Title: Governance, Multilevel Governance and Europeanization
1Governance, Multilevel Governance and
Europeanization
European Social Policy Course4 May 2009 J. R.
Grote
2Governance
- Where does it come from?
- What does it mean?
- How has been conceptualized?
- What are the nain types?
- Which are the scientific disciplines devoted to
its study? - Is there something like an overall definition
that would be shared by everybody? - What are its pre-requisites and what its
obstacles? - What is it expected to achieve?
3 Worldwide governance indicators
- The most widely diffused notion of the
governance term is probably the various
governance indices produced by international
organizations to measure the performance and
development capacity of countries in the first,
the second and the third world. The aim is, in
most cases, to arrive at something being called
good governance. - Most of these studies make use of compound
indices whose number, in principle, is unlimited.
For example - Gross Domestic Product
- Levels of Poverty
- Levels of Education
- Government effectiveness
- Rule of law
- Political stability and so forth
- Whether this really adds up to reflect
governance and governance capity is questionable.
Yet, at least, it provides for interesting
comparative information that has not been
available in previous periods - Â
-
4Control of corruption 2007
Political stability 2007
Voice and accountability 2007
5Government effectiveness 2007
Rule of law 2007
Regulatory quality 2007
6Governance design or emergence?
- Governance is a method/mechanism for dealing with
a broad range of problems or conflicts in which
actors regularly arrive at mutually satisfactory
and binding decisions by negotiating with each
other and cooperating in the implementation of
these decisions. - Governance as institutional cybernetics or
governance as an emergent phenomenon that
develops behind the backs of the people.
Governance as a quasi-natural response to
increasing problems of coping with complexity in
politics, in technology, in social life, etc.
Governance as a self-equlibrating process.
7John Stuart Mill, 1862. Considerations on
Representative Government. New York Harper
Brothers.
- Central question To what extent are forms of
government a matter of choice? -
-
- All speculations concerning forms of government
bear the impress, more or less exclusive, of two
conflicting theories respecting political
institutions or, to speak more properly,
conflicting conceptions of what political
institutions are. By some minds, government is
conceived as strictly a practical art, giving
rise to no questions but those of means and an
end. Forms of government are assimilated to any
other expedients for the attainment of human
objects. They are regarded as wholly an affair of
invention and contrivance. Being made by man, it
is assumed that man has the choice either to make
them or not, and how or on what pattern they
shall be made. () To find the best form of
government, to persuade others that it is the
best and, having done so, to stir them up to
insist on having it, is the order of ideas in the
minds of those who adopt this view of political
philosophy. They look upon a constitution in the
same light (difference of scale being allowed
for) as they would upon a steam plow or a
threshing machine.
8- To these stand opposed another kind of political
reasoners, who are so far from assimilating a
form of government to a machine that they regard
it as a sort of spontaneous product, and the
science of government as a branch (so to speak)
of natural history. According to them, forms of
government are not a matter of choice. We must
take them, in the main, as we find them.
Governments can not be constructed by
premeditated design. They are not made, but
grow. Our business with them, as with the other
facts of the universe, is to acquaint ourselves
with their natural properties, and adapt
ourselves to them. The fundamental political
institutions of a people are considered by this
school as a sort of organic growth from the
nature of life of that people a product of their
habits, instincts, and unconscious wants and
desires, scarcely at all of their deliberate
purposes. Their will has had no part in the
matter but that of meeting the necessities of the
moment by the contrivances of the moment (). It
is difficult to decide which of these doctrines
would be the most absurd, if we suppose either of
them held as an exclusive theory. But, though
each side greatly exaggerates its own theory, out
of opposition to the other, and no one holds
without modification to either, the two doctrines
correspond to a deep-seated difference between
two modes of thought and though it is evident
that neither of these is entirely in the right,
yet it being equally evident that neither is
wholly in the wrong, we must endeavour to get
down to what is at the root of each, and avail
ourselves of the amount of truth which exists in
either.
9- Governance in the economy and in industrial
sectors
10The variety of mechanisms for the governance of
sectorsby P.C. Schmitter
- Up to now, scholars have emphasized the
importance of simple dichotomies - Charles Lindblom Market and State
- Oliver Williamson Hierarchy and Market
- Hybrid forms may exist according to these
authors, but they are regarded as intrinsically
unstable - Schmitter argues that there are many of such
hybrids and that they may be more stable than
suggested by the standard literature - Alliances
- Networks
11- Figure 1 distinguishes between
- a vertical axis two generic types of exchange)
and a - horizontal axis three means of enforcing
whatever mechanism comes about) - The figure generates six partially overlapping
boxes - Markets spontaneously equilibrating (unvisible
hand), - Hierarchies based on enforcement mechanisms
(guarantee of property rights) which can be
internalized within a company, - Communities self-equilibrating (normative
consensus among their members), - States (or public hierarchies) external units of
enforcement par excellence and have a sovreign
status - Alliances
- Networks.
