The U.S. Electoral College - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

The U.S. Electoral College

Description:

Title: The U.S. Electoral College: Origins and Transformation, Problems and Prospects Author: nmiller Last modified by: Windows User Created Date – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:302
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 74
Provided by: nmil9
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: The U.S. Electoral College


1
The U.S. Electoral College
  • N. R. Miller
  • POLI 423

2
How the EC Works in Practice
  • Instead of electing a President (and Vice
    President) in a single national election on
    Presidential election day,
  • we have 51 separate state ( DC) elections,
  • in which voters (reasonably enough but
    incorrectly) think they are voting directly for a
    Presidential/Vice Presidential ticket.
  • the plurality winner in each state (except ME and
    NE) wins all of the states electoral votes
    (winner-take-all)
  • which are equal in number to the states total
    representation in Congress,
  • i.e., its House seats 2
  • plus DC has 3 electoral votes, so
  • total EV 538, and
  • these electoral votes are added up to determine
    the winner of the election,
  • with 270 required for election.
  • Thus in practice (about 95 of the time), the EC
    is merely a vote counting system that
  • takes the popular votes in each state,
  • automatically translates them into nationwide
    electoral votes, and
  • declares a winner.

3
Implication of the EC in PracticeBattleground/
Swing States
  • The principal implication of the EC in practice
    is that it creates battleground (or swing)
    states, because
  • it matters only which party ticket carries a
    state,
  • and not what the margin of victory or defeat is.
  • cf. marginal constituencies in the UK.
  • Hence states that are expected to be close become
    battlegrounds while other are substantially
    ignored.
  • Today (frequent and relatively accurate) state
    polls make it easier to identify battleground
    states.
  • Until a decade or two ago, there were relatively
    few state (as opposed to national) polls.
  • Contemporary campaign resources (especially TV on
    local channels and cable services) ads can be
    both
  • focused on particular states, and
  • can moved from one state to another,
  • in contrast to
  • party organization rooted in states and
    localities in the 19th century, and
  • national TV advertising (mid- to later-20th
    century).

4
More Esoteric EC Details
  • Lurking beneath electoral votes are real people
    called Presidential electors,
  • who voters actually vote for on Presidential
    election day,
  • who are actually elected on Presidential election
    day, and
  • who actually cast the electoral votes (about six
    weeks later).
  • Underlying the winner-take-all system is the
    fact that (in almost universal practice)
    Presidential electors are elected not
    individually but on statewide party slates
    (general ticket system).
  • The Constitution gives state legislature the
    power to determine how their states electors are
    elected (or appointed).
  • A variety of methods other than winner-take-all
    for selecting Presidential electors have been
    used by some states in the past, which could
    often produce split electoral votes from a state.
  • Indeed, at the present time, ME (since 1972) and
    NE (since 1992) do not award electoral votes on a
    winner-take-all basis,
  • but rather on the basis of the Modified District
    Plan,
  • so their electoral votes may be split (though in
    fact this never happened until 2008 in NE).

5
Esoteric Details (cont.)
  • Party nominees may occasionally be deprived of
    electoral votes by faithless electors,
  • who cast electoral votes in a way that
    contradicts their pledge to support their party
    ticket, and
  • in a way that does not reflect popular vote in
    the state
  • and produces a split electoral vote from a state.
  • If no candidate wins 270 electoral votes, either
    because
  • a third candidate wins some electoral votes or
  • there is a (mathematically possible) 269-269 tie,
  • the election is thrown into the House of
    Representatives (which last happened in 1824),
  • where voting by state delegation (one delegation
    one vote).
  • A number of elections have other displayed
    electoral vote oddities --- for example
  • President Truman received no votes in AL in 1948,
  • President Johnson received no votes in AL in
    1964,
  • because no elector candidates pledged to these
    Presidents were on the ballot.
  • unpledged electors were elected in AL and MS in
    1960.
  • Even presumptive experts (e.g., textbook authors)
    often mischaracterize esoteric features of the
    Electoral College.
  • Adkinson and Elliot, The Electoral College A
    Misunderstood Institution, PS, March 1997

6
Evaluating the Electoral College
  • Alexander Hamilton, Federalist 68
  • The mode of appointment of the Chief Magistrate
    of the United States is almost the only part of
    the system, of any consequence, which has escaped
    without severe censure, or which has received the
    slightest mark of approbation from its opponents.
    . . . I venture somewhat further, and hesitate
    not to affirm that if the manner of it be not
    perfect, it is at least excellent.
  • Actually there were some Antifederalist
    criticisms of the mode of appointment of the
    Chief Magistrate, but they were not among the
    leading arguments against the proposed
    Constitution.
  • Many subsequent evaluations (and the many
    proposed constitutional amendments) suggest a
    less favorable assessment of the mode of
    appointment of the Chief Magistrate,
  • Range of evaluations the Electoral College was
  • part of a generally elitist and anti-democratic
    constitution or
  • a last-minute jerry-built compromise or perhaps
  • a well designed compromise among diverse
    considerations, or possibly
  • the embodiment of well-thought-out selection
    criteria.

