Title: DIMENSIONS OF CONTESTATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION
1DIMENSIONS OF CONTESTATIONIN THE EUROPEAN UNION
- Tapio Raunio (tapio.raunio_at_uta.fi)
- Credits 2 ECTS
- Location Paasivirta Lecture room, Department of
Contemporary History -
- Dates and topics
- 9.10 14-17 Introduction / Public opinion
- 10.10. 9-12 Political parties / European
Parliament - 16.10 14-17 The Council / Democratic deficit
- 17.10 9-12 The future of EU governance
2INTRODUCTIONWhy study dimensions of
contestation(or lines of conflict) in the
European Union?
- While the EU can be characterized as a consensual
polity (multiple checks and balances), its
outputs (laws, non-binding decisions, foreign
policy etc.) are nonetheless the product of
bargaining between actors that have policy goals
shaped by their ideological dispositions - Media seldom pays attention to the dimensions of
politics in the EUs political system (notably in
the Council or the Parliament) or to the reasons
why certain member states favour / oppose
decisions - Media far too often provides a simplified picture
of reality e.g., Poland is a difficult country
in the EU, or Swedes oppose further
integration
3Consensus democracy and supermajorities
- Constitutional (Treaty) amendment is subject to
unanimity, with all member states having the
power of veto this basically rules out
large-scale reforms - EU has no government or president the European
Council is the collective executive board of
the Union. The European Council decides with
some exceptions - by unanimity - The role of the Commission in initiating and
implementing legislation is overseen by national
governments, whose civil servants participate in
the hundreds of committees and working groups
that draft the EUs legislative initiatives and
oversee their eventual implementation - The Council decides most issues by QMV (over 70
of votes), but its working methods are still
consensual, with emphasis on building compromises
acceptable to all or nearly all governments
4- The Council is still far more powerful than the
European Parliament - Consultation procedure is still the most common
legislative procedure (EP only consulted) - The two chambers are equal only in matters
falling under the co-decision procedure (used in
under half of EU legislation depending how one
measures the share of issues processed according
to the co-decision procedure) - Co-decision procedure involves two readings in
both institutions, following which a conciliation
committee is convened if no agreement has been
reached. In the second reading the Council
decides by QMV and the EP by absolute majority
(50 1 of all MEPs) - Decision rules are reflected in the work of the
institutions in both the Council and the EP the
emphasis is on building broad consensus (laws
based on supermajorities) - No opposition Example how can citizens oppose
Common Agricultural Policy? Would require the
election of parliamentary majorities opposed to
CAP in all or nearly all member states!!
5Chains of representationin the EUs political
system
- The national channel
- Citizens ? national parliament ? government ?
Council / European Council - The European channel
- Citizens ? European Parliament ? Commission
6Co-decision procedure
7PUBLIC OPINION ONEUROPEAN INTEGRATION
- Basic premises
- The political elites (MPs, MEPs, parties,
business and administrative elites) are more
pro-integrationist than citizens - Low salience of EU for voters (permissive
consensus?) - Weak attachment to the EU hardly any feeling of
a political community - Citizens knowledge of how EU functions remains
very limited (particularly regarding
decision-making) - Public support for integration remained at a high
level until the early 1990s - Highest levels of Euroscepticism are normally
found in the UK, Sweden, Austria, and Finland --
and also in some of the new member states
8- Explanatory factors
- Utilitarian calculations (perceived benefits) are
usually seen as the strongest explanatory factor - those that benefit from trade liberalization
support integration - those that otherwise benefit from the removal of
borders support integration - The popularity of the national government or
the state of the national economy influences
support for the EU - Identity is becoming more important if citizens
have an exclusive (national) identity, they are
more likely to be critical of integration - New member countries transition winners are
likelier to support integration
9REFERENDA ON EU MEMBERSHIP
10Referenda and European Integration
- Domestic context and factors impact on voting
behaviour in EU referenda and EP elections and
also explain to some extent public opinion on
integration - Why the French voted against the Constitutional
Treaty on 29 May, 2005? (turnout 70 , 55
against the Constitution) - Outcome mainly explained by
- French economy worries about unemployment,
relocation of businesses, and the decline of the
French social model (and lack of social
dimension in the Treaty) and - opposition to the government and the president
(which were in favour of the Constitutional
Treaty) - Argument even though the citizens may overall be
supportive of integration, referenda provide them
the opportunity to protest against particular
aspects of integration (e.g., Turkeys potential
membership)
11Irish referendum on the Treaty of Lisbon
- Irish referendum on 12 June 2008 53 against,
47 in favour. Turnout was 53 - All three government parties supported the 'Yes'
campaign. So did all opposition parties in the
parliament, with the exception of Sinn Féin. Most
Irish trade unions and business organisations
also supported the 'yes' campaign - Ireland was the only member state that held a
referendum on the Treaty (in addition to a
parliamentary vote) - Outcome probably explained by a combination of
domestic (resignation of PM Ahern due to
corruption pro-EU consensus of the political
elite worries about economy) and European
(fears of tax harmonisation and common EU
defence agricultural policy) reasons - Citizens also suffered from lack of information ?
