Title: V. ADVERSE SELECTION, TRADING AND SPREADS
1V. ADVERSE SELECTION, TRADING AND SPREADS
2A. Information and Trading
- The economics of information is concerned with
how information along with the quality and value
of this information affect an economy and
economic decisions. - Information can be inexpensively created, can be
reliable and, when reliable, is valuable. - The simplest microeconomics models assume that
information is costless and all agents have equal
access to relevant information. - But, such assumptions do not hold in reality, and
costly and asymmetric access to information very
much affects how traders interact with each
other. - Investors and traders look to the trading
behavior of other investors and traders for
information, which affects the trading behavior
of informed investors who seek to limit the
information that they reveal. - Here, we discuss the market mechanisms causing
prices to react to the information content of
trades (market impact or slippage), and how
traders and dealers can react to this information
content to maximize their own profits (or
minimize losses). - This chapter is concerned primarily with problems
that arise when traders and other market
participants have inadequate, different
(asymmetric information availability) and costly
access to information.
3Adverse Selection
- Adverse selection refers to pre-contractual
opportunism where one contracting party uses his
private information to the other counterpartys
disadvantage. - For example, the adverse selection problem can
arise when a pyromaniac purchases fire insurance. - The agent (insured or customer) has private
information with respect to the higher
anticipated costs of the insurance coverage or
lease, but pays a pooling premium for the
incident or casualty coverage. - This private information affects the behavior or
insurers and other insured clients, in what might
otherwise be taken to be a sub-optimal manner,
referred to as the adverse selection problem. - In a financial trading context, adverse selection
occurs when one trader with secret or special
information uses that information to her
advantage at the expense of her counterparty in
trade. - Trade counterparties realize that they might fall
victim to adverse selection, so they carefully
monitor trading activity in an effort to discern
which trades are likely to reflect special
information. - For example, large or numerous buy (sell) orders
originating from the same trader are likely to be
perceived as being motivated by special
information. Trade counterparties are likely to
react by adjusting their offers (bids) upwards
(downwards), resulting in slippage.
4B. Noise Traders
- Noise traders trade on the basis of what they
falsely believe to be special information or
misinterpret useful information. - Noise traders make investment and trading
decisions based on incorrect perceptions or
analyses. - Do noise traders distort prices? Maybe yes if
- noise traders trade in large numbers
- their trading behavior is correlated
- their effects cannot be mitigated by informed and
rational traders - Milton Friedman suggested that traders who
produce positive profits do so by trading against
less rational or poorly informed investors who
tend to move prices away from their fundamental
or correct values. - Fama argued that when irrational trading does
occur, security prices will not be significantly
affected because sophisticated traders will react
quickly to exploit and eliminate deviations from
fundamental economic values. - Figlewski 1979 suggested that it might take
irrational investors a long time to lose their
money and for prices to reflect security
intrinsic values, but they are doomed in the long
run. - Noise traders might be useful, perhaps even
necessary for markets to function. - Without noise traders, markets would be
informationally efficient and maybe no one would
want to trade. - Even with asymmetric information access, informed
traders can fully reveal their superior
information through their trading activities, and
prices would reflect this information and
ultimately eliminate the motivation for
information-based trading. - That is, as Black 1986 argued, without noise
traders, dealers would widen their spreads to
avoid losing profits to informed traders such
that no trades would ever be executed. - However, noise traders do impose on other traders
the risk that prices might move irrationally. - This risk imposed by noise traders might
discourage arbitrageurs from acting to exploit
price deviations from fundamental values. - Prices can deviate significantly from rational
valuations, and can remain different for long
periods. - Arbitrageurs might ask themselves the following
question Does my ability to remain solvent
exceed the asset prices ability to remain
irrational?
5C. Adverse Selection in Dealer Markets
- Bagehot 1971 described a market where dealers
or market makers stand by to provide liquidity to
every trader who wishes to trade, losing on
trades with informed traders but recovering these
losses by trading with uninformed, noise or
liquidity motivated traders. - The market maker sets prices and trades to ensure
this outcome, on average. - The market maker merely recovers his operating
costs along with a "normal return. - In this framework, trading is a zero sum or
neutral game uninformed investors will lose more
than they make to informed traders. - Market makers observe buying and selling pressure
on prices, set prices accordingly, often making
surprisingly little use of fundamental analysis
when making their pricing decisions. - The theoretical model of Kyle 1985 describes
the trading behavior of informed traders and
uninformed market makers in an environment with
noise traders.