7
Evaluating the Electoral College (cont.)
  • Today, as a rough generalization,
  • liberals mostly criticize the Electoral College
    and advocate its replacement by a national
    popular vote, e.g.,
  • George Edwards, Why the Electoral College is Bad
    for America, and
  • Neal R. Peirce, The Peoples President,
  • while conservatives mostly oppose a national
    popular vote and defend the existing Electoral
    College, e.g.,
  • Judith Best, assigned reading on webpage and The
    Case Against Direct Election of the President,
    and
  • Tara Ross, Enlightened Democracy The Case for
    the Electoral College (with an Introduction by
    George Will).

8
Evaluating the Electoral College (cont.)
  • However, in the mid-20th century liberals
    mostly defended the existing Electoral College
    system, which they viewed as having features that
  • enhanced the voting power of major constituencies
    of the New Deal, in particular,
  • urban dwellers,
  • racial and ethnic minorities, and
  • union members,
  • and which counterbalanced the rural and
    conservative advantage
  • in the malapportioned House of the that era, and
  • In the malapportioned Senate of every era.
  • In that era, proposals to modify (but not
    abolish) the Electoral College (the Modified
    District and Proportional Plans) were supported
    mostly by conservatives.)

9
Evaluating the Electoral College (cont.)
  • My own take on the Electoral College (Why the
    Electoral College Is Good for Political
    Science)
  • The original EC was a compromise among diverse
    considerations that was cleverly designed but had
    a fatal flaw that had to be (and was) corrected
    by the 12th Amendment to the Constitution in
    1804.
  • The original EC established a selection system
  • that was designed to operate in a non-partisan
    environment, but
  • did not operate satisfactorily once political
    parties formed to contest Presidential selection.
  • The EC was rapidly transformed into an
    institution quite different from its designers
    had intended.
  • So, even if you like the existing EC, you cant
    really give credit to the wisdom of the framers
    of the Constitution.
  • Likewise, even if you dislike the existing EC,
    you cant really blame the framers.
  • The transformed EC has proved to be a serviceable
    institution but is problematic in a number of
    ways.

10
Why the Electoral College is Good for Political
Science
  • Moreover, the Electoral College is a terrific
    boon for political science research and teaching
    -- hence, my title (a play on the title of the
    Edwards book).
  • the origins of the Electoral College and applied
    social theory
  • unanticipated consequences in institutional
    design
  • political strategy and institutional equilibrium
  • voting power in weighted voting systems
  • comparative institutional analysis
  • individual voting power and the Electoral
    College
  • election inversions
  • Electoral College deadlock
  • circumventing formal structure through commitment.

11
Problems with the EC in Practice
  • It typically produces a disparity between popular
    and electoral vote proportions, which
  • almost always exaggerates the winners margin,
    for example
  • Popular Vote Electoral Vote
  • 2008 Obama 53 365
  • McCain 46 173
  • But is this really a problem?

12
Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
  • It disenfranchises voters in non-battleground
    states.
  • On the other hand, are all voters
    disenfranchised in landslide elections?
  • It produces a small state advantage resulting
    from the apportionment of electoral votes.
  • Regardless of population, every state
  • has two Senators, and
  • at least one House seat, and therefore
  • has at least three electoral votes.
  • It produces a large state advantage resulting
    from the winner-take-all system (not fixed by the
    Constitution) in casting electoral votes.
  • But can both of the problems be true?

13
Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
  • An creates an incentive for disputes or fraud
    concerning vote counting in pivotal states,
  • e.g., Florida in 2000.
  • But with a close national popular vote, any such
    dispute would be nationwide.
  • It tolerates an absence of national standards for
  • voter qualifications,
  • voter registration,
  • voting technology,
  • ballot access, etc.
  • But imposing national standards might be
    controversial.
  • It is subject to spoiler effects, so that
  • the presence or absence of a third candidate who
    cannot win the election may tip the outcome
    between the two major candidates,
  • e.g., Nader (and possibly Buchanan) in 2000.
  • But in fact, every electoral system whatsoever is
    vulnerable in some degree to spoiler effects.