Ahern's successor PM Brian Cowen admitted that
not even he had read the text of the Treaty!
12Image of the EU (Eurobarometer 69, spring 2008)
13Support for membership
14Public opinion IIElites versus the citizens
- Hooghe, Liesbet (2003) Europe Divided? Elites
vs. Public Opinion on European Integration.
European Union Politics 43, 281-304. - Elites (both national and European) are by and
large more supportive of European integration
than the citizens - How should authority be distributed between the
EU and national governments? - Elites favour a European Union capable of
governing a large, competitive market (currency,
single market) and projecting political muscle
(foreign and defense policy) - Citizens are more in favour of a caring European
Union, which protects them from the vagaries of
capitalist markets
15- Elites and public preferences are similar in that
both are least enthusiastic about Europeanizing
high-spending policies such as health, education,
or social policy -- shifting authority in these
policies could destabilize powerful vested
interests and disrupt policy delivery - However, the public wants to Europeanize
market-flanking policies, and elites do not - As the single market intensifies labor market
volatility, the public seems intent to contain
this other distributional risk through
selectively Europeanizing policies that flank
market integration employment, social policy,
cohesion policy, environment, and industrial
policy - The views of elites are consistent with a
functional rationale, which conceives integration
as an optimal solution for reaping economies of
scale the policies elites want to Europeanize
most are currency, foreign policy, development
aid, immigration, environment, and defense
16POLITICAL PARTIES ANDEUROPEAN INTEGRATION
- European integration has not altered the basic
structure of national party systems by resulting
in the formation of new parties - But, most national parties are divided over EU
for example, the main British and French parties
have experienced serious internal disputes on
integration matters since the 1950s - There are very strong reasons to expect that we
would not witness the entry of new parties as a
result of European integration -- or any other
issue for that matter - The main explanatory factor for the observed
stability is that the established national
parties have an interest in sustaining the status
quo and the prevailing structures of party
competition
17- Parties that are successful in the existing
structure of contestation have little incentive
to rock the boat, while unsuccessful parties,
that is, parties with weak electoral support or
those that are locked out of government, have an
interest in restructuring competition. The same
strategic logic that leads mainstream parties to
assimilate the issues raised by European
integration into the Left/Right dimension of
party competition leads peripheral parties to
exploit European integration in an effort to
shake up the party system. (Hooghe et al. 2002
970) - Does ideology or country-specific factors explain
how parties view European integration? - The standard finding has been that of an inverted
U-curve, with opposition to European integration
found at the extreme ends of the left-right
dimension while more centrist parties are
supportive of further integration - This implies that party family is a powerful
predictor of party positions on EU
18- Centrist party families are in favour of
integration - Leftist parties -- particularly social democrats
but also greens and the radical left -- have
become considerably more pro-integrationist since
the early 1990s - Leftist parties want to counterbalance economic
integration with increasing the EUs role in
social and environment policies, while the
centre-right parties focus primarily on EMU
(broad agreement about the deepening of
integration) - According to recent studies deeper integration
enjoys more support among representatives of
leftist parties - Opposition to the EU is mainly the reserve of
anti-system or ideologically more radical
(extreme left or right) parties these parties
find it difficult to establish regular
cooperation with each other largely the same
group of parties that are excluded from
government in their countries
19- However, more recent research has partially
challenged this argument, particularly as a
result of the enlargement that took place in 2004 - Marks et al. (2006) show that another cleavage,
the GAL (Green / alternative / libertarian) -TAN
(traditional / authoritarian / nationalist)
dimension is a strong predictor of parties EU
positions -- with opposition to further
integration mainly found among extreme left/right
and TAN parties - There are important differences between the old
member states and those that joined the Union in
2004. In the West, the leftist parties tend to
be GAL parties while rightist parties are more
TAN in their orientation. In the East, on the
other hand, opposition to the EU is primarily
concentrated among a group of left/TAN parties
20Domestic structure of party competition and
positioning on European integrationWest vs.
