Title: The U.S. Electoral College
1The U.S. Electoral College
2How the EC Works in Practice
- Instead of electing a President (and Vice
President) in a single national election on
Presidential election day, - we have 51 separate state ( DC) elections,
- in which voters (reasonably enough but
incorrectly) think they are voting directly for a
Presidential/Vice Presidential ticket. - the plurality winner in each state (except ME and
NE) wins all of the states electoral votes
(winner-take-all) - which are equal in number to the states total
representation in Congress, - i.e., its House seats 2
- plus DC has 3 electoral votes, so
- total EV 538, and
- these electoral votes are added up to determine
the winner of the election, - with 270 required for election.
- Thus in practice (about 95 of the time), the EC
is merely a vote counting system that - takes the popular votes in each state,
- automatically translates them into nationwide
electoral votes, and - declares a winner.
3Implication of the EC in PracticeBattleground/
Swing States
- The principal implication of the EC in practice
is that it creates battleground (or swing)
states, because - it matters only which party ticket carries a
state, - and not what the margin of victory or defeat is.
- cf. marginal constituencies in the UK.
- Hence states that are expected to be close become
battlegrounds while other are substantially
ignored. - Today (frequent and relatively accurate) state
polls make it easier to identify battleground
states. - Until a decade or two ago, there were relatively
few state (as opposed to national) polls. - Contemporary campaign resources (especially TV on
local channels and cable services) ads can be
both - focused on particular states, and
- can moved from one state to another,
- in contrast to
- party organization rooted in states and
localities in the 19th century, and - national TV advertising (mid- to later-20th
century).
4More Esoteric EC Details
- Lurking beneath electoral votes are real people
called Presidential electors, - who voters actually vote for on Presidential
election day, - who are actually elected on Presidential election
day, and - who actually cast the electoral votes (about six
weeks later). - Underlying the winner-take-all system is the
fact that (in almost universal practice)
Presidential electors are elected not
individually but on statewide party slates
(general ticket system). - The Constitution gives state legislature the
power to determine how their states electors are
elected (or appointed). - A variety of methods other than winner-take-all
for selecting Presidential electors have been
used by some states in the past, which could
often produce split electoral votes from a state. - Indeed, at the present time, ME (since 1972) and
NE (since 1992) do not award electoral votes on a
winner-take-all basis, - but rather on the basis of the Modified District
Plan, - so their electoral votes may be split (though in
fact this never happened until 2008 in NE).
5Esoteric Details (cont.)
- Party nominees may occasionally be deprived of
electoral votes by faithless electors, - who cast electoral votes in a way that
contradicts their pledge to support their party
ticket, and - in a way that does not reflect popular vote in
the state - and produces a split electoral vote from a state.
- If no candidate wins 270 electoral votes, either
because - a third candidate wins some electoral votes or
- there is a (mathematically possible) 269-269 tie,
- the election is thrown into the House of
Representatives (which last happened in 1824), - where voting by state delegation (one delegation
one vote). - A number of elections have other displayed
electoral vote oddities --- for example - President Truman received no votes in AL in 1948,
- President Johnson received no votes in AL in
1964, - because no elector candidates pledged to these
Presidents were on the ballot. - unpledged electors were elected in AL and MS in
1960. - Even presumptive experts (e.g., textbook authors)
often mischaracterize esoteric features of the
Electoral College. - Adkinson and Elliot, The Electoral College A
Misunderstood Institution, PS, March 1997
6Evaluating the Electoral College
- Alexander Hamilton, Federalist 68
- The mode of appointment of the Chief Magistrate
of the United States is almost the only part of
the system, of any consequence, which has escaped
without severe censure, or which has received the
slightest mark of approbation from its opponents.
. . . I venture somewhat further, and hesitate
not to affirm that if the manner of it be not
perfect, it is at least excellent. - Actually there were some Antifederalist
criticisms of the mode of appointment of the
Chief Magistrate, but they were not among the
leading arguments against the proposed
Constitution. - Many subsequent evaluations (and the many
proposed constitutional amendments) suggest a
less favorable assessment of the mode of
appointment of the Chief Magistrate, - Range of evaluations the Electoral College was
- part of a generally elitist and anti-democratic
constitution or - a last-minute jerry-built compromise or perhaps
- a well designed compromise among diverse
considerations, or possibly - the embodiment of well-thought-out selection
criteria.
7Evaluating the Electoral College (cont.)
- Today, as a rough generalization,
- liberals mostly criticize the Electoral College
and advocate its replacement by a national
popular vote, e.g., - George Edwards, Why the Electoral College is Bad
for America, and - Neal R. Peirce, The Peoples President,
- while conservatives mostly oppose a national
popular vote and defend the existing Electoral
College, e.g., - Judith Best, assigned reading on webpage and The
Case Against Direct Election of the President,
and - Tara Ross, Enlightened Democracy The Case for
the Electoral College (with an Introduction by
George Will).