12 Fig. 1 The governance of economic sectors
13- Governance in politics and society
14- However, the problem can also be addressed from
the more encompassing perspective of Overall
Modes of Societal Order in modern societies and
nation states. - Several of such modes have been said to exist
and are frequently addressed by different social
science disciplines - - The Market
- - The State
- - The Society
- While state and market are generally accepted as
ordering mechanisms by virtually all scholars, it
happens that some use the notion of Civil Society
(rather than just society) while others insert
Networks into the menu of orders. Others again
have suggested that the market and the state are
complemented by the Community as a third and the
Association as a forth mode of societal order. - Independently from what is ultimately prefered,
the most important thing is that, to speak of
governance, these orders need to overlap to some
extent thus partly complementing and partly
contradicting each other.
15Is Governance able of solving the problems
resulting from the incompatibility or
complementarity of different types of orders?
(from Streeck/Schmitters essay on PIGs)
- Modern societies, polities and economies can
only be analyzed in terms of a specific mix of
these institutions and principles. Each of them
can in principle undermine but also strengthen
the existence of adjacent institutions and
principles. - Communities can undermine markets (informal
collusion, clientelist arrangments) but can also
encourage mutual confidence and good faith
necessary for stable economic exchange. - Markets can decompose community bonds and erode
common values but can also provide for
opportunities for extended reproduction.
16- State intervention can distort markets but can
also provide for a legal framework that guides
and makes economic exchange viable. - Free contracts and competition may contradict
state policies but even the most etatist state
requires markets as a supplementary mechanism of
allocation. - State growth and government intervention may lead
to a disintegration of communities but, at the
same time, communities without a state would
always be in danger of losing their identity and
independence. - Communitarian tribalism can frustrate the
development of a stable nation state while, at
the same time, a state without some degree of
spontaneous solidarity among its citizens is no
more than a bureacratic or military conspiracy.
17While until this point, hardly anybody would have
a problem with the description of virtues and
vices of these three modes of societal order,
Streeck and Schmiiter are convinced that there is
a forth mode which has so far been largely
neglected
-
- Streeck and Schmitter introduce an additional
and distinct institution (including these
institutions guiding principles) which they call
Association. - Association is more than a transient amalgam
of the three other orders and is capable of
making a lasting and autonomous contribution to
rendering the behaviour of social actors
reciprocally adjustive and predictable. The
guiding principle of interaction and allocation
of this mode of societal governance is
organizational concertation. - But let us have a look at the other principles
as well -
18Three or four modes of societal order
Communities, Markets, States and Associations?
Communities Markets States Associative order (PIG)
Coordination Spontaneous solidarity Dispersed competition Hierarchical control Intra/ inter-organizational Concertation
Main actors Families Firms/ parties Bureaucratic agencies Associations, movements
Entry conditions Ascriptive member status Abiltiy to pay, eligibility to vote Legal authorization Capacity to disrupt and compromise
Exchange medium Esteem Money/ votes Coercion Mutual recognition
Exchange product Compacts Contracts/ political positions Regulation Pacts
Resources Trust, respect Pol. and econ. entrepreneurship Legitimate control Guaranteed access
Motives of actors Esteem of followers Profit/ electoral victory Careers, bureaucratic stability Organizational development
Cleavages Natives vs. foreigners Sellers vs. buyers, parties vs. voters Rulers vs. ruled Members vs. leaders vs. state interlocutors
Pay-offs Mutual affection, collective identity Material prosperity, citizen accountability (External) security Social peace
19- Both in practice (empirical manifestations of
it) and in theory (analytical reflection on it),
governance needs to be/ can be - - approached from (at least) three
analytical angles in a simultaneous fashion. - - understood in terms of an emergent
phenomenon that tends to develop
everywhere within a given political system and
tends to achieve equilibrium points which
reflect highly specific situations in
political, societal and in economic terms - - understood in terms of deliberate design.
i.e. as a program or strategy elaborated by
political practitioners and political analysts
20The number of potential hybrids and of their
concrete overlap areas is in principle unlimited
S
M
A
C
Communitarian markets, New Public Management,
social economy, associative democracy,
public-private partnerships, etc.