East(Vachudova Hooghe 2006)
21Domestic structure of party competition and
positioning on European integrationWest vs.
East(Vachudova Hooghe 2006)
22PARTY POLITICS INTHE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT
- Compared with parties in EU member state
legislatures, the party groups of the European
Parliament operate in a very different
institutional environment - There is no real EU government accountable to the
Parliament - There are no coherent and hierarchically
organized European-level parties - MEPs are elected from lists drawn by national
parties and on the basis of national electoral
campaigns - The social and cultural heterogeneity of the EU
is reflected in the internal diversity of the
groups, with a total of 170 national parties from
25 member states winning seats in the Parliament
in the 2004 elections
23- However, despite the existence of such factors,
EP party groups have gradually over the decades
consolidated their position in the Parliament - At the same time the shape of the party system
has become more stable, at least as far as the
main groups are concerned. One can thus talk of
the institutionalization of the EP party system
- Throughout its history the EP party system has
been based on the left-right dimension - Initially the party system consisted of only
three groups socialists/social democrats (PES),
Christian democrats/conservatives (EPP), and
liberals (ELDR), the three main party families in
most EU member states - Since the first direct elections also the Greens
and the group of the radical left parties, now
titled the Confederal Group of the European
United Left / Nordic Green Left (EUL-NGL), have
become institutionalized in the chamber - Moreover, Eurosceptical parties, parties whose
main reason of existence is opposition to further
integration, have formed a group under various
labels since the 1994 elections
24Seat distribution in the EP after the 2004
elections
25- The EP groups achieve rather high levels of
voting cohesion (around 90 ) - The main cleavage structuring competition in the
Parliament is the familiar left-right dimension,
the main dimension of contestation in European
democracies (Hix et al. 2007) - While the primary decision rule in the EP is
simple majority (50 1 of those voting), for
certain issues (mainly budget amendments and
second reading amendments under the co-decision
procedure) the EP needs to muster absolute
majorities (50 1 of all MEPs) - The absolute majority requirement facilitates
co-operation between the two main groups, EPP and
PES, as the surest way of getting the required
number of MEPs behind the Parliaments decision
is when the two large groups agree on the issue - Cooperation between EPP and PES could also be
regarded as a sign of maturity, as the
Parliament needed to moderate its resolutions in
order to get its amendments accepted by the
Council and the Commission. After all, the
overwhelming majority of national ministers
represented in the Council and members of the
Commission are either social democrats or
Christian democrats/conservatives - However, in recent years (particularly after the
1999 EP elections) this co-operation has played a
lesser role than before, with EPP and PES
opposing each other more often regardless of the
voting rule but still the two large groups vote
together most of the time
26Life in the post-enlargement 2004-2009 EP has
anything changed? (Based primarily on Hix and
Noury 2008)
- Enlargements (2004 and 2007) have increased the
number of MEPs 626 to 785. These MEPs represent
27 countries and around 180 parties - The increase in heterogeneity of membership
plausibly leads to less predictable and less
stable voting patterns. Moreover, it may
complicate coalition formation across national
lines - Some scholars argue that political parties in the
new Central and Eastern European member states