8Evaluating the Electoral College (cont.)
- However, in the mid-20th century liberals
mostly defended the existing Electoral College
system, which they viewed as having features that
- enhanced the voting power of major constituencies
of the New Deal, in particular, - urban dwellers,
- racial and ethnic minorities, and
- union members,
- and which counterbalanced the rural and
conservative advantage - in the malapportioned House of the that era, and
- In the malapportioned Senate of every era.
- In that era, proposals to modify (but not
abolish) the Electoral College (the Modified
District and Proportional Plans) were supported
mostly by conservatives.)
9Evaluating the Electoral College (cont.)
- My own take on the Electoral College (Why the
Electoral College Is Good for Political
Science) - The original EC was a compromise among diverse
considerations that was cleverly designed but had
a fatal flaw that had to be (and was) corrected
by the 12th Amendment to the Constitution in
1804. - The original EC established a selection system
- that was designed to operate in a non-partisan
environment, but - did not operate satisfactorily once political
parties formed to contest Presidential selection. - The EC was rapidly transformed into an
institution quite different from its designers
had intended. - So, even if you like the existing EC, you cant
really give credit to the wisdom of the framers
of the Constitution. - Likewise, even if you dislike the existing EC,
you cant really blame the framers. - The transformed EC has proved to be a serviceable
institution but is problematic in a number of
ways.
10Why the Electoral College is Good for Political
Science
- Moreover, the Electoral College is a terrific
boon for political science research and teaching
-- hence, my title (a play on the title of the
Edwards book). - the origins of the Electoral College and applied
social theory - unanticipated consequences in institutional
design - political strategy and institutional equilibrium
- voting power in weighted voting systems
- comparative institutional analysis
- individual voting power and the Electoral
College - election inversions
- Electoral College deadlock
- circumventing formal structure through commitment.
11Problems with the EC in Practice
- It typically produces a disparity between popular
and electoral vote proportions, which - almost always exaggerates the winners margin,
for example - Popular Vote Electoral Vote
- 2008 Obama 53 365
- McCain 46 173
- But is this really a problem?
-
12Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
- It disenfranchises voters in non-battleground
states. - On the other hand, are all voters
disenfranchised in landslide elections? - It produces a small state advantage resulting
from the apportionment of electoral votes. - Regardless of population, every state
- has two Senators, and
- at least one House seat, and therefore
- has at least three electoral votes.
- It produces a large state advantage resulting
from the winner-take-all system (not fixed by the
Constitution) in casting electoral votes. - But can both of the problems be true?
13Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
- An creates an incentive for disputes or fraud
concerning vote counting in pivotal states, - e.g., Florida in 2000.
- But with a close national popular vote, any such
dispute would be nationwide. - It tolerates an absence of national standards for
- voter qualifications,
- voter registration,
- voting technology,
- ballot access, etc.
- But imposing national standards might be
controversial. - It is subject to spoiler effects, so that
- the presence or absence of a third candidate who
cannot win the election may tip the outcome
between the two major candidates, - e.g., Nader (and possibly Buchanan) in 2000.
- But in fact, every electoral system whatsoever is
vulnerable in some degree to spoiler effects.
14Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
- It can produces minority Presidents,
- who win less than a majority of the popular vote,
but - are elected on the basis winning a majority
(270) of electoral votes, e.g., - Bush in 2000,
- Clinton in both 1996 and 1992,
- Nixon in 1968,
- Kennedy in 1960,
- Truman in 1948,
- Wilson in both 1916 and 1912.
- But many electoral systems do the equivalent.
- The British refer to such an effect as a
manufactured majority. - Every British election since WWII has produced a
manufactured majority except the two (February
1974 and May 2010) that did not produce any
majority (that produced a hung Parliament),
i.e., - in which the leading party held fewer than half
the seats in House of Commons.
15Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
- Most important, it produces election inversions
(or reversals of winners, wrong winners, EC
misfires, etc.) in which - a candidate who wins less than a plurality of the
popular vote - is elected on the basis of electoral votes.
- Popular Vote Electoral Vote
- 2000 Bush (R) 47.87 271
- Gore (D) 48.38 267
- 1888 Harrison (R) 47.80
233 - Cleveland (D) 48.63
168 - 1876 Hayes (R) 51
185 - Tilden (D) 48 184
- 1960(?) Kennedy (D) 49.464 (?)
303 - Nixon (R) 49.548 (?) 219
16Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
- The election inversion problem is usually
regarded as the most serious flaw in the
Electoral College. - In fact, every districted electoral system is
subject to election inversions. - Election inversions occur in parliamentary
systems as well as U.S. Presidential elections
(but get less attention). - Votes Seats
- UK 1951 Conservative 47.97 321
- Labour 48.78 295
- In fact, election inversions can occur under
(list) proportional representation systems - Netherlands 2010 VVDPVDCDA 49.55
76 - All other parties 50.45
74 - This coalition of parties actually formed the
government.
