Title: Chapter 4 Utility
1Chapter 4Utility
2Introduction
- Last chapter we talk about preference, describing
the ordering of what a consumer prefers. - For a more convenient mathematical treatment, we
turn this ordering into a mathematical function.
3Utility Functions
- A utility function U Rn?R maps each consumption
bundle of n goods into a real number that
satisfies the following conditions x
x U(x) gt U(x) x
x U(x) lt U(x) x x
U(x) U(x).
p
p
4Utility Functions
- Not all theoretically possible preferences have a
utility function representation. - Technically, a preference relation that is
complete, transitive and continuous has a
corresponding continuous utility function.
5Utility Functions
- Utility is an ordinal (i.e. ordering) concept.
- The number assigned only matters about ranking,
but the sizes of numerical differences are not
meaningful. - For example, if U(x) 6 and U(y) 2, then
bundle x is strictly preferred to bundle y. But
x is not preferred three times as much as is y.
6An Example
- Consider only three bundles A, B, C.
- The following three are all valid utility
functions of the preference.
7Utility Functions
- There is no unique utility function
representation of a preference relation. - Suppose U(x1,x2) x1x2 represents a preference
relation. - Consider the bundles (4,1), (2,3) and (2,2).
- U(2,3) 6 gt U(4,1) U(2,2) 4.That
is, (2,3) (4,1) (2,2).
p
8Utility Functions
- Define V U2.
- Then V(x1,x2) x12x22 and V(2,3) 36 gt
V(4,1) V(2,2) 16.So again, (2,3)
(4,1) (2,2). - V preserves the same order as U and so represents
the same preferences.
p
9Utility Functions
- Define W 2U 10.
- Then W(x1,x2) 2x1x210. So, W(2,3) 22
gt W(4,1) W(2,2) 18. - Again, (2,3) (4,1)
(2,2). - W preserves the same order as U and V and so
represents the same preferences.
p
10Utility Functions
- If
- U is a utility function that represents a
preference relation and - f is a strictly increasing function,
- then V f(U) is also a utility
functionrepresenting . - Clearly, V(x)gtV(y) if and only if f(V(x)) gt
f(V(y)) by definition of increasing function.
11(No Transcript)
12Ordinal vs. Cardinal
- As you will see, for our analysis of consumer
choices, an ordinal utility is enough. - If the numerical differences are also meaningful,
we call it cardinal. - For example, money, weight, height are all
cardinal.
13Utility Functions Indiff. Curves
- An indifference curve contains equally preferred
bundles. - Equal preference ? same utility level.
- Therefore, all bundles on the same indifference
curve must have the same utility level.
14Utility Functions Indiff. Curves
15Utility Functions Indiff. Curves
U6
U5
U4
U3
U2
U1
16Goods, Bads and Neutrals
- A good is a commodity which increases your
utility (gives a more preferred bundle) when you
have more of it. - A bad is a commodity which decreases your utility
(gives a less preferred bundle) when you have
more of it. - A neutral is a commodity which does not change
your utility (gives an equally preferred bundle)
when you have more of it.
17Goods, Bads and Neutrals
Utility
Utilityfunction
Units ofwater aregoods
Units ofwater arebads
Water
x
Around x units, a little extra water is a
neutral.
18Some Other Utility Functions and Their
Indifference Curves
- Consider V(x1,x2) x1 x2.
- What do the indifference curves look like?
- What relation does this function represent for
these two goods?
19Perfect Substitutes
x2
x1 x2 5
13
x1 x2 9
9
x1 x2 13
5
V(x1,x2) x1 x2.
x1
5
9
13
These two goods are perfect substitutes for this
consumer.
20Some Other Utility Functions and Their
Indifference Curves
- Consider W(x1,x2) minx1,x2.
- What do the indifference curves look like?
- What relation does this function represent for
these two goods?
21Perfect Complements
x2
45o
W(x1,x2) minx1,x2
minx1,x2 8
8
minx1,x2 5
5
3
minx1,x2 3
x1
3
5
8
These two goods are perfect complements for this
consumer.