are not easily placed in party families based on
durable ideological cleavages such as the
left-right conflict - Around 60 of MEPs from the new member countries
are members of the PES and the EPP. In general,
there is little evidence that formal affiliations
are markedly different for the new members (but
note the lack of green MEPs from the new member
states)
27Life in the post-enlargement 2004-2009 EP has
anything changed? (Based primarily on Hix and
Noury 2008)
- In general party cohesion has remained very
stable - The EPP and PES voted together almost exactly the
same amount of times in the 1999-2004 EP (65 of
the time) and in the first 18 months of the
2004-2009 Parliament (67 of the time) - In the 2004-2009 Parliament there has (so far)
been a clearer centre-right majority bloc
(ALDE-EPP/ED-UEN), while the three leftist groups
(PES, G/EFA, EUL/NGL) have been in a minority
position and have also been less united - Certain nationalities exhibit a stronger tendency
to vote against the group line Polish, British,
Danish, Swedish, and Czech MEPs
28VOTING AND COALITIONS IN THE COUNCIL (OF
MINISTERS)
- Based primarily on Mattila, Mikko (2008) Voting
and Coalitions in the Council after the
Enlargement. In Daniel Naurin Helen Wallace
(eds) Unveiling the Council of the EU Games
Governments Play in Brussels. Palgrave Macmillan
Basingstoke (forthcoming) - How has the accession of ten new member states in
2004 affected decision-making in the Council? - How has the contestation of decisions changed and
what is the role of the new member states in this
potential change? - Has the introduction of ten new members affected
coalition formation in Council voting? - How do the new members fit into the existing
political space of Council interaction?
29- Data roll call records of the Council during the
whole period of the EU25 from May 2004 to the end
of 2006 - During this period the Council decided on 416
legislative acts and 942 other acts. Of these
about 38 were decisions, 32 regulations, 8
directives, 6 joint actions and the rest
consisted of various other types of decisions
(resolutions, common positions, declarations,
agreements etc.) - Of all the decisions in the data set about 90
were agreed upon unanimously. Negative votes were
given in 8.9 and 6.2 of cases, respectively.
This means that the share of contested decisions
has not increased after the enlargement - One interpretation of this would be that the ten
new member states have been very quick to
internalise the prevailing norms of the EU
decision making, particularly the culture of
consensus
30Uncontested votes, negative votes and abstentions
by member state( of all decisions)
31Multidimensional scaling map of Council voting
32- The overall alignment of member states in the
Figure points to the existence of a north-south
dimension that affects voting patterns in the
Council. The situation has not changed in any
significant way when compared to the time before
the enlargement - At least tentatively, these results show that the
fears of a gridlock in Council decision-making in
the enlarged union were exaggerated - However, one should not draw too far-reaching
conclusions from this analysis - Roll-call data can provide only a limited and
rather superficial picture of the way the Council
operates. In order to evaluate the effects of the
enlargement in its entirety these results should
be supplemented by a more thorough analysis of
the content of contested Council decisions. In
addition, qualitative analyses based on
interviews and participant observations could
show how the day-to-day interaction in Council
bargaining has changed - Note also that bargaining in the Council (the
political space) differs most likely from
bargaining in Intergovernmental Conferences and
in the European Council!
33DEMOCRATIC DEFICIT?
- Does the EU suffer from a democratic deficit?
