Title: Adverse selection
1Adverse selection
- Lecture 3 - Economics of insurance
- EOCN6053 Selected topic in financial economics
- Raymond Yeung, PhD
- Honorary Assistant Professor
- 15 February 2007
2Rate making (price setting) in practice
- In the real world, insurance companies compete by
offering competitive premium rates - An insurer needs to consider on one hand whether
their premium rate, adjusted by its quality of
services, is at least as lower than its
competitors an understanding of elasticity is
needed - Another major consideration is regulatory
requirement. In many countries, premium rate is
highly regulated, also called tariffication (e.g.
India). Rate regulation is often applied to what
we called statutory insurance e.g. compulsory
third party motor liability
3Methods of rating in non-life insurance
- Judgement rating each risk exposure is
evaluated based on the underwriters judgement,
e.g. natural catastrophes - Class rating exposure of similar
characteristics are placed in the same
underwriting class and each is charged the same
rate, e.g. group medical insurance - Merit rating a rating plan by which class rates
are adjusted upward or downward according to the
loss experience of the insured, e.g. motor
insurance
4Methods of rating in life insurance
- Life insurance is rated according to mortality
table, often published by insurance regulator or
the countrys actuary society - For example, premium for a term life insurance
with X of sum assured can be computed as - If the life policy is paid by installment, net
annual level premium can be computed as
5Challenges and issues
- In the end, how insurance companies face two
constrasting goals commercial consideration
(economic efficiency) and social / regulatory
obligation (equity) - Similar to banks, insurance companies are
conventionally, morally, not supposed to make
huge profit, or extract consumer surplus too much - Furthermore, the community always longs for
universal coverage in order to protect all
population from risk exposure e.g. medical care
6Theory of adverse selection
- Theory of demand for insurance states that when
an insurance contract is actuarially fair, the
optimum from consumer point of view is to buy
full coverage. - Consumer has been assumed homogeneous in terms of
their risk profile. Insurance company will not
incur loss by offering a single contract one
single premium rate per dollar of compensation. - In reality, consumers are heterogeneous. One
important consequence is that when an offer is
acceptable to one type, it may not be acceptable
to another.
7Theory of advese selection
- If insurance company can accurately observe the
risk profile of every individual, they can
discriminate the consumers by offering insurance
policies with different premium rates. - In reality it is not practical because there is a
cost associated with risk rating. Furthermore,
some risk types are almost unidentifiable. - A single item menu often attracts those who are
high risk and deters those who are less risk,
resulting in self-selection of adverse groups
into the insurance pooling, further driving up
the premium rates. The process can go on until
the whole pool vanishes, i.e. death spiral
81. Adverse selection model
- Consider a simple two-state model where a
consumer faces a good or a bad state. The
expected utility can be written as - For simplicity, assume the insurance contract is
offered without deductible so that the insured
received a fixed amount of payment in the bad
state. Also assume zero loading factor. - Assume insurance companies are risk neutral and
operate in a competitive insurance market,
insurance contracts are actuarially fair.
91. Adverse selection model
- Lets relax the model and assume there are two
types of individuals high risk and low risk - and there are ß of high risk type. The average
risk profile in the market can be weighted as - Suppose insurance firm cannot observe there are
two risk types and offer a single contract and
set pp. The insurance company expects the
following FOC holds
101. Adverse selection model
- High risk type will buy this contract with full
coverage because they would have expected - which is currently cheaper than in the case when
the insurance companies charge them pH - Low risk type will demand for less than full
coverage because recall our full coverage result
CL
111. Adverse selection model
- implies
- In order for FOC to hold, given u()lt0
- There is no surprise due to Mossins model
121. Adverse selection model
- The expected profit to the insurance companies is
- The first term is now negative because of
additional risks from the high-risk individuals - In a competitive equilibrium, expected profit to
the insurer must be zero, implying
131. Adverse selection model
- Solve the zero profit condition, one can find
that the only situation for the insurer to
balance the book is to have - This result contradicts our earlier finding that
low risk type will not demand for full coverage
if premium is set as - This in turn implies that in this case the
insurer will run a loss which will not be a
competitive equilibrium
141. Adverse selection model
- In Rothschild Stiglizs paper, the contract is
offered as a single pair (P,L)
take-it-or-leave-it. In that setting, low risk do
not buy insurance at all - This average contract leaves the insurer to serve
the high-risk community. If, instead of just two
discrete risk type, pi increases continuously,
the whole insurance market will collapse as the
process of screening out goes on, resulting in
what we called death sprial
151. Adverse selection model death sprial
drop out the 3rd round
drop out in the first round
drop out the second round
High risk
Low risk
P1
P2
161. Adverse selection model - exceptional
- A pooling contract is not entirely impossible but
depending on the proportion of risk types in the
population - It may be the case where the low risk is just
willing to participate but insurer can extract
their consumer surplus to subsidize the loss
making group - Rothschild Stigliz suggests that in general
setting the only possible equilibrium, if it
exists, must be a separating equilibrium.
Otherwise, there is no equilibrium at all.
171. Adverse selection model
- The high-risk will always find it beneficial and
buy this contract, similar to all other contract
where Plt PH - We need to search for a separating equilibrium
by offering two contracts high-risk (PH, CH) and
(PL, CL) so that they satisfy the participation
constraints
181. Adverse selection model
- The schemes should also need to prevent high-risk
type from choosing the product targeting the
low-risk - Likewise, the incentive compatibility constraint
for the low-risk would be
191. Adverse selection model
- To be a competitive equilibrium, the final
constraint requires zero profit to the insurer - The last condition reflects that whether there is
an equilibrium pair depend critically on the
proportion of risk types in the pool - These constraints define the set of possible
equilibria where it is the interest for different
risk groups to reveal their truth. The existence
of these sets of revelation mechansim is called
revelation principle
202. Rating and screening
- Insurer can design a mechanism to allocate
different contracts to appropriate type of the
insured - Subject to one participation constraint and one
incentive constraint
212. Rating and screening example
- For the same benefit level, the rate offered to
low risk is always attractive to the high risk.
Insurer can only adjust the benefit level
downward to be consistent with the incentive
constraint - The participation constraint requires that given
the original premium the low risk still finds it
is their interest to participate - The optimal contract would be an actuarially
unfair contract as surplus is transfer to the
insurer