17Problems with Details of the EC
- Unpledged or faithless electors might determine
the outcome of the election. - But this is unlikely --- theyre looking for
their 15 minutes of fame. - State legislatures can manipulate the manner of
selecting electors. - Colorado Proposition 36 in 2004 (Democratic
supported initiative) - Republican efforts in CA in 2008 and PA in 2012
- If a state decides to select electors by
district, the districts may be gerrymandered. - A state legislature might decide to appoint
electors. - There is no constitutional right to vote for
President (or even Presidential electors). - The most problematic feature of the Electoral
College is Contingent Procedure (when an election
is thrown into the House). - We have little understanding of how this would
work in practice. - State equality regardless of population appears
to be unsupportable (especially today, e.g., CA
vs. WY) - A President would not be selected until about two
weeks before Inauguration Day (if then).
18Alternatives to the Existing Electoral College
System
- As we have noted, some changes in the EC system
can by made by individual state legislatures, - namely, how their electors are selected and thus
how state electoral votes are cast
(winner-take-all or otherwise). - Other changes would require an amendment to the
Constitution, e.g., - to change or abolish position of electors,
- change the apportionment of electors/electoral
votes among the states, or - abolish or change the contingent procedure.
- Of course, a constitutional amendment is also
required to make nationally uniform changes in
how electors are selected and electoral votes are
cast. - Congress cant direct change the EC by simple
legislation however, it can - change the size of the House or Representatives,
- admit new states (and thus increase the size of
the Senate), - both of which would change the size of the
Electoral College and the magnitude of the small
state advantage in the apportionment of electoral
votes), and - change the method of apportioning House seats
among the states on the basis of the decennial
census.
19Alternatives to the Existing EC System (cont.)
- The Automatic Plan. Regularize the existing
system by abolishing the position of elector
while retaining electoral votes to be
automatically awarded on a winner-take-all basis
to the popular-vote winner in each state. - This requires a U.S. constitutional amendment,
which probably should abolish or revise the
contingent procedure as well. - The Pure District Plan. Select electors by
plurality vote in single-member districts within
states. - This can be implemented on a state-by-state
basis. - But if it is effected by a constitutional
amendment, it should probably revise the
contingent procedure as well. - The Modified District Plan. Select electors by
plurality in the existing single-member
Congressional Districts, with the two remaining
(Senatorial) electors elected state-wide. - This can be implemented on a state-by-state basis
(as ME and NE have done). - The Mundt-Coudert Plan proposed this as a
constitutional amendment in the 1950s and in
revised form in the 1960s. - It modified the contingent procedure to a joint
ballot of the whole Congress voting as
individuals.
20Alternatives to the Existing EC System (cont.)
- The (Pure) Proportional Plan. Award the
electoral votes of each state to candidates
precisely (out to three or more decimal places)
in proportion to their popular votes within each
state. - Since fractional electoral votes would result,
the office of elector would have to be abolished. - This therefore requires a constitutional
amendment, which should probably abolish or
revise the contingent procedure as well. - The Lodge-Gossett Plan proposed this as a
constitutional amendment in the 1940s and 1950s, - and it modified the contingent procedure to a
joint ballot of the whole Congress voting as
individuals. - The Whole-Number Proportional Plan. Award the
electoral votes of each state to candidates in
whole numbers that are proportional as possible
to their popular votes within the states. - An established PR apportionment formula could be
used. - Since electors could be retained, this can be
implemented on a state-by-state basis, - e.g., Colorado Proposition 36 in 2004 (using an
ad hoc PR formula). - But if it is effected by a constitutional
amendment, it should probably abolish or revise
the contingent procedure as well, - especially as minor candidate could more easily
win electoral votes.
21Alternatives to the Existing EC System (cont.)
- The National Bonus Plan. Retain the existing
system (or use the Automatic Plan) but award an
additional bonus of perhaps 102 electoral votes
to the national popular vote plurality winner. - This would require a U.S. constitutional
amendment. - Its obvious rationale is to preclude election
inversions and it would effectively preclude the
contingent procedure as well. - Revision of Contingent Procedure. Many options
exist, but these have received the most
attention - abolish the electoral vote majority requirement
for election entirely, or - reduce the majority requirement, and/or
- change the nature of the contingent procedure,
i.e., - to election by a joint session of Congress,
voting one-member, one-vote. - But the problem of electoral vote ties (which
also leads to the contingent procedure) remains
so long as the number of electoral votes is even. - The current problem was created by the 23rd
Amendment giving DC three electoral votes
(starting in 1964).
