Title: The costs of mitigating climate change from macroeconomic models
1The costs of mitigating climate change from
macroeconomic models
A day-long forum cosponsored by the International
Council for Capital Formation and FORATOM on Do
Current Climate Policy Models Measure the Real
Cost of Emission Reductions?, 26 November, 2003,
Brussels
- Terry Barker
- University of Cambridge and Cambridge
Econometrics
2Outline
- Approach to costs what type of model is used,
what policies are simulated and what policies are
implemented? - Outline
- What are the costs?
- Types of models used
- Factors affecting the cost estimates
- Conclusions
3What are the costs?
- Costs not observable from market prices because
- outcome of complex E3 interactions
- involve changes in environment that have no
market valuations - Macroeconomic costs are usually measured in terms
of future loss of GDP, comparing one hypothetical
state of the world with another - Costs include loss of fossil fuels output and
employment, and short-term costs, e.g. from any
premature retiring of fossil fuel burning power
plant - Such costs may be offset by ancillary benefits
and benefits from use of tax or emission permit
revenues - but
- taxes/auctioned permits may incur high
political costs - free allocation of emission permits (as in phase
I EU emissions trading scheme (ETS)) yields no
revenues to recycle
4Assessing the costs of mitigation
- Need to understand types of models used
- energy sector models with no impact on rest of
economy - general equilibrium models that provide
century-long time horizons but with rigid and
implausible economic structures - macro econometric E3 models which track the
economy-wide adjustment process to new policies - And what types of cost impacts are estimated
- cost-reducing government policies (e.g. many EC
studies, WRI study for US) - costs to business (e.g. EMF-16 studies)
- both (e.g. EIA study for US Congress)
5Some cost of mitigation estimates
- Government estimates
- UK White Paper (2003) on low-carbon economy 2050
0.5 to 2 GDP for a 60 cut in CO2 an example of
energy-sector modelling - US Administration Kyoto would cost 4 GDP an
example of a macro econometric E3 model analysis
6A key element short-term costs of adjustment
- Rapid, unplanned and unexpected adjustment is
likely to be more costly than slow, planned and
expected change - eg coal-fired power stations are closed before
end of working lives - EIA study assumes that the US economy has to
reduce CO2 emisisons by over 30 over 4 years - the -4.2 GDP effect for 2010 reduces to -0.8GDP
by 2020, with more time to adjust and with the
Kyoto target continued to 2020 - the EMF-16 studies assume adjustment usually from
2000 - not much research on time for adjustment, but one
study found a 25 reduction in carbon tax rate
for US ratification in 2000 rather than 2005
7Ancillary benefits of GHG mitigation
- The literature acknowledges that they may exist
and may be comparable to costs of mitigation - EU studies find substantial benefits for the US,
WRI finds that inclusion of the benefits is
important (1.1pp of GDP) but EIA and EMF studies
do not include these benefits. (EIA estimates a
77 reduction in coal consumption by 2010 13
in oil products for the 31 reduction in CO2
emissions) - A conservative estimate of the value of the
implied reduction in damages - for the EU is 0.1 GDP for a 2 reduction in CO2
and - for the US is 0.4 GDP for a 30 reduction in CO2
- However, most ancillary benefits are off-line
calculations done outside the macroeconomic
modelling framework.
8The effects of recycling revenues
- If a general equilibrium optimum is assumed
initially, then a carbon tax (with lump-sum
recycling) will move the economy from the
optimum, and reduce welfare - The revenue-raising GHG mitigation policy has a
potential benefit as an opportunity for reform of
the tax system many EU studies find that
recycling leads to increases in GDP - however, the EU emissions trading system is not
economy-wide and is not a full auction system. - In EIA US study using revenues to reduce
employers social security contributions, the
4.2 GDP cost by 2010 falls to 1.9 - the permit revenues give the option for improving
the tax system, but this may not be taken and the
revenues may be wasted.
9Conclusions for low-cost mitigation in the EU by
2008-12
- From 2008, new eastern EU members will further
modernise their energy sectors via ETS - Substantial use of coal that can be easily and
efficiently replaced by gas - Ancillary benefits available
- ETS with free allocation will have effects
depending price of allowances and use of higher
profits by the power sector - if used for new power generation, GDP may be
higher - if distributed as dividends, GDP is likely to be
lower
10Kyoto and the US economy(effects on GDP in for
-30CO2)
- effects by 2010 EIA EMF-16 WRI
- date of study (1998) (1999) (1997)
- models covered 1 7 16
- no Annex I permit trade -4.2
- non-CO2sinks 0.7
- revenue recycling 1.9
- ancillary benefits 0.4
- total of above (no trade) -1.2
- total with permit trade
-0.7 0.8 0.3 - (total with permit trade for 2020) -0.1
note denotes that the estimate includes
additional information not in original
study. Source http//www.econ.cam.ac.uk/dae/peopl
e/barker/v3ej_k.pdf
11Conclusions on the costs of mitigation
- Overall conclusion the high-cost estimates in
the literature of mitigation action through
market-based instruments demonstrate - the costs of making policy mistakes (too hasty
action or ill-advised use of permit revenues) - costs of not using the Kyoto flexibilities for
sinks, non-CO2 gases and international permit
trading - how selection of worst-case assumptions can
accumulate to lead to high costs - Costs are likely to be insignificant, or even
negative provided policies are expected,
long-term and well-designed - ie market-based with revenues recycled to reduce
burdensome taxes