Title: Chinas Uneven Progress Against Poverty
1Chinas (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty
Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development
Research Group, World Bank
2Questions
- How much progress has China made against absolute
poverty? - When and where was the greatest progress made?
- What happened to inequality? A
poverty-inequality trade off? - What were the proximate causes of uneven progress
over time and across provinces? What role was
played by public policies? - What lessons does Chinas past success against
poverty hold for China in the future and for the
rest of the developing world?
3Data Five findings Five lessons
4Data
5Distributional data for China
- Newly constructed poverty lines
- Old lines seen as out of date too low no
allowance for geographic COL differences - New lines 850 Yuan per year for rural areas and
1200 Yuan for urban areas, both in 2002 prices
also province-specific lines - Newly assembled distributional data
- much of which has not previously been analyzed
- Rural Household Surveys (from 1980) and Urban
Household Surveys (1981) of National Bureau of
Statistics - Early surveys small for 30 of provinces, but no
sign of bias - Time series of tabulated distributions (micro
data not available) - Incomplete data at provincial level
- though we can still provide estimates of the
trends.
6New poverty lines
- Region-specific food bundles for urban and rural
areas, valued at median unit values by province.
- Food bundles based on the actual consumption of
those between the 15th and 25th percentile
nationally. - These bundles are then scaled to reach 2100
calories per person per day, with 75 of the
calories from foodgrains. - Allowances for non-food consumption are based on
the nonfood spending of households in a
neighborhood of the point at which total spending
equaled the food poverty line in each province
(and separately for urban and rural areas).
7Deflators over time
- Urban and rural CPI
- Urban inflation rate higher than rural, esp., in
the 1990s (higher costs of previously subsidized
goods)
8Rising urban-rural COL differential
9Corrections for 1990 change in valuation method
in RHS
- 1990 change in valuation methods for imputing
income from consumption of own-farm output - Distributions by both methods for 1990 are used
to correct the data for the late 1980s
10Corrections for 1990 change in valuation method
in RHS
- 1990 change in valuation methods for imputing
income from consumption of own-farm output - Distributions by both methods for 1990 are used
to correct the data for the late 1980s
11Poverty measures
- Headcount index (H) living in households with
income per person below the poverty line. - Poverty gap index (PG) mean distance below the
poverty line as a proportion of the poverty line - Squared poverty gap index (SPG) poverty gaps are
weighted by the gaps themselves, so as to reflect
inequality amongst the poor (Foster et al.,
1984). - Parameterized Lorenz Curves
- alternative functional forms (Betageneral
elliptical) - checks for theoretical consistency and accuracy
12Inequality measures
- Relative Gini index based on sum of income
differences normalized by the mean for that
distribution - Absolute Gini index based on sum of income
differences normalized by a fixed mean
13Persistent data problems
- Sample frame based on registration system gt
underestimation of urban poverty - Survey compliance problems, esp., urban areas
- Single price indices, independent of level of
income
14Five findings
15- Huge overall progress against poverty, but uneven
progress - Rising inequality, though more so in some periods
and places - The pattern of growth matters to both poverty and
inequality in China - No sign of an aggregate growth-equity trade off
- Poverty would have fallen much faster without
rising inequality
16Finding 1 Huge overall progress against
poverty, but uneven progress
- In the 20 year period after 1981, the proportion
living below our new poverty lines fell from 53
to 8. - ( 62 in 1980.)
- Half of the decline in poverty came in 1981-84.
- However, there were many setbacks for the poor.
- Poverty rose in the late 1980s and stalled in
early 1990s, - recovered pace in the mid-1990s,
- but stalled again in the late 1990s.
-
17Headcount index, 1981-2001
18Headcount index for 1/day, 1981-2001
China
Developing world less China
East Asia less China
19Effect on headcount index of our correction for
the change in valuation methods
20Trend rates of change in rural headcount index
(upper line by province /year 1983-2001)
21Trend rates of change in rural headcount index
(upper line by province /year 1983-2001)
Fujian, Jiangsu
Beijing
Guangdong
22Finding 2 Rising inequality But not
continuously and more so in some periods and some
provinces
- Relative inequality is higher in rural than urban
areas - in marked contrast to most developing countries.
- Though steeper increase in urban inequality.