22Alternatives to the Existing EC System (cont.)
- The Popular Vote Plan. Abolish the Electoral
college in its entirety and hold a national
direct popular election for President (and Vice
President), - with or without an runoff (instant or
otherwise), and - perhaps (if a runoff is used) using a 40 (rather
than 50) quota for election in the first round. - This would require a constitutional amendment.
- Such a national popular vote might/should entail
national administration of Presidential (and
Congressional, while were at it?) elections,
including - nationally uniform voter qualifications,
- national voter registration (and voter ID
requirements,if any), - nationally uniform ballot types and voting
technology, - nationally uniform rules for ballot access
(listing of candidates), etc.
23The National Popular Vote Plan
24National Popular Vote Plan (cont.)
- This is a proposal to (in effect) enact a direct
national popular election for President - without using a constitutional amendment,
- which requires ratification by three-quarters of
the states, - and is therefore believed to be very difficult to
obtain. - Its starting point is the fact that, under the
Constitution, - state legislatures have sole power over how their
Presidential electors are selected.
25National Popular Vote Plan (cont.)
- NPVP proposes that states collectively
controlling at least 270 electoral votes - enter into an interstate compact
- that would commit them to select Presidential
electors who would cast their electoral votes, - not for the candidate who carries their state,
but - for the national popular vote winner.
- Note that national popular vote winner means
plurality winner, so - NPVP would also preclude the House contingent
procedure - barring a national popular vote tie.
26Problems with the NPVP
- NPVP does not (and cannot) address the problems
entailed by direct popular vote previously
identified in particular, - national rules for and administration of
Presidential elections and - runoff or related provisions
- There is no officially certified national
popular vote winner. - Would the compact hold, especially in the event
of an extremely close/disputed (with respect to
the national popular vote) election? - In every election, some states in the compact
would have to cast electoral votes for the
candidate that lost the popular vote in that
state. - In some (close) elections, such electoral votes
would be decisive. - In particular, would the compact hold in the
event that there would otherwise be an election
inversion (the very event the NPVP is designed to
preclude)?
27Why Do We Have an Electoral College?
- The answer goes back to 1787 and the framing of
the U.S. Constitution. - The charge to the Constitutional Convention was
to revise and strengthen the Articles of
Confederation. - Under the A of C, the only central government
institution was Congress. - Each state legislature appointed Congressional
delegates. - Each state delegation had one vote (the same rule
was used in the Constitutional Convention). - A 9/13 supra-majority was required for
substantive matters. - 13/13 unanimity was required to amend the A of C.
- Congress had very limited powers in particular,
- It could not lay and collect taxes, and
- It could not pass laws that directly exercised
its powers. - In both respects, Congress had to rely on the
cooperation of state legislatures. - There was no national executive or judiciary.
28Why Do We Have an Electoral College? (cont.)
- The Constitution
- expanded the powers of Congress and
- allowed Congress to exercise its powers by
passing laws that bound individuals directly, and - that would be executed by a national executive
(President), who also had other independent
powers, and - that would be enforced by a national court
system. - The executive (and judiciary) would also check
and balance the naturally predominant
legislature.
29Designing The Original Electoral College
- Designing the mode of selecting the President was
one of the most difficult tasks that confronted
the framers. - Their most famously difficult task was designing
the scheme of representation for a new national
legislature. - The difficulty in the legislative case lay in the
fact that most delegates knew what they wanted,
but different delegates wanted different things - small-state delegates wanted to preserve the
principle of state equality, while - large-state delegates wanted state representation
proportional to state population (and/or wealth).
- In contrast, the difficulty in the executive case
was that most delegates were not at all sure what
they wanted, - though the small-state versus big-state conflict
remained a factor).
30Designing The Original Electoral College
- The menu of options for Presidential selection
- Selection by states,
- But this would be too much like the Article
Confederation - Selection by the Congress,
- which was the default option found in both VA
and NJ plans. - But many feared it would make the President too
dependent on and (if eligible for re-election)
subservient to Congress. - How would a bicameral Congress (as provided for
by the Great Compromise) elect a President? - House only
- Senate only
- concurrent ballot
- joint ballot
- Selection by some kind of popular election
- which presented many practical difficulties.
- Some kind of mixed system, which might
distinguish between - a first round of selection (nomination) and
- a second round of selection (election or
runoff), and - might use intermediate electors.
31Designing The Original EC (cont.)
- The perceived advantages of an Electoral College
of intermediate electors - unlike Congress, the EC would perform a single
task i.e., cast votes for President -- and
would then disband, so - the President would be subservient to neither
Congress nor the Electoral College and - unlike popular election, the EC
- avoided difficult questions about the extent of
suffrage, and - allowed a compromise between the large vs. small
states through its fine details, and - and public opinion could be informed and refined
through representation. - Since legislative election was the default
choice, it is more accurate to say the framers
settled on the EC - as an alternative to legislative election, rather
than - as an alternative to popular election.
