Title: Chapter 2: Gains from Trade
1Chapter 2 Gains from Trade
- Keith Head
- Sauder School of Business
2Objectives of this chapter
- Illustrate the gains from trade based on
exploiting comparative advantage - Show how productivity, wages, competitive
advantage, and exchange rates relate to each
other. - Illustrate the gains from trade based on
exploiting plant-level scale economies.
3Your assignment
- Decide the number of workers in each of two
factories (Korea Thailand) to allocate to each
of two activities (molding soles stitching
uppers). - Maximize corporate shoe output
4Shoe terms
Upper
Sole
5Assumptions
- 450 workers in Thai factory
- 300 workers in Korean factory
- In the short run, you cannot add or subtract
workers, or move them between plants. - One sole and one upper needed for each finished
shoe. - Transport costs are negligible
6Productivity Matrix
7Compute total shoe output for
- Plan A (self-sufficient factories) Each country
combines workers to produce completed shoes.
There is no trade. - Plan B
- Thailand produces only uppers,
- Korea produces soles and uppers.
- Plan C
- Korea produces only uppers,
- Thailand produces soles and uppers.
8Plan A (self-sufficient factories)
- Thailand US ? 10Lu 20(450-Lu)
- Lu 300, Ls 150, output 3000
- Korea US ? 15Lu 45(300-Lu)
- Lu 225 Ls 75, output 3375
- Combined output 6375 shoes
- 6375/750 8.5 shoes per worker
9Plan B Thailand specializes in uppers
- Thailand Lu 450 ? 4500 uppers
- Korea US ? 4500 15Lu 45(300-Lu)
- Lu 150 ? 2250 U, Ls 150? 6750S
- Combined output 6750 shoes
- 4500 shoes stitched in Thailand using soles
imported from Korea - PLUS 2250 finished shoes made in Korea
- Productivity 9 shoes per worker
10Plan C Korea specializes in Uppers
- Korea Lu 300 ? 4500 uppers
- Thailand US ? 450010Lu20(450-Lu)
- Lu 150 ? 1500 U, Ls300 ? 6000 S
- Combined output 6000 shoes
- 4500 shoes stitched in Korea using soles
imported from Thailand - PLUS 1500 finished shoes made in Thailand
- Productivity 6000/750 8 shoes/worker
11Plan B increases shoe output by 6
- Firm-level productivity rises 8.5 to 9 shoes per
day - Output growth
- (6750-6375)/6375 .06
- No new machinery, no new skills, no extra effort.
- Trade is like a new technology!
12Specialization is not enough
- Plan C, involves specialization but it lowers
output by 6 relative to Plan A. - Specialization based on comparative advantage
yields gains from trade. - Comparative advantage low opportunity costs.
- CA gains matching process
13Opportunity cost calculations
- Opportunity cost of uppers in foregone soles
- Thailand 20 S/ 10 U 2 S/U
- Korea 45S/15U 3 S/U
- Opportunity cost of soles in foregone uppers
- Thailand 10 U/ 20 S 0.5 U/S
- Korea 15U/45S 0.33 U/S
- Korea has lower opportunity cost of seouls!
14Beyond Guess Check general method
- Determine comparative advantage via opportunity
cost calculation (T-U, K-S) - Check if complete specialization is possible
compare prody in CA task X factory size for
each factory - T 10 X 4504500, K 45 X 300 13500
- So, Thai factory is too small (it needs 1350 or
more) - If no, then the too small factory fully
specializes in its CA task but the too big
factory will partially specialize - Supply from too small non-CA supply from too
big CA supply from too big - 10 X 450 15 X L 45 (300-L)
15Long run decisions
- The level of employment is only fixed in each
plant in the short run. - When employment is a decision variable, not a
sunk cost, then wages and productivity matter.
16Calculate the critical wages
- If wages were equal, Koreas factory would be the
low cost source for both uppers and soles. (Why?
AA) - How low would Thai wages have to be justify
operating the plant? (doing what?) - How low would the wage in Thailand have to be to
justify shutting the Korean plant? - Draw the Korean relative wage line.