- Moravcsik, Andrew (2002) In Defence of the
Democratic Deficit Reassessing legitimacy in
the European Union. Journal of Common Market
Studies 404, 603-624. - Follesdal, Andreas Simon Hix (2006) Why There
is a Democratic Deficit in the EU A Response to
Majone and Moravcsik. Journal of Common Market
Studies 443, 533-562. - How to make the EU more democratic? the answer
depends on what kind of Europe one wants
(intergovernmental or supranational or
something in between?) - Note national political systems also have
serious problems of their own most notably
falling participation rates and the (alleged)
move towards spectator or audience democracy
34Definitions of the democratic deficit
- Broader definition or meaning
- limited role of the citizens in the EUs policy
process or - weak connection between public preferences and
EUs decisions - The institutional definition
- weak role of directly-elected institutions
(national parliaments and the European
Parliament) - The electoral dimension
- no election really focuses on European matters
- referendums do, but opinion is divided on whether
they should be used in integration matters
(agenda manipulation) - Lack of a European public sphere
- no European media
- no real European parties
- no European debates or European language!
35Defending supranational democracy
- Not a state, may never be one not a federation,
but operates increasingly like federal systems - Yet the EU to an increasing extent carries out
functions traditionally associated with
independent countries - Foreign and security policy
- Trade policy
- Citizenship and legal system
- Currency etc.
- A constitution that defines the competence of
the EU the jurisdiction of the Union covers
nearly all policy areas from cultural exchange
programmes to security policy - The EU already possesses significant
policy-making powers hence there should be
competition for leadership of the Union - Democracy is good for its own sake it will also
contribute to the gradual emergence of a European
identity
36Does the EU need input (democracy) or does its
legitimacy depend on outputs (results)?
- But arguably most issues that are salient for
European voters are still decided nationally
(taxation, health care, education, social and
employment policies etc.) - National politicians use the EU for solving
domestic problems, with the oversight of common
interest delegated to supranational agents
(Commission, ECJ) - Lack of common identity
- The success of integration depends primarily on
the ability of the EU to produce efficient
outputs peace and stability, economic growth,
removal of barriers to trade, counterweight to
globalization and excesses of capitalism - Low turnout in EP elections is used as an
argument against strengthening supranational
democracy
37THE FUTURE OFEU GOVERNANCE
- Limited capacity for change constitutional
amendment subject to unanimity, thus ruling out
large-scale reforms - Asymmetry of national preferences the final
outcome of IGCs reflects the configuration and
intensity of national objectives - Institutional questions have proven more
problematic than transfer of competencies
(compare with USA and Philadelphia in 1787) - Producing supranational laws through the
Community method or relying increasingly on
intergovernmental policy coordination? - The purpose of the following comparison is to
identify the strengths and weaknesses of these
two modes of EU governance, and to examine how
genuine supranational democracy would work in the
EU
38OPTION ICommunity method
- The Community method is the expression used
for the institutional operating mode for the
first pillar of the European Union -
- It has the following salient features1)
Commission monopoly of the right of initiative
2) General use of QMV in the Council - 3) An active role for the European Parliament in
co-legislating frequently with the Council - 4) Uniformity in the interpretation of Community
law ensured by the Court of Justice - The method used for the second and third pillars
is similar to the so-called intergovernmental
method, with the difference that the Commission
shares its right of initiative with the Member
States, the European Parliament is informed and
consulted and the Council may adopt binding acts.
As a general rule, the Council acts unanimously.