22Perfect Substitutes and Perfect Complements
- In general, a utility function for perfect
substitutes can be expressed as u (x, y)
ax by - And a utility function for perfect complements
can be expressed as u (x, y) min ax ,
by for constants a and b.
23Some Other Utility Functions and Their
Indifference Curves
- A utility function of the form
U(x1,x2) f(x1) x2is linear in just x2 and
is called quasi-linear. - For example, U(x1,x2) 2x11/2 x2.
24Quasi-linear Indifference Curves
x2
Each curve is a vertically shifted copy of the
others.
x1
25Some Other Utility Functions and Their
Indifference Curves
- Any utility function of the form
U(x1,x2) x1a x2bwith a gt 0 and b gt 0 is
called a Cobb-Douglas utility function. - For example, U(x1,x2) x11/2 x21/2, (a b
1/2), and V(x1,x2) x1 x23 , (a 1, b 3).
26Cobb-Douglas Indifference Curves
x2
All curves are hyperbolic,asymptoting to, but
nevertouching any axis.
x1
27Cobb-Douglas Utility Functions
- By a monotonic transformation Vln(U)U( x, y)
xa y b implies - V( x, y) a ln (x) b ln(y).
- Consider another transformation WU1/(ab)W( x,
y) xa/(ab) y b/(ab) xc y 1-c so that the
sum of the indices becomes 1.
28Marginal Utilities
- Marginal means incremental.
- The marginal utility of commodity i is the
rate-of-change of total utility as the quantity
of commodity i consumed changes i.e.
29Marginal Utilities
- For example, if U(x1,x2) x11/2 x22, then
30Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates of
Substitution
- The general equation for an indifference curve
is U(x1,x2) º k, a constant. - Totally differentiating this identity gives
31Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates of
Substitution
It can be rearranged to
32Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates of
Substitution
And
can be furthermore rearranged to
This is the MRS (slope of the indifference curve).
33A Note
- In some texts, economists refer to the MRS by its
absolute value that is, as a positive number. - However, we will still follow our convention.
- Therefore, the MRS is
34MRS and MU
- Recall that MRS measures how many units of good 2
youre willing to sacrifice for one more unit of
good 1 to remain the original utility level. - One unit of good 1 is worth MU1.
- One unit of good 2 is worth MU2.
- Number of units of good 2 you are willing to
sacrifice for one unit of good 1 is thus MU1 /
MU2.
35An Example
- Suppose U(x1,x2) x1x2. Then
so
36An Example
U(x1,x2) x1x2
x2
8
MRS(1,8) -8/1 -8 MRS(6,6) - 6/6
-1.
6
U 36
U 8
x1
1
6
37MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions
- A quasi-linear utility function is of the form
U(x1,x2) f(x1) x2.
Therefore,
38MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions
- MRS - f'(x1) depends only on x1 but not on x2.
So the slopes of the indifference curves for a
quasi-linear utility function are constant along
any line for which x1 is constant. - What does that make the indifference map for a
quasi-linear utility function look like?
39MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions
x2
Each curve is a vertically shifted copy of the
others.
MRS -f(x1)
MRS -f(x1)
MRS is a constantalong any line for which x1
isconstant.
x1
x1
x1
40Monotonic Transformations Marginal Rates of
Substitution
- Applying a monotonic (increasing) transformation
to a utility function representing a preference
relation simply creates another utility function
representing the same preference relation. - What happens to marginal rates of substitution
when a monotonic transformation is applied?
41Monotonic Transformations Marginal Rates of
Substitution
- For U(x1,x2) x1x2 , MRS -x2/x1.
- Create V U2 i.e. V(x1,x2) x12x22. What is
the MRS for V?which is the same as the MRS
for U.
42Monotonic Transformations Marginal Rates of
Substitution
- More generally, if V f(U) where f is a strictly
increasing function, then
The MRS does not change with a monotonic
transformation. Thus, the same preference with
different utility functions still show the same
MRS.