14
Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
  • It can produces minority Presidents,
  • who win less than a majority of the popular vote,
    but
  • are elected on the basis winning a majority
    (270) of electoral votes, e.g.,
  • Bush in 2000,
  • Clinton in both 1996 and 1992,
  • Nixon in 1968,
  • Kennedy in 1960,
  • Truman in 1948,
  • Wilson in both 1916 and 1912.
  • But many electoral systems do the equivalent.
  • The British refer to such an effect as a
    manufactured majority.
  • Every British election since WWII has produced a
    manufactured majority except the two (February
    1974 and May 2010) that did not produce any
    majority (that produced a hung Parliament),
    i.e.,
  • in which the leading party held fewer than half
    the seats in House of Commons.

15
Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
  • Most important, it produces election inversions
    (or reversals of winners, wrong winners, EC
    misfires, etc.) in which
  • a candidate who wins less than a plurality of the
    popular vote
  • is elected on the basis of electoral votes.
  • Popular Vote Electoral Vote
  • 2000 Bush (R) 47.87 271
  • Gore (D) 48.38 267
  • 1888 Harrison (R) 47.80
    233
  • Cleveland (D) 48.63
    168
  • 1876 Hayes (R) 51
    185
  • Tilden (D) 48 184
  • 1960(?) Kennedy (D) 49.464 (?)
    303
  • Nixon (R) 49.548 (?) 219

16
Problems with the EC in Practice (cont.)
  • The election inversion problem is usually
    regarded as the most serious flaw in the
    Electoral College.
  • In fact, every districted electoral system is
    subject to election inversions.
  • Election inversions occur in parliamentary
    systems as well as U.S. Presidential elections
    (but get less attention).
  • Votes Seats
  • UK 1951 Conservative 47.97 321
  • Labour 48.78 295
  • In fact, election inversions can occur under
    (list) proportional representation systems
  • Netherlands 2010 VVDPVDCDA 49.55
    76
  • All other parties 50.45
    74
  • This coalition of parties actually formed the
    government.

17
Problems with Details of the EC
  • Unpledged or faithless electors might determine
    the outcome of the election.
  • But this is unlikely --- theyre looking for
    their 15 minutes of fame.
  • State legislatures can manipulate the manner of
    selecting electors.
  • Colorado Proposition 36 in 2004 (Democratic
    supported initiative)
  • Republican efforts in CA in 2008 and PA in 2012
  • If a state decides to select electors by
    district, the districts may be gerrymandered.
  • A state legislature might decide to appoint
    electors.
  • There is no constitutional right to vote for
    President (or even Presidential electors).
  • The most problematic feature of the Electoral
    College is Contingent Procedure (when an election
    is thrown into the House).
  • We have little understanding of how this would
    work in practice.
  • State equality regardless of population appears
    to be unsupportable (especially today, e.g., CA
    vs. WY)
  • A President would not be selected until about two
    weeks before Inauguration Day (if then).

18
Alternatives to the Existing Electoral College
System
  • As we have noted, some changes in the EC system
    can by made by individual state legislatures,
  • namely, how their electors are selected and thus
    how state electoral votes are cast
    (winner-take-all or otherwise).
  • Other changes would require an amendment to the
    Constitution, e.g.,
  • to change or abolish position of electors,
  • change the apportionment of electors/electoral
    votes among the states, or
  • abolish or change the contingent procedure.
  • Of course, a constitutional amendment is also
    required to make nationally uniform changes in
    how electors are selected and electoral votes are
    cast.
  • Congress cant direct change the EC by simple
    legislation however, it can
  • change the size of the House or Representatives,
  • admit new states (and thus increase the size of
    the Senate),
  • both of which would change the size of the
    Electoral College and the magnitude of the small
    state advantage in the apportionment of electoral
    votes), and
  • change the method of apportioning House seats
    among the states on the basis of the decennial
    census.