21Scientific order and disorder
In a situation where everything overlaps and
depends on each other, the established
disciplines dealing with these systems might run
into problems. It is today hardly imaginable that
any single of these disciplines will be able to
dealing with the complexity characterizing any
single of their analytical targets. Hence the
need for inter-disciplinary research!
22Governance as network
23There is of course also a network component
involved in discussions of governance. Imagine
the people represented below were political
institutions, organizations and different
organizational layers that are formally divided
by specific tasks and duties (e.g. the president,
ministerial offices, and public and private
organizations attached to these offices).
24Rectangular matrix of advise relations (14 x 14)
director
head of division
book-keeper
secretaries
To whom do you turn with questions relevant to
your work? orTo whom do you turn for
information of strategic importance?
25Simple network graph
26Status analysis
27Status indices
secretaryhead of divisiondirectorhead of
division head of division secretarysecretarybook
keeperbook keeper book keeper book keeper book
keeper book keeper book keeper book
keeper secretary
head of division
28Governanceby Anne Mette Kjaer
- On paradigm shifts and the meanings of
governance - GOV in Public Administration/ Public Policy
- GOV in International Relations
- European GOV (and MLG)
- GOV in Comparative Politics and economic
development - GOV in Processes of Democratization and
Transition - GOV and the World Bank
29I. Paradigm shift in public policies
- From hierarchy, sub-ordination and top-down
control - towards
- Policy networks
- network management, self-organizing networks
- Meta-governance
- Managing the rules (of formulation,
decision-making and implementation) and
coordinating them across policy domains - Coordinating the plurality of hierarchies,
markets and networks across domains
30II. Paradigm shift in international relations
- From the neo-realist assumption of states as the
most important actors in world politics - versus
- a growing importance of multinational actors and
transnational networks - a growing importance of international regimes
31III. Paradigm shift in European integration
studies
- From a focus on European integration and
institutions (as the explanandum) - towards
- a focus on EU policy-making,
- its effects on domestic policies and
- on the management of complex inter-relationships
in policy-making across all levels (subnational,
domestic, supranational)
32IV. Paradigm shift in political economy
- From the neo-liberal position (the state should
have no role at all and leave development to the
market) - towards
- a heterarchic conception of governance as the
management of self-organizing networks that
involve a plurality of organizational forms such
as the state, the market or networks
33V. Paradigm shift in democratization/ transition
research
- From modernization and early transition theories
(determinism and presumption of the existence
of only one single path-way of development
towards democracy) - towards
- institutional governance approaches
- that allow for a more open-ended vision
- and argue that institutions circumscribe
political agency in as much as agents themselves
are capable of altering institutions
34VI. Paradigm shift in the international economy
- From a selective policy followed by the World
Bank (granting help to those that already have
good governance) - towards
- a critique of the WBs dependency on its largest
shareholder (the US) - a focus on accountability versus a global public
35Governance and political design
36Attributive requisites of governance
arrangements (from PC Schmitter, 2002)
- a. List of potential pro-governance policies
supported and implemented by public authorities -
- b. List of necessary attributes on the part of
(organized) civil society - c. List of principles for the chartering,
composition and decision-rules of governance
arrangements
37I. Pro-governance policies
- 1. freedom of association, petition and assembly
- 2. legal recognition
- 3. special fiscal treatment
- 4. arenas for functional representation
- 5. guarantees of access to decision-making
- 6. protection from non-intromission in internal
affairs - 7. subsidization with public funds
- 8. obligatory membership and/ or member
contributions - 9. legal extension of contracts
- 10. devolved responsibility for policy
implementation
38II. Attributes of (organized) civil society
- 1. class, sectoral, professional or corporate
consciousness - 2. voluntarism
- 3. moral sentiments
- 4. sociability
- 5. trust
- 6. altruism or other-regardingness
- 7. universalism
- 8. sense of personal efficacy
- 9. organizational skills
39III. Principles for the chartering, the
composition and the decision-rules of Governance
Arrangements
a) Chartering
- 1. mandated authority (clearly circumscribed
mandate by the EU establishing its composition
and rules) - 2. sunset principle (not for an indefinite
period pre-established date of expiry with
possibility of renewal) - 3. functional separability (no overlap in tasks
with existing EU institutions) - 4. non-supplementarity (no displacement of
existing EU institutions) - 5. request variety (EGA can narrow or widen the
range of participants and modify internal rules