6Kyle 1985 Informed Traders, Market Makers and
Noise Traders
- Suppose two rational traders have access to the
same information and are otherwise identical.
They have no motivation to trade. - Now, suppose they have different information.
Will they trade? Not if one trader believes that
the other will trade only if the other has
information that will enable him to profit in the
trade at the first traders expense. - Rational traders will not trade against other
rational traders even if their information
differs. This is a variation of the Akerlof Lemon
Problem. - So, why do we observe so much trading in the
marketplace? Most of us believe that others are
not as informed or rational as we are or that
others do not have the same ability to access and
process information that we do. - Kyle examines trading and price setting in a
market where some traders are informed and others
(noise or liquidity traders) are not. - Dealers or market makers serve as intermediaries
between informed an uninformed traders, - Dealers set security prices that enable them to
survive even without the special information
enjoyed by informed traders. - Kyle models how informed traders use their
information to maximize their trading profits
given that their trades yield useful information
to market makers. - Furthermore, market makers will learn from the
informed traders trading, and the informed
trader's trading activity will seek to disguise
his special information from the dealer and noise
traders.
7The Kyle Framework
- Consider a one-time period single auction model
involving an asset that will pay in one time
period vN(p0 S0) - p0 is the unconditional expected value of the
asset. - Variance, S0, can be interpreted to be the amount
of uncertainty that the informed traders perfect
information resolves - There are three risk-neutral trader types
- a single informed trader with perfect information
- many uninformed noise traders
- and a single dealer or market maker who acts as
an intermediary between all trades. - There is no spread and money has no time value.
- Market makers and noise traders seek to learn
from informed trader actions who seeks to
disguise his information in a batch market
(markets accumulate orders before clearing them).
- The informed trader determines x, an appropriate
share transaction volume that maximizes trading
profits p E(v - p) xvwhere p is the market
price of the asset. - Noise traders and the market maker will observe
total share purchases X x u where u reflects
noise trader transactions, bidding up the price
of shares p as X increases. - The market maker cannot distinguish between and
u, but does correctly observe total demand X. - Neither the dealer nor the noise traders know
which trades or traders are informed, but they
try to discern informed demand x from noisy
signal X. - Noise traders submit market orders for u shares
randomly. - Noise traders demand u shares, where u is
distributed normally with mean Eu 0 and
variance su2 uN (0 su2). - Informed traders do not know how many shares
uninformed traders will trade, but does know the
parameters of the distribution of the demand. - Informed and noise traders submit their order
quantities x and u to the market maker in a batch
market. - The market maker observes the net market
imbalance X sets p such that total order flow X
x u clears. - The market maker observes X then sets the price
as a function of the sum of x and u p Evx
u.
8The Informed Traders Problem Profit Maximization
- Kyle's Bayesian Learning model assumes that
informed investor demand x can be expressed as a
simple linear function of v x a ßv where a
and ß are simple coefficients. - Similarly, the securitys price p, set by the
market maker or dealer, is also assumed to be a
simple linear function of demand p µ ?(x
u), where µ and ? are also simple coefficients. - Thus, informed investor demand x is a linear
function of true security value v and the
security price p is a linear function of the sum
of informed and uninformed investor demand X (x
u). - The informed traders problem is to determine the
optimal purchase (or sale) quantity x -
- (1)
-
-
- To maximize the informed traders profits,
-
- (2)
-
- Note that ? must be positive for the second order
condition (the second derivative must be negative
to hold for maximization. We rearrange terms to
obtain -
- (3)
-
- (4)
-
- which is linear in v as Kyle proposed it would
be. Now, we see that our coefficients a and ß are
simply
9Dealer Price Setting
- We now explore our coefficients a and ß.
- The dealer observes total order flow X x u
and sets a single market clearing price p Evx
u where x a ßv. - Since v and X are normally distributed, we apply
the Projection Theorem to p - (5)
-
- This dealer pricing function has a
straightforward interpretation. - The sensitivity of the dealer price to total
share demand is a function of the covariance
between the stocks value and total demand for
the shares. - Thus, if the dealer believes that total demand
for the stock increases dramatically with its
intrinsic value v (unknown to him, but known to
the informed trader), the price that the dealer
sets for shares will be very sensitive to total
demand. - If the informed trader dominates trading, the
dealer will set the price of the security mostly
or entirely as a function of total demand for the
security. - Sensitivity to total demand will diminish as
uninformed demand volatility increases. - As total demand deviates more from expected
demand, share prices will increase.