- Relative inequality between urban and rural areas
has not shown a rising trend once one allows for
the higher rate of increase in the urban
cost-of-living. - Absolute inequality has increased appreciably
- between and within both urban and rural areas,
- and absolute inequality is higher in urban areas.
23Relative inequality between urban and rural areas
24Absolute inequality between urban and rural areas
25Relative inequality in rural and urban areas and
nationally
26Absolute inequality in rural and urban areas and
nationally
27Effect on Gini index and mean of our correction
for the change in valuation methods
28Finding 3 The pattern of growth matters
- Economic growth was clearly a key proximate cause
of poverty reduction - Growth elasticity of poverty reduction
- 3.2 (t 8.7) (using survey means)
- 2.6 (t 2.2) (using GDP per capita)
29The sectoral pattern of growth matters
- The gains to the poor from aggregate economic
growth depended on its sectoral composition. - Decomposition of change in poverty
- Within-sector effect is the change in poverty
measures over time weighted by final year
population shares - Population shift effect measures the partial
contribution of urbanization over time, weighted
by the initial urban-rural difference in poverty
measures. (Kuznets process of migration.)
30Decomposition of the change in poverty Migration
to urban areas helped, but the bulk of the
reduction in poverty came from within rural areas
- Note Quite rapid urbanization despite
restrictions on migration - Urban share of 19 in 1980 rose to 39 in 2002
31Regression decomposition for mean income growth
- Mean income
- Growth rate
- Test equation
- Null hypothesis
32(No Transcript)
33(No Transcript)
34Decomposing GDP growth
- Standard classification of its origins, namely
- primary (mainly agriculture),
- secondary (manufacturing and construction) and
- tertiary (services and trade).
- The primary sectors share fell from 30 in 1980
to 15 in 2001, though not montonically. - Almost all of this decline was made up for by an
increase in the tertiary-sector share. -
35Shares of GDP by sector
36Regression decomposition for sectoral
decomposition
- Test equation
- Null hypothesis
37(No Transcript)
38(No Transcript)
39Primary sector was the main engine of poverty
reduction
- Growth in the primary sector (primarily
agriculture) did more to reduce poverty than
either the secondary or tertiary sectors. -
- Starting in 1981, if the same aggregate growth
rate had been balanced across sectors then it
would have taken 10 years to bring the national
poverty rate down to 8, rather than 20 years. - But could a more equitable growth process have
allowed the same rate of growth?
40Province level
- Complete series of mean income from 1980
- But less complete distributional data 11-12
years - Marked differences in initial conditions Gini
index around mid-1980s varied from 18 to 33. - OLS estimates of province specific trends
41Provinces with higher growth rates in rural mean
income saw faster poverty reduction
42Provinces with higher growth rates in rural mean
income saw faster poverty reduction
Reliability? Hlt2
43Provinces with higher growth rates in rural mean
income saw faster poverty reduction
Elasticity -2.4 (t -4.3) (dropping Beijing,
Shanghai, Tianjin)
44Wide variation in growth elasticities of poverty
reduction
- 95 CI for the impact of a 3 growth rate on H is
(0, 9) - Dropping Beijing, Shanghai and Tianjin the 95 CI
for 3 growth rate is (4, 10) - Growth elasticity calculated as ratio of trend in
H to trend in mean varies from 6.6 ro 1.0
(mean-2.3) - Geographic composition of growth mattered to
aggregate rate of poverty reduction.
45Growth did not occur where it would have most
impact on poverty
46Inequality and the pattern of growth
- The composition of growth also mattered to the
evolution of aggregate inequality. - Agricultural growth was inequality decreasing.