39OPTION IIIncreasing use of soft law and
(intergovernmental) policy coordination
- The growing use of the open method of
coordination (OMC) and other forms of policy
coordination common objectives defined by member
states and the EU, monitoring by the EU
institutions, and implementation and choice of
instruments for meeting the objectives delegated
to member states - While intergovernmental policy coordination has
been a feature of the EUs decision-making system
throughout the history of integration, such
informal policy coordination has become much more
prominent since the early 1990s - The European Employment Strategy (EES) adopted at
the Essen European Council in 1994 and the
coordination of national economic policies agreed
in the Maastricht Treaty extended this
coordination to two highly salient issue areas of
domestic politics
40- OMC became officially a part of EU jargon at the
Lisbon European Council in 2000 - OMC has four main components
- 1) Fixed guidelines set for the EU, with short-,
medium-, and long-term goals - 2) Quantitative and qualitative indicators and
benchmarks - 3) European guidelines translated into national
and regional policies and targets and - 4) Periodic monitoring, evaluation and peer
review, organized as a mutual learning process - In recent years OMC has been applied to a broad
range of policies, including employment, social
policy, environment, taxation, immigration,
research, social protection, education, social
infrastructure, regional cohesion, and social
inclusion
41- The increasing use of OMC and other forms of
informal, non-binding, primarily
intergovernmental soft law instruments needs to
be understood in the context of the sensitive
question of dividing competencies between the EU
and its member states - European integration has reached the stage where
the core areas of welfare state, such as social
policy, employment, and education are starting to
be affected. In these policy areas (that are both
money-intensive and touch core areas of national
sovereignty) it is very difficult to build the
needed consensus among national governments for
transferring policy-making authority to the
European level -- hence the resort to
intergovernmental policy coordination - The national governments want, on the one hand,
to achieve highly-valued policy objectives, such
as reducing unemployment and making their
economies more competitive, while on the other
hand they are not willing to cede formal
sovereignty to the Union
42- The Commission sees these new modes of governance
as a way to expand EUs competence in the face of
resistance from the member states - The literature on OMC and other forms of soft law
instruments or new modes of governance is
already quite extensive, and it has produced
three main findings - 1. It is still too early to make any definitive
assessments of the success of OMC. Scholars
usually point that, unlike top-down supranational
legislation, it is flexible and (supposedly)
respects subsidiarity and national autonomy. The
down-side of this non-binding nature of outputs
is that the EU has few if any means to make
national governments follow its recommendations - 2. OMC has strengthened the leadership role of
the Council (and the European Council) the
Commission has a central role to play through its
role as the institution setting objectives and
issuing guidelines to national governments
43- The EP has until now been effectively
marginalized, and, the contribution of local and
regional actors, often identified as the main
stakeholders in these processes, has so far been
quite disappointing. At the national level OMC
seems to be the preserve of a fairly small circle
of civil servants that possess expertise on the
issues. - 3. It appears that the actual impact of OMC and
other forms of informal policy coordination has
so far been relatively modest, if not even
inconsequential, in many policy areas - Trade-off between efficiency and democracy
cooperative federalism and intergovernmental
policy coordination can be seen as decision
methods prioritizing efficiency. However, the
decision process is removed from the public
sphere to intergovernmental meetings taking place
behind closed doors. As a result, cooperative
federalism weakens the transparency of collective
decision-making and, hence, the accountability of
the representatives
44Comparing the two modes of EU governance
- Agenda setting and proposal power
- In supranational legislation the Commission
basically has the monopoly of initiative, but
obviously its initiatives are largely based on
instructions from the Council and the European
Council. The OMC is much more a tool to be used
collectively by the member states, but here too
the EU institutions mainly the Commission and
the Council set the agenda and coordinate
subsequent actions - Policy competence
- In supranational legislation the competence
belongs to the EU, whereas the OMC is primarily
used in policy areas where the Union has no
access to binding legislation - Decision rule
- Most supranational legislation is passed nowadays
in the Council by QMV, but in OMC processes
issues are decided by mainly by unanimity
45- The role of the European Parliament
- The EP performs an increasing role as a
co-legislator in producing supranational laws,
but it is merely consulted (or kept informed) in
OMC - Bureaucrats vs. elected office-holders
- Civil servants are central actors in both types
of governance. However, in the OMC their role
appears to have been far more influential, with
much less guidance and instructions from members
of government - Openness and transparency
- The European Parliament meets in public the
Council is gradually moving towards deliberating
and voting on laws in public. OMC processes are
conducted behind closed doors - Policy learning
- As the OMC produces non-binding outputs, it has a
higher capacity for policy learning. In
supranational legislation the same solution
applies throughout the Union (with the partial
exception of directives)
46OPTION IIITwo models of supranational democracy
- a) Parliamentary model
- Parliamentary system the government is
accountable to the parliament (and can be voted
out of office by the latter) - The members of the lower house (EP) would be
directly elected the people while the upper
house/senate (Council) would consist of either
directly-elected representatives (as in the U.S.