32The Original Electoral College Rules
- Each state selects a number of electors equal
in number to its total (House Senate)
representation in Congress (H 2). - The legislature of each state determines the mode
of selection of the electors from its state, the
most likely options being - Election/appointment by the legislature itself,
- popular election from districts, and
- popular election on a state-wide general ticket.
- Congress has the power to determine
- when electors are selected, and
- when electors cast their votes (which must be the
same day for all states). - Originally, Congress gave the states a window of
about 30 days within which to select electors.
33The Original Electoral College (cont.)
- The Electoral College never meets as a group in
one place. - Rather electors meet and vote in their own state
capitals - Electors were originally required to
- cast two votes for two different candidates,
- at least one of whom had to be a resident of
another state, - In effect, electors could vote for one favorite
son but were required also vote for at least one
national candidate. - Once cast, the electoral votes are each are
transmitted to Congress, - to be counted before a joint session presided
over by the President of the Senate (Vice
President of U.S.). - To be elected by the Electoral College, a
candidate was originally required to receive - votes from a majority of electors and
- more votes than any other candidate.
- Given this double vote system, these requirements
were logically distinct. - In particular, more that one candidate could
receive the required majority.
34The Original Electoral College (cont.)
- If no candidate met both requirements, the
election would be thrown into the House of
Representatives. - The House chooses
- between the two (or more) tied candidates, in the
event both (or all) received votes from a
majority of electors, or - (in the original EC) among the top five
candidates, in the event no candidate received
votes from a majority of electors. - Voting in the House is by state delegation, with
each delegation casting one vote. - Balloting continues until some candidate is
supported by a majority of state delegations.
35The Fatal Flaw in the Original Electoral College
- However, the Committee was concerned that some
electors might throw away their second votes. - It believed a second office had to be at stake to
induce electors to take their second votes
seriously. - For this reason (only), it proposed the office of
Vice President. - The Vice Presidency was introduced only for the
sake of a valuable mode of election which
required two to be chosen at the same time, - which largely explains the awkward and largely
impotent place this office occupies in the
overall constitutional scheme. - This turned out to be a miscalculation that
produced a fatal flaw in the original EC, - and created what historian Richard McCormick has
called a hazardous game of Presidential
selection.
36The Electoral College An Example
- THE ORIGINAL ELECTORAL COLLEGE BEFORE THE 12th
AMENDMENT AND USING THE PROVISIONAL APPORTIONMENT
OF HOUSE SEATS - House Size 65
- Number of Electors 65 (2 13) 91
- Number of Electoral Votes 2 91 182
- Maximum Vote Any Candidate Can Receive 91 (one
vote from every elector) - Required Majority 46 (one vote from a majority
of electors) - If no one gets 46 votes or if there is a tie
among those who do - Required Vote in House 7
- In any event, the runner-up becomes Vice
President - Note these numbers were never actually used.
37Expectations Concerning the Original EC
- This original Electoral College system was
designed to operate in a non-partisan
environment. - It therefore was expected that
- typically there would be many potential
Presidential candidates, - who would not declare themselves as such, let
alone actively campaign for the office, and - electors would choose among these candidates on
the basis of their character and connections, not
party affiliation or policy promises. - Therefore, it was also expected that electoral
votes would be widely scattered and the House
contingent procedure would be used 19 times out
of 20 (George Masons estimate), so - big states would have the dominant role in
screening/nominating candidates (in the EC),
while - small states would have equal role in most
final/runoff elections (in the House).
38Expectations Concerning the EC (cont.)
- However, James Madison (a big-state advocate)
thought/hoped that big state electors would
coordinate their electoral votes so as to keep
the election out of the House (where small states
would have the advantage). - Madison, not Mason, was correct in his
expectation, but not for the reason he gave. - It was generally hoped and expected that electors
would typically be - popularly elected
- from single-member districts (like most state
legislators, delegates to the state ratifying
conventions, members of the British House of
Commons, and as was expected also for members of
the new U.S. House) and - that they would be well-informed local notables
who would act as representative trustees of their
states and districts.
39The Hazardous Game President Selection under the
Original Electoral College
- There were problems from the very start.
- From the outset, electors and those who selected
them (and most everyone else) thought of a
presidential election, not as an occasion to cast
two votes for two worthy presidential candidates,
but as an occasion to elect a Presidential-Vice
Presidential ticket. - In the very first election of 1789, it was
generally agreed that - George Washington should be the first President,
and - John Adams should be the first Vice President.
- Most or all electors were expected to cast one
vote for Washington and one vote for Adams.
40The Hazardous Game (cont.)