as long as it does not violate the general
charter) - 6. anti-spill-over (no EGA should exceed the
tasks for whose solution it has originally been
designed)
40b) Composition
- 1. rights (membership in a national political
community) - 2. spatial location (all those living on a
regular basis within a demarcated territory) - 3. knowledge (person or organization possessing
indispensible knowledge for solution of problem) - 4. share (holders of property rights in those
assets being affected by EGA) - 5. stake (all those that could materially or
spiritually be affected by operation of EGA) - 6. interest (anybody representing a constituency
who demonstrates sufficient awareness about the
issue at stake) - 7. status (each organization having an official
status in the representation of social, economic
or political categories)
41Composition continued (different types of
holders)
- primary citizens
- 1. rights holders citizens/voters
- secondary citizens
- 2. space holders residents
- 3. knowledge holders experts
- 4. share holders owners
- 5. stake holders beneficiaries AND victims
- 6. interest holders spokespersons
- 7. status holders representatives
42c) Decision rules
- 1. putative equality (irrespective of size,
each participant should be considered as equal
no first, second, third class participants) - 2. horizontal interaction (avoidance of hierarchy
such as stable delegation of tasks, formalized
leadership, etc.) - 3. consensus principle (no majority voting, no
imposition but deliberation, persuasion and
regular interaction) - 4. open-door (possibility of exit-option without
subsequent retaliation) - 5. proportionality (outcomes are roughly
proportional to the specific assets of each
participant) - 6. shifting alliances (avoidance of rigid
cleavages permanent re-composition of groups and
actors) - 7. checks and balances (no decision on matters
concerning outside organizations) - 8. reversibility (no decisions that cannot be
annulled by right holders, i.e. citizen/ voters
43Multilevel Governance (MLG)
- 1. MLG visualized
- 2. MLG and jurisdictions
44A simple circuit of functional political exchange
State authorities Representatives of labor
unions Representatives of business associations
45A simple circuit of territorial political exchange
Government at level A
Government at level A
Government at level A
46A more complex representation of Multilevel
Governance and of the positioning of different
actor categories
government
NGOs
International suprantional
associations
National
Sub-national(regional, local)
47Unraveling the Central State, but How? Types of
Multi-Level Governanceby Liesbet Hooghe and Gary
Marks
- Type I Governance
- The intellectual foundation for Type I
governance is federalism, which is concerned with
power sharing among a limited number of
governments operating at just a few levels.
Federalism is concerned chiefly with the
relationship between central government and a
tier of non-intersecting sub-national
governments. The unit of analysis is the
individual government, rather than the individual
policy. In the words of Wallace Oates (1999,
1121), dean of fiscal federalism, "The
traditional theory of fiscal federalism lays out
a "general normative framework for the assignment
of functions to different levels of government
and the appropriate fiscal instruments for
carrying out these functions." The framework is
system-wide, the functions are bundled, and the
levels of government are multiple but limited in
number.
48- Type II Governance
- An alternative form of multi-level governance is
one in which the number of jurisdictions is
potentially vast rather than limited, in which
jurisdictions are not aligned on just a few
levels but operate at numerous territorial
scales, in which jurisdictions are task-specific
rather than general-purpose, and where
jurisdictions are intended to be flexible rather
than durable. This conception is predominant
among neoclassical political economists and
public choice theorists, but it also summarizes
the ideas of several scholars of federalism,
local government, international relations, and
Europeanstudies.
49- Type I governance constrains the number of
jurisdictions according to the following design
principles - Nonintersecting memberships. Jurisdictional
memberships at the same territorial level do not
overlap. Nonintersecting membership limits the
need for jurisdictional coordination horizontally
at any level and, vertically, across levels. - Cascading jurisdictional scale. The territorial
scale of jurisdiction decreases sharply across
levels. European Union countries have between two
and five subnational levels, described by the
European Commission in terms of a common rubric,
the Nomenclature des unitis territoriales
statistiques (NUTS) (Eurostat 1999, 27). The
median population represented in the first level,
NUTS 1 jurisdictions, is 3.89 million that in
the second level, NUTS 2 jurisdictions, is 1.42
million NUTS 3 jurisdictions have a median
population of 369,000 the median population in
NUTS 4 is 48,000 and at the lowest level, NUTS
5, it is 5,100. In the United States, the
corresponding median population is 3.76 million
for states, 69,600 for counties, and 8,800 for
subcounties. A cascading jurisdictional scale
spreads governance across vastly different scales
but limits the total number of sub-national
levels to three, four, or, at most, five tiers.