Senate) or of government representatives (as in
the German Bundesrat) - Government formation would be based on elections
to the lower house and the cabinet would have to
enjoy the confidence of the lower house (or
alternatively, of both houses)
47- For the parliamentary model to work effectively,
four criteria should be met - 1) The choices offered to voters should be
identical throughout the Union (common Europarty
manifestos) - 2) The elections should be contested on the basis
of issues relevant to the Union - 3) Democratically elected party leaders would
head the campaigns (who would also be potential
future prime ministers) - 4) The party groups of the Europarties should be
cohesive enough to enable the government to
execute its programme once in office - The effective performance and durability of the
executive would require a hierarchical, cohesive
party organisation, and it is unlikely that this
would happen without giving the Europarties the
right to influence or determine candidate
selection
48- The Commission would have to be the real EU
government, thus reducing the powers of the
European Council - But, would majoritarian parliamentary democracy
work in a Union characterised by strong national
identities (and a weak European identity)? - This potential problem could be alleviated by
- 1) A constitutional rule guaranteeing all
countries representation in the government as
they currently have an own commissioner - 2) Bicameralism and demanding parliamentary
voting rules (absolute majorities, QMV) in
certain questions (like in Germany) - Would change fundamentally the role of the
Commission by making it a party-political
institution (and not anymore so much a neutral
defender of the common EU interest or a guardian
of the Treaties)
49- Government formation after the 2004 EP elections
- Alternative 1
- Grand coalition between EPP and PES (note the
absolute majority rule in the Parliament) - This would be the safest option in terms of
building the needed majorities, but it would also
lead to a weak opposition (particularly if the
ELDR was also in the government) - Alternative 2
- Centre-right coalition between EPP, ELDR (ALDE),
and possibly Greens and UEN - Alternative 3
- Centre-left minority coalition between PES,
EUL/NGL, and Greens (and possibly liberals)
50- b) Presidential model
- Importing the U.S. presidential system to the EU
- The presidential model would not put similar
pressure on the EP party groups to achieve
unitary behaviour, but would require EU-wide
parties that would each put forward a single
candidate - While this reform would undoubtedly improve the
leadership capacity of the Commission (when
coupled with strengthening its competence), it
might also lead to a two-party system, at least
in the presidential elections - The winner would either be the candidate
receiving the plurality of the votes or then a
second round would be organised between the most
successful candidates if none of the candidates
gets a majority of the votes (as in France) - 1st round candidates by EPP, PES, ELDR, Greens,
radical left (EUL-NGL), and anti-EU parties 2nd
round most likely EPP and PES
51Predicting the Future
- Strengthening parliamentarism by (a) tying the
formation of Commission more explicitly to the EP
elections -- this will also become the
constitutional rule should the Lisbon Treaty
enter into force and (b) extending the use of
co-decision procedure and QMV in the Council - Simultaneously most of the member states and
their main parties emphasize maintaining the
European Council (and the Council) as the leading
decision bodies. The presidential version
receives only very marginal support - OMC, together with other forms of soft law,
will be used to an increasing extent
particularly as it is so difficult to transfer
new law-making powers to the European level
52FINAL QUESTIONS
- 1) Will the unanimity rule in amending the
Treaties and in other important matters lead to
increasing use of flexibility (enhanced
cooperation)? According to the Lisbon Treaty at
least 1/3 of the member states must want to
co-operate, and others must be free to join - 2) Should EU have a stronger role in carrying out
redistributive policies? Are the EU citizens
willing to support active EU fiscal or regional
policies (compare with Belgium, Canada and
Switzerland)? Note the lack of common identity
(emotional attachment) or feeling of a political
community! - 3) How to connect citizens to EU decision-making?
In EP elections parties have campaigned primarily
on domestic political issues. EU questions are
marginalized also in national elections, and thus
no electoral forum focuses directly on EU. More
precisely, should constitutional amendment be
subject to referendum?