- But this expectation was precarious
- If just one elector were to cast one vote for
Adams and one vote for anybody but Washington,
Adams would be elected President and Washington
would be relegated to the Vice Presidency. - On the other hand, if every elector did in fact
cast one vote for Washington and one for Adams,
there would be an electoral vote tie, sending the
election to the House. - Indeed, Alexander Hamilton (who disliked Adams)
was afraid that some New England electors would
withhold votes from Washington, thereby making
Adams president. - In anticipation of this, he urged some other
electors to withhold votes from Adams. - In fact, all electors voted for Washington but
quite a few did not vote for Adams, - so in fact the agreed upon ticket was elected.
41- The Election of 1789
- Not literally unanimous
- Double-vote system
- NC and RI had not yet ratified
- NY failed to cast electoral votes
- Scattering of second votes
- Fears that northerners wanted to make Adams
President
42The Election of 1792
- We see beginnings of the Federalist-Republican
two-party system in the second (Vice
Presidential) votes
43Schattschneiders Law
- The framers expectations did not anticipate the
development of a national two-party system. - Schattschneiders Law if you create a large
popularly elected legislative body, - party caucuses will arise in the legislature, and
- political parties will develop in the electorate.
- Caucuses and parties are organized attempts to
win by concentrating votes (through a bloc vote
in the legislature or nominating process in
elections) on a few motions or candidates, - They arise because ambitious politicians find it
expedient to conspire with others to win these
contests.
44Duvergers Law
- Duvergers Law If you have single-winner
elections, you get (in equilibrium) two political
parties, i.e., - two rival organized attempts, each trying to
concentrate votes on a single candidate. - Conversely, parliamentary systems using
proportional representation in large districts
tend to produce and sustain multi-party systems. - In part, Duvergers Law is driven by strategic
(or tactical) voting by ordinary voters who are
reluctant to waste their votes by voting for
third candidates/parties that have no real chance
of winning.
45Duvergers Law (cont.)
- In much greater part, Duvergers Law is driven by
the strategic calculations of ambitious
candidates and parties. - If a party splits and runs two (more or less
clone) candidates, they will be spoilers against
each other and throw the election to the other
party. - This prospect of electoral disaster creates a
huge incentive for even a highly factionalized
party to unite behind a single candidate. - Conversely, if there are three significant
candidates or parties are contesting an election,
there is a huge incentive for two of them to
make deal under which one makes a strategic
withdrawal in favor of the other (in return for
something). - In general, each party in a competitive two-party
system has a huge incentive to remain united and
not split into rival factions that run candidates
in general elections. - With respect to the Electoral College system,
Duvergers Law implies that (contrary to the
Framers expectations) the House contingent
procedure will be bypassed at least 19 times out
of 20.
46The Hazardous Game1796
- The first contested Presidential election
- Federalists John Adams (MA) Thomas Pickney
(SC) - Republicans Thomas Jefferson (VA) Aaron Burr
(NY) - They were nominated by their respective
Congressional Caucuses. - Note the regionally (North South) balanced
tickets. - Each party nominated elector candidates pledged
to vote their partys candidates. - Intra-Federalist maneuvering
- Hamilton (continuing to feud with Adams)
unsuccessfully urged some Southern electors to
vote for Pickney anybody but Adams - However, some Northern electors learned about
this and withheld votes from Pickney. - The electoral vote outcome was very close
- Federalists won 71 electors, all of whom voted
for Adams, giving Adams the required majority of
70 for election as President. - Republicans won 68 electors, all of whom voted
for Jefferson. - But the withholding of second votes from Pickney
lowered his vote total to 59, dropping him to
third place behind Jefferson, - So the defeated Republican Presidential candidate
became Vice President. - Burr won only 30 votes.
47The Election of 1796 (cont.)Electors 138
Electoral votes 276, Required majority 70
48The Election of 1796 (cont.)
- Sectionalism is evident, despite the sectionally
balanced tickets. - Many states did not select electors by popular
vote. - Most state electoral votes are cast
winner-take-all.
49Lessons from the Hazardous Game
- Electors are expected to be party men,
- i.e., pledged electors.
- However, Samuel Miles (Fed., PA) violated his
pledge (first faithless elector). - An angry Federalist supporter complained What,
do I chuse Samuel Miles to determine for me
whether John Adams or Thomas shall be President?
No! I chuse him to act, not to think. - State legislative elections (perhaps coming a
year or more in advance of Presidential
elections), become very important for politicians
with national ambitions, because - legislatures chose how to select electors and may
change the method from election to election and - legislatures may choose to appoint the electors
themselves.
50Lessons from the Hazardous Game (cont.)
- A party that controls a state legislature may not
want to risk a popular election for electors. - States using legislative election increased to 10
in 1800. - And if a controlling party is confident it can
win popular election, the particular mode of
popular election can be manipulated (e.g., to
winner-take-all) to short-term party advantage. - Jefferson to Monroe (1800)
- All agree that an election by districts would be
best if it could be general, but while ten states
choose either by their legislatures or by a
general ticket, it is folly or worse for the
other six not to follow.