50- General-purpose jurisdictions. A logical
corollary is that authoritative competencies are
bundled into a small number of extensive packages
at each level. Type I governance disperses
authority across widely different levels and
constrains the number of levels by making the
jurisdictions at each level multipurpose. - Systemwide architecture. The pyramidal structure
of Type I governance lends itself to hierarchical
direction. Most Type I governance systems are
bound together by a single court system with
ultimate authority to adjudicate among contending
jurisdictions.
51- Type II governance is alternative to Type I.
-
- It limits coordination costs by constraining
interaction across jurisdictions. Type II
governance sets no ceiling on the number of
jurisdictions but spawns new ones along
functionally differentiated lines. As a result,
externalities across jurisdictions are minimized.
This is an exact corollary to Herbert Simon's
(1996,178) notion of "nearly decomposable
structures. Simon argues that tasks within an
organization should be distributed so that the
share of internal interactions within constituent
units is maximized and the share of external
interactions minimized. The idea, applied to
jurisdictional design, is to distribute tasks so
that the short-run behavior of actors across
different jurisdictions is more or less
independent from that of others, while their
long-run behavior is connected only in the
aggregate.' How can decomposability be attained
in policy provision? How, in other words, can one
break up policymaking into discrete pieces with
minimal external spillover? -
52- The following design principles characterize
Type II governance. -
- Functional specificity. Specific, functionally
distinct competencies are hived off and
insulated. In this way, externalities-and
therefore interdependence-among jurisdictions are
minimized. The assumption that all significant
costs and benefits are internalized within the
jurisdiction is a foundation of Type I1
governance theory, including Tiebout's (1956)
theory of jurisdictional competition, Buchanan's
(1965) theory of clubs, and Oates analysis of
metropolitan competition (Oates and Schwab 1988). - Flexible, policy-specific, architecture. Type I1
governance is designed with respect to particular
policy problems-not particular communities or
constituencies. Institutional design-the scope of
a jurisdiction, its mode of decision making,
adjudication, and implementation-can thus be
adapted to particular policy problems.
53- The two types of governance share one vital
feature They are both radical departures from
the centralized state. However, they diffuse
authority in contrasting ways. - Type I governance bundles competencies in
jurisdictions at a limited number of territorial
levels. These jurisdictions form part of a
system-wide plan They are mutually exclusive at
each territorial level, and the units at each
level are perfectly nested within those at the
next higher level. Jurisdictional design
generally corresponds to communal identities
Each jurisdiction caters to an encompassing group
or territorial community. These jurisdictions are
oriented to voice rather than to exit. Type I
governance reflects a simple design principle
Maximize the fit between the scale of a
jurisdiction and the optimal scale of public good
provision while minimizing inter-jurisdictional
coordination by (a) creating inclusive
jurisdictions that internalize most relevant
externalities and (b) limiting the number of
jurisdictional levels.
54- Type II governance also limits the transaction
costs of inter-jurisdictional coordination, but
it does so in a fundamentally different way, by
splicing public good provision into a large
number of functionally discrete jurisdictions.
But these jurisdictions do not conform to an
overarching blueprint. Rather, each is designed
to address a limited set of related problems.
Type II jurisdictions are task-driven. Hence, the
same individual may be part of several
overlapping and intersecting jurisdictions.
Membership in Type II jurisdictions tends to be
conditional and extrinsic. Type II jurisdictions
are often designed to have low barriers to entry
and exit so as to engender competition among them.
553. Europeanization
- 1.Conceptualizing and measuring it
- 2. Europeanization in comparative perspective
563.1 The domestic effect of Europeanization
573.2 Two logics of domestic change
583.3 Degrees of domestic change
59Democracy in Europe. The EU and National Policy
Makingby Vivian A.Schmidt
1. Policies
603. Patterns of policy formulation and
implementation
Member states along a continuum from statist to
corporatist processes
61Corporatist countries
62Statist/ etatist countries
63Pluralist countries
64National patterns of policy-making and the impact
of the EU
65Conclusions Policies
662. Politics
67Representative politics of simple and compound
polities
68Simple and compound polities along a continuum
betweenmajoritarian and proportional electoral
systems
69Percentage of people who said they were very or
fairly satisfied with their domestic political
system
70Percentage of people who said they trusted the
European Union
71Percentage of people who feel their countrys
membership in the European Union is a good
thing
72Percentage of people who see themselves as both
their nationality and European
73Percentage of people who feel their country
benefits from EU membership
74Conclusions Politics
752. Polities
76Simple and compound polities along a continuum
betweenunitary, regionalized and federal
structures
77Institutional structures of simple and compound
polities
78The differential effect of the EU on national
executives powers, projection of preferences
and compliance patterns related to institutional
structure
79Conclusions polity