47Inequality and GDP growth by origin
48Inequality and GDP growth by origin
49Inequality and growth in mean urban and rural
incomes
Rural economic growth reduced inequality within
both urban and rural areas, as well as between
them
50Inequality and growth in mean urban and rural
incomes
Rural economic growth reduced inequality within
both urban and rural areas, as well as between
them
51Finding 4 No sign of an aggregate growth-equity
trade off
- The strong positive correlation over time between
Chinas GDP per capita and inequality is driven
by common time trends. - Near zero correlation between changes in (log)
Gini and growth rate. - The periods of more rapid growth did not bring
more rapid increases in inequality. Indeed,
52The periods of falling inequality had highest
growth in mean household income
53The periods of falling inequality had highest
growth in mean household income
54Provinces with higher growth did not have
steeper rises in inequality
r -0.18
55Double handicap in more unequal provinces
-
- More unequal provinces faced two handicaps in
rural poverty reduction - High inequality provinces had a lower growth
elasticity of poverty reduction - High inequality provinces had lower growth
- signs of inefficient inequality both within
rural areas, and between urban and rural areas gt
56Regressions for provincial trends in poverty and
mean incomes
Initial conditions (mean and distribution)
location
57Initially poorer and less unequal provinces had
higher rates of poverty reduction
- Large effects going from the lowest initial
inequality to - the highest inequality cuts 7 points off the
annual rate of - poverty reduction.
- Initial distribution matters independently of
growth both - inequality measures remain significant (though
with smaller - coefficients) when one adds the trend growth
rate to the - regression for trend poverty reduction
58Finding 5 Poverty would have fallen much faster
without rising inequality
- Lack of aggregate growth-equity trade-off implies
that - Growth has more impact on poverty
- Rising inequality puts a brake on poverty
reduction - If not for the rise in inequality within rural
areas, the national poverty rate in 2001 would
have been 1.5 rather than 8. - In most provinces, rapidly rising rural
inequality meant far lower poverty reduction than
one would have expected given the growth. - An exception was Guangdong, which achieved rapid
rural poverty reduction by combining growth with
stationary inequality. Why? - Nor did higher inequality permit higher growth
59Steeper increases in inequality did not mean
faster poverty reduction
60Actual poverty incidence in 2001 and simulated
level without the rise in inequality
61Five lessons
62Lesson 1 Low-lying fruit of agrarian reform
- Great Leap Forward and the Cultural Revolution
left a legacy of pervasive and severe rural
poverty by the late 1970s. - Yet much of the rural population that had been
forced into collective farming (with weak
incentives for work) could still remember how to
farm individually. - Undoing these failed policies called for
de-collectivizing agriculture and shifting the
responsibility for farming to households. - This brought huge gains to the countrys (and the
worlds) poorest. Possibly half of the total
decline in poverty in China 1981-2001 was due to
this reform. - But it was a one-time reform.
63Lesson 2 Agricultural growth is good for poor
people
- Important lesson for other developing countries.
- Though here too are unusual historical
circumstances - the relatively equitable land allocation that
could be achieved at the time of breaking up the
collectives. - With fairly equal access to land (at least for
the present) and relatively few distortions to
incentives, achieving higher agricultural growth
in China will require - sound investments in research and development,
- and in rural infrastructure.
- Evidence that targeted poor-area development
programs can help in this setting.
64Lesson 3 Some forms of public spending and
taxation matter more than others
- Taxation Dont tax poor farmers to subsidize
urban consumers! Higher procurement prices
reduced poverty. - These are distributional effects in large part
- This too is an unusual country circumstance
- a procurement system that taxed farmers by
setting quotas and fixing procurement prices
below market levels. - This was a powerful anti-poverty lever in the
short-term. - Public spending Local but not central public
spending reduced poverty, but not inequality.
65Lesson 4 Less clear on economy-wide policies
(macro stability and free trade)
- Support for the view that macroeconomic stability
(esp., avoiding inflationary shocks) has been
good for poverty reduction -
- But the score card for trade reform is blank!
- Neither the trade reforms nor the trade
expansions coincided with the times of falling
poverty. - Zero correlation between changes in trade volume
(TV) and changes in poverty. Nor with lagged TV
up to two years. - Also holds with controls (inflation, proc. price,
mean Y). - Endogeneity of trade? Yes, but bias probably goes
against the view that trade reform was poverty
reducing in short-term.
66Lesson 5 Inequality is now an issue for China
- High inequality in many provinces will inhibit
future prospects for both growth and poverty
reduction. - Aggregate growth is increasingly coming from
sources that bring limited gains to the poorest.
- Inequality is continuing to rise
- and poverty is becoming much
- more responsive to rising inequality.
- Perceptions of what poverty means are also
changing, which can hardly be surprising in an
economy that can quadruple its mean income in 20
years.