51The Hazardous Game 1800
- Largely a repeat of 1796
- same candidates (except one Pickney replaced by
another) and - same battle lines.
- However, the strategic implications of the EC
rules were (even) better understood - manipulation of elector selection and
- danger of withholding too many votes.
- The election of 1800 was as close as 1796 but
tipped the other way. - Republicans won 73 electors vs. 65 for
Federalists. - The Republicans (unlike the Federalists) failed
to withhold one Vice Presidential electoral
vote. - Jefferson 73
- Burr 73
- Adams 65
- Pickney 64
- Jay 1
52(No Transcript)
53The Hazardous Game 1800 (cont.)
- But the original EC rules did not distinguish
between Presidential vs. Vice-Presidential
electoral votes. - So the election was thrown into House, under
the contingent procedure, - choosing between the tied candidates Jefferson
and Burr only. - Burr did not chose to withdraw.
- Four electoral votes from GA had been improperly
certified but the intent of the voters was
clear (four votes for each of Jefferson and
Burr). - Had they been disqualified as invalid, no
candidate would have received the required 70
electoral votes, in which case - the House could have chosen any of the five
candidates as President. - But Vice President Jefferson, presiding over the
counting of electoral votes, counted himself
and Burr in. - Note that the single Federalist elector who voted
for Adams and Jay could have voted for Adams and
Burr, - in which case Burr would have immediately been
elected President on the basis of electoral votes
(with no House election) and - Jefferson would have remained Vice President.
54The Hazardous Game 1800 (cont.)
- Until 20th Amendment (1933), a newly elected
Congress did not convene until late in the year
following Congressional elections. - So the 1800 Presidential election was thrown into
the lame duck House elected in 1798, which was
still controlled by the Federalists (55-50),
though Republicans controlled the House elected
in 1800. - There were 16 state delegations, so 10 votes were
required for election. - Each delegation would decide how to vote by
majority vote within the delegation. - Republicans controlled 8 state delegations.
- Federalists controlled 6 state delegations.
- Two state delegation were equally split.
- Evidently, all Republican representatives
supported Jefferson as the intended Presidential
candidate. - Likewise, all Federalist representatives
supported Burr, in order to deny the presidency
to more formidable Jefferson. - The two internally tied delegations had to
abstain. - For 35 ballots, the House deadlocked Jefferson 8
and Burr 6 with 2 abstentions. - Ultimately, the four Federalists within in the
tied delegations abstained, resulting in
Jeffersons election on the 36th ballot.
55Contingent Procedure in the House, 1801
56The 12th Amendment
- After the 1800 fiasco, Congress proposed, and the
states quickly ratified (in time for 1804
election), the 12th Amendment to the
Constitution. - Electors now cast separate (single) votes for
President and Vice President. - The required electoral vote majority for
President (and for Vice President) is a simple
majority of votes cast ( number of electors),
which at most one candidate can achieve. - If no candidate receives the required simple
majority for President, the House (still voting
by state delegations) chooses from among the top
three vs. top five candidates. - If no candidate receives the required majority
for Vice President, the Senate (voting
individually) chooses from among the top two
candidates. - Early drafts of the amendment included a
requirement that electors be popularly elected
from districts, but this provision was later
dropped. - The 12th Amendment remains the constitutional
language governing Presidential elections.
57The Transformation of the Electoral College
- By the 1830s, the Electoral College, already
formally modified by the 12th Amendment, had been
further transformed into the kind of
(essentially) automatic popular vote counting
system that exists today. - This transformation
- was driven largely by the development of a
two-party system, and - was brought about without any further
constitutional amendments or (with one minor
exception) change in federal law, - but rather by changes in state laws and party
practice.
58Elements of the Transformation (cont.)
- In early elections, the mode of selecting
Presidential electors was regularly manipulated
by party politicians in each state, on the basis
of partisan calculations. - By 1832, Presidential electors were almost
universally selected by popular (vs. legislative)
vote (and by much expanded electorates). - South Carolina was the lone hold out.
- By 1836, the mode of popular election in every
state was (following Jeffersons strategic
advice) the general ticket (or party slate),
rather than election from districts (or by some
kind of proportional representation). - This induced the almost universal
winner-take-all rule for the casting electoral
votes at the state level. - However, at the present time two small states (ME
and NE) use the Modified District Plan.
59Mode of Elector Selection
60Mode of Elector Selection (cont.)
