Title: Economic Growth in the Long 20th Century
1Economic Growth in the Long 20th Century
2Table 1. Real GDP/Head (UK 100 in each year)
USA West Germany France
1870 76.6 58.8
1913 107.8 70.8
1950 137.7 61.7 74.7
1964 133.5 101.3 92.2
1979 142.7 115.9 111.1
1997 133.7 100.9 95.4
2007 124.9 88.9 86.8
Sources The Conference Board (2014) and West
Germany in 2007 calculated from Statistiches
Bundesamt Deutschland.
3Table 5. Contributions to Growth in Market
Sector, 1873-2007 ( per year).
Education K/HW TFP Y/HW
UK
1873-1913 0.3 0.4 0.2 0.9
1924-1937 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.7
1950-1973 0.5 1.5 1.4 3.4
1973-1995 0.4 1.2 1.3 2.6
1995-2007 0.4 1.0 1.0 2.6
Germany
1950-1973 0.4 2.3 2.5 5.2
1973-1995 0.3 1.1 1.3 2.7
1995-2007 0.0 1.0 0.7 1.7
United States
1871-1890 0.0 0.8 1.0 1.8
1890-1905 0.1 0.5 1.3 1.9
1905-1927 0.2 0.5 1.4 2.1
1929-1948 0.4 0.1 1.5 2.0
1950-1973 0.3 0.9 1.5 2.7
1973-1995 0.3 0.5 0.4 1.2
1995-2007 0.3 1.2 1.1 2.6
4Did Victorian Britain Fail?
- New Economic History said NO! subsequent
research says this is a bit too strong - Competition in a very open economy was central to
the NEH argument (McCloskey Sandberg, 1971) if
correct, implies Golden-Age UK much more
susceptible to failure - But examples skewed to tradeables look at a
sector (railways) where competition and
shareholders are both weak and productivity
performance is much more questionable
5The Managed Economy Strategy of the 1930s
- Post-1932 dirty floating, cartels, tariffs
understandably seen as damage limitation and a
way to restore profitability - This implied a major reduction in competition
which lasted well into the post-war period - The reduction in competition reduced productivity
growth both before and after WWII (Broadberry
Crafts, 1992, 1996) - No evidence that imposing tariffs was good for
productivity growth (Broadberry Crafts, 2011) - The claim that the 1930s represents an antidote
to Victorian failure is seriously misleading
6Relative Economic Decline in the Golden Age
- The UK growth failure in 1950-73 was about 0.75
pp per year - Supply-side policy was badly designed and
undermined incentives to invest and to innovate - Policy was seriously constrained by accepting the
trade union veto in seeking to maintain full
employment - Competition was much weaker than pre-WWI
7Traditional Criticisms of Post-WWII British
Industry
- Weak and incompetent management
- Difficult industrial relations
- Seriously inefficient use of inputs
- NB these were all nurtured by inadequate
competition in product markets interacting with
the historical legacy
8Institutional Legacies (1)
- By the later 20th century, the UK was
characterized by an unusual degree of separation
of ownership and control (Cheffins, 2008) - Relatively few large firms had a dominant
external shareholder principal-agent problems a
big concern, especially when competition was weak - UK followed a path from 19th-century origins to
Anglo-American (rather than German) capitalism
promoted by revisions to company law, taxation,
transition from personal to institutional
investors
9Institutional Legacies (2)
- The early start produced a distinctive and
persistent British system of industrial
relations - Characteristics include craft control, legal
immunities, multi-unionism, TUC rather than LO,
effort bargains that influenced technical choice - E.g., the British system of mass production
(Lewchuk, 1987) - 19th-century organizational structures became
dysfunctional but employers did not find it
worthwhile to pay the price/take the risk to
abolish them
10Competition and Productivity Growth
- Competition is strongly positive for productivity
outcomes in UK firms without dominant shareholder
(Nickell et al., 1997) - Competition promotes better management practices
(Bloom van Reenen, 2007) - 1956 Act led to significant improvement in
productivity performance in formerly-cartelized
sectors (Symeonidis, 2008)
11Impact of Increased Competition (1)
- Increases in competition correlated with 1980s
productivity growth at sectoral level (Haskel,
1991) - Openness promoted TFP growth in catch-up model
for manufacturing sectors post-1970 (Proudman
Redding, 1998) - Single Market shock improved TFP performance in
plants exposed to agency problems (Griffith,
2001), raised patenting in close-to-frontier
industries (Aghion et al., 2009) - Post-1980, competition for corporate control
meant restructuring and divestment in large firms
(Toms Wright, 2002) management buyouts raised
TFP (Harris et al., 2005)
12Impact of Increased Competition (2)
- During the 1980s and 1990s, increased competition
reduced union membership, union wage mark-ups and
union effects on productivity (Brown et al.,
2008 Metcalf, 2002) - Surge of productivity growth in unionized firms
in 1980s as organizational change took place
under pressure of competition (Machin Wadhwani,
1989) - De-recognition of unions in face of increased
foreign competition had strong effect on
productivity growth in late 1980s (Gregg et al.,
1993)
13UK in the ICT Age
- Invests relatively large amount in ICT capital
with positive productivity effects - This requires reorganization and is supported by
light regulation - This would not have happened with 1970s-style
industrial relations and weak competition
14Table 11. Sources of labour productivity growth
in the market sector, 1995-2007 ( per year)
Labour Quality ICTK/HW Non-ICT K/HW TFP Growth Y/LGrowth
France 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.9 1.9
Germany 0.0 0.5 0.5 0.7 1.7
UK 0.4 0.8 0.4 1.0 2.6
USA 0.3 0.9 0.3 1.2 2.6
Source van Ark (2011)