10Informed Trader Demand and Dealer Price
Adjustment
- Since x a ßv, and S0 is the variance of asset
payoffs v, the variance of informed trader demand
VARx will equal ?2?0. This means that VARxu
S0 ?u2, which means that the dealer pricing
equation is - (6)
-
- ß is the slope of a line plotting a random
dependent variable X or (x u) with respect
random variable v -
- (7)
-
- Kyle suggested a linear relationship between the
security price and its demand p µ ?(x u).
This implies a slope ? equal to -
- (8)
-
- which implies µ p ?(-x - u) and
-
- (9)
-
- Next, we will use a and ß coefficients from above
to demonstrate that µ Ev -
- (10)
11Solving for Demand and Pricing Coefficients
- We for ?, starting by multiplying ? and the right
hand side of equation 11 by the denominator of
the right hand side of the equation -
- (12)
-
- Simplify the left hand side, then multiply both
sides by ? and simplify further by subtracting
1/4S0 from both sides -
- (13)
-
- (14)
-
- (15)
-
- (16)
-
- ? is positive and that our second order condition
for profit maximization has been fulfilled. - ? is the dealer price adjustment for total stock
demand or the illiquidity adjustment. - S0/?u2 is the ratio of informed trader private
information resolution to the level of noise
trading. - The dealer price adjustment is proportional to
the square root of this ratio, increasing as
private information S0 is increasing and
decreasing as noise trading increases. This
means that if the dealer determines that the
informed trader resolves a substantial level of
risk relative to the amount of noise trading, the
level of dealer price adjustment will be large.
12Informed Trader Demand
- Informed investor demand coefficients a and ß
are -
- The informed trader demand function is
- (17)
-
- Informed trader transaction sizes will increase
as the variance of uninformed noise demand for
shares su2 increases. - This increased noise volume will better enable
informed traders to camouflage their information
advantage over the dealer. - As the informed traders information improves
relative to the dealer, the informed trader will
seek to camouflage his advantage by reducing his
trade volume. The informed trader will earn his
profits by maintaining more profit on a per share
basis rather than on transaction volume.
13Dealer Price Setting
- Recall from equation (7) that the market maker
sets the price at p, which we will rewrite using
the result of equation 16 -
- (18)
-
- (19) p µ ?(x u) Ev (xu)
-
- Notice that the dealer price p is the securitys
expected value Ev conditioned on total demand
xu for the security. - Higher noise or uninformed trader uncertainty
reduces the security price unless total demand
(xu) is negative. - The opposite is true for value or cash flow
uncertainty, which increases the informed
trader's informational advantage. - The market maker sets the price at p, such that
the informed trader buys (sells) whenever v gt
Ev (v lt Ev), and buys (sells) more
aggressively as this difference increases.
14Informed Trader Profits
- Notice that some of these implications might be
clarified with the following informed trader
profit function -
- (20)
-
-
- Informed trader profits are linear and increasing
in the quality of their information advantage and
the demand uncertainty su of noise traders. - A larger value for S0 implies a greater deviation
in the security value v (known by the informed
trader) from its expected value Ev (estimated
by the dealer). - A larger value for S0 implies a larger
information advantage to the informed trader. - Greater dealer price uncertainty increases
informed trader trading profits. - Increased uninformed trader uncertainty and its
associated increase in transactions mean that the
informed trader is better able to disguise from
the market maker his information advantage and
trading activity through the increased noise
trader volume su. This ability to camouflage
means that the informed trader can trade more
aggressively, taking larger positions (x or x)
and profits in the stock without accurately
revealing his transactions to the market maker. - The market maker sets a price p such that
informed traders earn their profits indirectly
from noise traders. The market maker loses on
trades with informed traders and earns profits on
trades with noise traders, earning a competitive
profit as long as informed traders successfully
camouflage their intentions at the ultimate
expense of noise traders.
