatshop campaign against Nike
- targeted the lowest paid workers
- Measuring the impacts wages versus employment
21Methodology to Identify Impact of US-mandated
minimum wage increases and anti-sweatshop
campaigns in Indonesia
- Minimum wage effects use regional variation in
minimum wages - Anti-sweatshop campaigns compare sectors
(textiles and apparel) and regions where targeted
firms (Nike) operated relative to others. - Econometric techniques
- Difference in differences
- Matching estimators
22Approach
- Wi96 Wi90 a1MinWAGErit
- a2ACTIVISMi,1990 a3 Zit ?r eit
- W wage or employment changes in logs
- MinWage minwager,96 minwager,1990 in logs
- Activism anti-sweatshop activity in region
- Z worker and/or plant controls
- i,r,t plant i in region r at time t
- ?r Region controls
23Results on Indonesian Case Study
- Minimum wage increase associated with 35 percent
increase in production worker wages suggests US
threats to eliminate GSP effective. - Anti-sweatshop activism successful Exporting
and foreign textiles and footwear producers
increased wages 20 to 25 percent faster than
others - Upward pressure on wages generated through
anti-sweatshop campaigns did NOT affect
employment - BUT minimum wage increases cut employment by 10
- Anti-sweatshop activism also associated with
falling profits, investment, some reduced entry,
greater exit - Suggests costs to intervention, but
anti-sweatshop campaigns probably a better
approach
24Conclusions
- Orthodox prescriptions claiming that poor gain
from trade reforms are misleading because workers
cannot easily relocate from contracting to
expanding sectors. - Specific sector modelwhich assumes that workers
are stuck in the short run--is more realistic,
at least according to case studies in my
forthcoming NBER study. - Poor in expanding sectors gain and poor in
contracting (import-competing) sectors
loselargely a consequence of labor immobility - While some forms of labor market interventions
are costly in terms of foregone employment
(minimum wages) other types of interventions
(such as anti-sweatshop campaigns) have led to
improved working conditions and pay
25Issues for Further Study
- Which type of labor market interventions help the
poor? (Right to organize, anti-sweatshop
campaigns) - Which labor market interventions hurt the poor?
(entry and exit barriers, minimum wages) - Which complementary policies are most critical
for ensuring that trade reforms help the poor?