- Why were state legislatures willing to give up
the power to select Presidential electors? - The intensity of party competition declined after
1800. - There was a minor split in Democratic-Republican
ranks in 1812. - DeWitt Clinton sought the Presidency as an
Independent Democratic-Republic and was
endorsed by the Federalists. - Democrats did the same in 1872 when Horace
Greeley ran as a Liberal Republican. - Legislative appointment of electors was
disrupting state legislative elections. - cf. the willingness of state legislatures to
ratify the 17th Amendment (popular election of
U.S. Senators)
61Mode of Elector Selection (cont.)
- Why were state legislatures willing to give up
the power to select Presidential electors? - The intensity of party competition declined after
1800. - Legislative appointment of electors was
disrupting state legislative elections. - cf. the willingness of state legislatures to
ratify the 17th Amendment (popular election of
U.S. Senators) - Why did election of electors by districts give
way to election of electors at-large (usually on
a slate or general ticket)? - Partisan strategic considerations,
- as expressed by Jefferson to Monroe in 1800.
- More important state strategic considerations.
- No matter what other states may do, each state
could enhance its influence in Presidential
politics by casting electoral votes on a
winner-take-all basis. - There is no equilibrium until all states use
the winner-take-all method. - It turns out that this equilibrium results in a
new balance of Electoral College voting power
that is more favorable to the large states, more
than counterbalancing the small-state advantage
in apportionment of electoral votes.
62Winner-Take-All
- Most states use a general ticket system in which
votes chose among party slates of elector
candidates. - Vote for one slate of
electors - Democratic electors
- Republican electors
- Minor party electors
- This effectively guarantees that a states
electoral votes are cast winner-take-all. - However, earlier in some states electors ran as
individuals on a generalized plurality basis. - Vote for no more than four elector candidates
- D1 R1
- D2 R2
- D3 R3
- D4 R4
- Typically almost every voter would vote for all
Democratic elector candidates or all Republican
elector candidate, again producing a
winner-take-result.
63Almost Winner-Take-All
- However, when the Presidential contest within the
state was very close, small discrepancies among
the votes for elector candidates might produce a
divided electoral vote - D1 93,456 R1 91,993
- D2 93,381 R2 91,553
- D3 92,358 R3 90,852
- D4 91,679 R4 90,761
- In this case, the electoral vote would be divided
3 for the Democratic ticket and 1 for the
Republican ticket. - By convention, the popular vote for President
in this state would be recorded as - Democratic ticket 93,456
- Republican ticket 91,993
64Bypassing the Contingent Procedure
- Given a two-party system accommodated by the 12th
Amendment, it is virtually assured that one or
other Presidential (and Vice Presidential)
candidate will receive the required majority of
electoral votes. - Thus Madison hope to keep the election out of the
House is realized, - not by coordination among the big states, but
- by coordination (a nominating process) within
each of two political parties. - In this way, the Electoral College system was
transformed into something in two ways more
favorable to large states than the Framers
expected, i.e., - not only do large states gain more power in the
first (electoral vote) stage (due to
winner-take-all electoral votes), but also - the second (House contingent election stage)
stage (where small states have equal power) is
almost always bypassed.
65Inverse Duvergers Law and the Election of 1824
- The inverse of Duvergers Law implies that
- if one of the parties in a two-party system is
greatly weakened, or is unable or unwilling to
compete for votes effectively, - the dominant party is very likely to break apart,
because the external threat that otherwise keeps
it together is removed. - The election of 1824 (the second and last time an
election was thrown into the House) is the
exception that proved the rule that a two-party
system bypasses the contingent procedure. - The Federalist Party had collapsed and the
Democratic-Republican Party was unchallenged. - Consequently there was no longer pressure for
D-Rs to unite behind a single Presidential-Vice
Presidential ticket. - Four candidates, all nominally belonging to the
same D-R party, sought the Presidency. - Unsurprisingly, no candidate received a majority
of the electoral votes and the election was
thrown into the House.
66The Election 1824 (cont.)
- The four candidates were
- John Quincy Adams (Secretary of State)
- Henry Clay (U.S. Representative and Speaker)
- William Crawford (Secretary of the Treasury)
- Andrew Jackson (hero of the Battle of New
Orleans and representative of the common
man) -
- Presidential election results (first
round) - Electoral Votes
Popular Votes - Jackson 99 41
- Adams 84 31
- Crawford 41 11
- Clay 37 13
- Others 0
4 - Bear in mind that six states still appointed
electors and that states that used popular
election varied considerably with respect to the
extent of franchise.
67The Election of 1824 (cont.)
- The compromise candidate Clay (most everyones
second choice, who probably could have defeated
each other candidate in a straight fight) was
squeezed out of third place in the electoral vote
ranking by Crawford. - Under the 12th Amendment, the House could chose
only from among top three candidates. - Clay probably would have been elected president
- if the House could still chose among the top five
candidates or - if Crawford had not been a candidate (i.e.,
Crawford was a spoiler to Clay). - Even if Adams or Jackson h