15Illustration Kyle's Adverse Selection Model
- Suppose that the unconditional value of a stock
in a Kyle framework is normally distributed with
an expected value equal to Ev 50 and a
variance equal to S0 30. - An informed trader has private information that
the value of the stock is actually v 45 per
share. - Uninformed investor trading is random and
normally distributed with an expected net share
demand of zero su2 equal to 5,000. - The dealer can observe the total level of order
volume X x u where u reflects noise trader
transactions and x reflects informed demand, but
the dealer cannot distinguish between x and u. - The ability of the informed trader to camouflage
his activity is directly related to su2 and
inversely related to x. - What would be the level of informed trader demand
for the stock? We solve for x as follows, using
equation 17 -
-
16Informed Demand and Dealer Pricing Coefficients
- The informed trader would wish to sell an
infinite number of shares to earn a 5 profit on
each, but cannot because the dealer would
correctly infer that his share sales convey
meaningful information, and the dealer's price
revisions would lead to slippage. - Thus, at what level does the dealer set his
price, given the total demand X x u
-64.5497 0 that he observes? First, we solve
for parameters in the dealer pricing equation - .
17The Dealer Price
- The Dealer sets her price as follows
18D. Adverse Selection and the Spread
- Walrasian markets assume perfect and frictionless
competition and symmetric information
availability. - In security markets, imperfect competition,
bid-offer imbalances and frictions often reveal
themselves in bid-offer spreads. Here, we are
concerned with the determinants of the bid-offer
spread. - The evolution of prices through time should
provide insight as to what affects the spread. - If market frictions were the only factors
affecting the spread, we should expect that, in
the absence of new information, execution prices
would tend to bounce between bid and ask prices.
Thus, frictions such as transactions costs will
tend to be either leave execution prices
unchanged or to change in the opposite direction.
Thus, transactions costs tend to induce negative
serial correlation in asset prices. - Asymmetric information produces positive serial
correlation in asset prices. Suppose that
asymmetric information is the only source of the
spread, such that transaction prices reflect
information communicated by transactions.
Transactions executed at bid prices would cause
permanent drops in prices to reflect negative
information and transactions executed at offer
prices would cause permanent increases in prices
to reflect positive information. If price changes
are solely a function of random news arrival,
price changes will be random. If the distribution
of information is asymmetric, prices will exhibit
positive serial correlation as informed traders
communicate their information through their
trading activity (recall that this is what
informed traders try to avoid in the Kyle model).
Thus, the extent to which information
distribution is asymmetric will affect the serial
correlation of asset prices. - Inventory costs (such as unsystematic risk from
the dealers inability to diversify) will tend to
cause negative serial correlations in price
quotes. Transactions at the bid will tend to
cause risk averse dealers to reduce their bid
quotes as they become more reluctant not to
over-diversify their inventories. Similarly,
transactions at the ask will tend to cause
dealers to raise their quotes as they become more
reluctant not to under-diversify their
inventories. - Inventory costs and transactions costs will tend
to lead towards negative serial correlation in
security prices. - Asymmetric information availability will lead
towards positive serial correlation in security
prices as transactions communicate new
information.
19The Demsetz 1968 Immediacy Argument
- Order imbalances impose waits on impatient
traders requiring immediacy. - The costs of providing immediacy to liquidity
traders include order processing costs
(transactions costs), information and adverse
selection costs, inventory holding costs, costs
of absorbing inventory risks and costs of
providing trading options. - The bid-offer spread provides the dealer
compensation for assuming these costs on behalf
of the market. - In the Demsetz 1968 analysis, buyers and
sellers of a security are each of two types, one
of which who wants an immediate transaction and a
second who wants a transaction, but can wait. - Buy and sell orders arrive to the market in a
non-synchronous fashion, causing order
imbalances. - An imbalance of traders demanding an immediate
trade forces the price to move against
themselves, causing less patient traders to pay
for immediacy. - The greater the costs of trading, and the greater
the desire for immediacy, the greater will be the
market spread.
20Glosten and Milgrom 1985 Information Asymmetry
Model
- The Glosten and Milgrom 1985 adverse selection
model assumes that dealer spreads are based on
the likelihood p that an informed trader will
trade. - Trades arrive to the market maker, each with some
random chance of originating from either an
informed or uninformed trader. - The asset can take on one of two prices, a high
price PH and a low price PL, each with
probability ½. - Uninformed traders will not pay more than PH for
the asset and they will not sell for less than
PL. - Risk neutral liquidity traders value the asset at
(PH PL)/2. - When setting his quotes, the dealer needs to
account for the probability that an informed
trader will transact at his quote, and will set
his bid price Pb and ask price Pa as follows -
- Pb pPL (1 p)(PH PL)/2
- Pa pPH (1 p)(PH PL)/2
-
- The spread is simply the difference between the
ask and bid prices - Pa - Pb p(PH - PL)
- Thus, in the single-period Glosten and Milgrom
model, the spread is a function of the likelihood
that there exists an informed trader in the
market and the uncertainty in the value of the
traded asset. - The greater the uncertainty in the value of the
traded asset as reflected by (PH PL)/2, and the
greater the probability p that a trade has
originated with an informed trader, the greater
will be the spread.