17Competitive advantage
- A factory has a competitive advantage in a task
when it can provide an equivalent product at a
lower monetary cost than alternatives. - Competitive advantage here corresponds to lower
unit labour costs. - Unit labour costs are given by wages divided by
productivity.
18Unit Labour Costs (in baht/unit)
WK wages in Korea (won/worker) WT wages in
Thailand (baht/worker)
e exchange rate (baht/won)
19Thai plant gains competitive advantage
- in uppers when Korea pays 50 more than the Thai
wage - e WK/15 WT/10
- eWK/WT 1.5
- in soles when Korea pays 2.25 times the Thai
wage - e WK/45 WT/20
- eWK/WT 2.25
20Competitive Advantage Equilibrium Exchange
Rates
- Suppose that unions or government fix the local
currency values of wages at WK 100 Won/day and
WT 200 Baht/day. - What values of e (in Baht/Won) would be
consistent with equilibrium (green zone)? - How would the e range change if Thai productivity
doubled in all activities?
21Exchange rate zones
- Recall the green zone for the relative wage
- 1.5
- Now set Wk/Wt 100/200 1/2,
- 1.5
- To simplify, just multiply everywhere by 2, we
get - 3
- If productivity in Thailand doubles, then we need
to divide 1.5 and 2.25 by two, so the new range
is - .75
- Substitute in Wk/Wt 100/200 1/2 as before and
multiply by 2 across the board, to get - 1.5
- Baht/Won must declinewon depreciates, baht
appreciates
22Lessons from the Shoe Story
- Making sense of the 1997-8 Asian exchange rate
crisis. - Average levels of productivity in the traded
goods sector determine wages. - Low wage countries are also low-productivity
- Rising productivity leads to appreciation
- Low wage countries do not steal all
industriesonly the ones where their productivity
gap is less than the wage gap.
23Shoe Story II Returns to Scale
- Comparative advantage is not the only way to
obtain gains from trade. - Plant-level economies of scale (PLEoS) are
important in many industries. - To illustrate the gains from exploiting PLEoS
through trade, we revise the story to exclude
comparative advantage and absolute advantage.
24New Productivity Matrix
25Indivisible Overhead
- Factory workers are supported by services of
non-production employees, also known as
overhead - Accounting
- Logistics and input procurement
- Machinery maintenance
- Some minimum number of overhead workers are
required for any positive level of production.
26New example
- 300 workers at each factory
- Let overhead be 30 workers per product (soles
or uppers) per plant. - A factory that produces both products (that is, a
factory that is not fully specialized) has
overhead of 3030 60, leaving 300-60240 workers
for production. - A factory that specializes has 300-30270 workers
for production.
27Plan A vs Plan B revisited
- Plan A (self-sufficiency)
- Sole output in each factory (240/2)10 1200
- Upper output in each factory (240/2)10 1200
- Combined output 120012002400 shoes
28Revisiting Plan B
- Plan B (full specialization, K?S,T?U)
- Sole output in Korea 27010 2700
- Upper output in Thailand 27010 2700
- Combined output 2700 shoes (11 gain!)
29PLEoS gains are different from CA gains
- Plan C (full specialization K?U and T?S) is just
as good (2700 shoes) as plan B - No such thing as specializing in the wrong
thing in this case. - The key for PLEoS is to avoid duplicative
overhead, rather than to match products with
skills (as in the CA case)
30PLEoS vs CA (contd)
- In the long run, only one plant stays open
(whichever has lower ULC) - Under PLEoS, increases in total production
increase productivity, whether or not factories
are specialized. - Under CA, changing scale of plants doesnt help
unless you change the mix of activities done in
each. - Under CA, observe larger plant to be less
productive.
31Gains from Trade Summary
- When relative productivities of two tasks
(uppers, soles) differ across locations, there
are CA gains. - When there is indivisible overhead (or other
PLEoS), concentrating activities in one location
helps. - Next question what is the ultimate source of
opportunity costs diffs?