21The Stoll 1978 Inventory Model
- A dealer needs to maintain inventories in assets
in which he makes a market to sell to investors
as well as cash to purchase assets from
investors. - Suppose that a dealer currently without inventory
in a particular asset trades so as to maximize
his expected utility level. - Assume that the dealer's wealth level could be
subject to some uncertain normally distributed
security return r whose expected value is zero
and variance s2. - The dealer is willing to quote a bid price Pb to
purchase this security whose consensus value or
price is P. Our problem here is to determine the
maximum price that a risk averse dealer would be
willing to bid -
- EU(W Pb (1r)P) U(W)
- EU(W (P - Pb) rP) U(W)
- The dealers expected utility after the security
purchase is a function of his current level of
wealth W, his bid price Pb and his uncertain
return. Our problem is to solve this equality for
Pb. - We start by performing a Taylor series expansion
around the left side of the equality -
- EU(W) (P - Pb rP)(U(W)) ½(P - Pb rP)
2(U(W)) U(W) - Since Er 0, ErPU(W) can be dropped from
the equality and s2 E(P - Pb rP)2 -
- EU(W) (P - Pb)(U(W)) ½(s2)U(W)
U(W)
22Simplifying the Stoll Pricing Model for the Bid
- Drop left-hand side higher order terms not
explicitly stated in the above equality -
- (P - Pb)(U(W)) ? - ½(s2)U(W)
- (P - Pb) ? - ½(s2)U(W)/ U(W)
- (P - Pb) ? ½(s2)ARA
- where -U(W)/U(W) is the dealers Arrow-Pratt
Absolute Risk Aversion Coefficient (ARA). - The greater the dealers risk aversion, or the
greater the uncertainty associated with the
asset, the greater will be the discount
associated with his bid. - The dealer maintains an initial inventory Wp of
securities Wp W0. The dealer borrows and lends
at the riskless rate r, assumed to be zero. This
initial inventory of securities Wp is an optimal
portfolio that maximizes the dealer's utility
U(W) subject to his initial wealth constraint - EU(Wp(1rp) (P - Pb) rP) U(W)
- where ri is the uncertain return on the tradable
asset i and rp is the uncertain return on the
optimal portfolio Wp. Expand the left side of
this equation around EU(Wp), assume that Er
Erp 0, and drop higher order terms -
- EU(Wp) (P - Pb)(U(Wp)) ½(s2)U(Wp)
2½ErPrpWpU"(Wp) U(W) - The covariance of cash flows between profits on
the optimal portfolio and the tradable asset i is
2½ErPrpWp si,P. Simplifying and solving
for (P - Pb), we find that the dealers bidding
discount from the consensus price is - (P - Pb) sI,PARA ½(s2)ARA
23Obtaining the Stoll Ask Price
- Similarly, the premium based the dealers ask or
offer price Pa is obtained as follows -
- (Pa - P) -sI,PARA ½(s2)ARA
- Thus, the dealer will increase his offer premium
as his inventory of securities decreases and as
the covariance between his inventory returns and
the asset returns decreases. The bid-offer spread
is simply the sum of the bid discount and offer
premium - (Pa - Pb) (s2)ARA
- The greater the dealers risk aversion, or the
greater the uncertainty associated with the
asset, the greater will be the dealers spread.
The dealers inventory level does not affect the
size of the spread.
24The Copeland and Galai 1983 Options Model
- A bid provides prospective sellers a put on the
asset, with the exercise price of the put equal
to the bid. - An offer provides a call to other traders.
- Thus, when the dealer posts both bid and offer
quotes, the spread is, in effect, a short
strangle provided to the market. Both legs of
this strangle are more valuable when the risk of
the underlying security is higher. - An options pricing model can be used to value
this dealer spread. - Ultimately, this "implied premium" associated
with this dealer spread is paid by liquidity
traders who trade without information. - Informed traders make money at the expense of the
dealer, who ultimately earns it back at the
expense of the uninformed trader. - The Copeland and Galai model, as presented here,
does not have a mechanism to allow trading
activity to convey information from informed
traders to dealers and uninformed traders.
Nonetheless, in the Copeland and Galai
option-based model, the spread widens as the
uncertainty with respect to the security price
increases.