19
Alternatives to the Existing EC System (cont.)
  • The Automatic Plan. Regularize the existing
    system by abolishing the position of elector
    while retaining electoral votes to be
    automatically awarded on a winner-take-all basis
    to the popular-vote winner in each state.
  • This requires a U.S. constitutional amendment,
    which probably should abolish or revise the
    contingent procedure as well.
  • The Pure District Plan. Select electors by
    plurality vote in single-member districts within
    states.
  • This can be implemented on a state-by-state
    basis.
  • But if it is effected by a constitutional
    amendment, it should probably revise the
    contingent procedure as well.
  • The Modified District Plan. Select electors by
    plurality in the existing single-member
    Congressional Districts, with the two remaining
    (Senatorial) electors elected state-wide.
  • This can be implemented on a state-by-state basis
    (as ME and NE have done).
  • The Mundt-Coudert Plan proposed this as a
    constitutional amendment in the 1950s and in
    revised form in the 1960s.
  • It modified the contingent procedure to a joint
    ballot of the whole Congress voting as
    individuals.

20
Alternatives to the Existing EC System (cont.)
  • The (Pure) Proportional Plan. Award the
    electoral votes of each state to candidates
    precisely (out to three or more decimal places)
    in proportion to their popular votes within each
    state.
  • Since fractional electoral votes would result,
    the office of elector would have to be abolished.
  • This therefore requires a constitutional
    amendment, which should probably abolish or
    revise the contingent procedure as well.
  • The Lodge-Gossett Plan proposed this as a
    constitutional amendment in the 1940s and 1950s,
  • and it modified the contingent procedure to a
    joint ballot of the whole Congress voting as
    individuals.
  • The Whole-Number Proportional Plan. Award the
    electoral votes of each state to candidates in
    whole numbers that are proportional as possible
    to their popular votes within the states.
  • An established PR apportionment formula could be
    used.
  • Since electors could be retained, this can be
    implemented on a state-by-state basis,
  • e.g., Colorado Proposition 36 in 2004 (using an
    ad hoc PR formula).
  • But if it is effected by a constitutional
    amendment, it should probably abolish or revise
    the contingent procedure as well,
  • especially as minor candidate could more easily
    win electoral votes.

21
Alternatives to the Existing EC System (cont.)
  • The National Bonus Plan. Retain the existing
    system (or use the Automatic Plan) but award an
    additional bonus of perhaps 102 electoral votes
    to the national popular vote plurality winner.
  • This would require a U.S. constitutional
    amendment.
  • Its obvious rationale is to preclude election
    inversions and it would effectively preclude the
    contingent procedure as well.
  • Revision of Contingent Procedure. Many options
    exist, but these have received the most
    attention
  • abolish the electoral vote majority requirement
    for election entirely, or
  • reduce the majority requirement, and/or
  • change the nature of the contingent procedure,
    i.e.,
  • to election by a joint session of Congress,
    voting one-member, one-vote.
  • But the problem of electoral vote ties (which
    also leads to the contingent procedure) remains
    so long as the number of electoral votes is even.
  • The current problem was created by the 23rd
    Amendment giving DC three electoral votes
    (starting in 1964).

22
Alternatives to the Existing EC System (cont.)
  • The Popular Vote Plan. Abolish the Electoral
    college in its entirety and hold a national
    direct popular election for President (and Vice
    President),
  • with or without an runoff (instant or
    otherwise), and
  • perhaps (if a runoff is used) using a 40 (rather
    than 50) quota for election in the first round.
  • This would require a constitutional amendment.
  • Such a national popular vote might/should entail
    national administration of Presidential (and
    Congressional, while were at it?) elections,
    including
  • nationally uniform voter qualifications,
  • national voter registration (and voter ID
    requirements,if any),
  • nationally uniform ballot types and voting
    technology,
  • nationally uniform rules for ballot access
    (listing of candidates), etc.

23
The National Popular Vote Plan
24
National Popular Vote Plan (cont.)
  • This is a proposal to (in effect) enact a direct
    national popular election for President
  • without using a constitutional amendment,
  • which requires ratification by three-quarters of
    the states,
  • and is therefore believed to be very difficult to
    obtain.
  • Its starting point is the fact that, under the
    Constitution,
  • state legislatures have sole power over how their
    Presidential electors are selected.

25
National Popular Vote Plan (cont.)
  • NPVP proposes that states collectively
    controlling at least 270 electoral votes
  • enter into an interstate compact
  • that would commit them to select Presidential
    electors who would cast their electoral votes,
  • not for the candidate who carries their state,
    but
  • for the national popular vote winner.
  • Note that national popular vote winner means
    plurality winner, so
  • NPVP would also preclude the House contingent
    procedure
  • barring a national popular vote tie.

26
Problems with the NPVP
  • NPVP does not (and cannot) address the problems
    entailed by direct popular vote previously
    identified in particular,
  • national rules for and administration of
    Presidential elections and
  • runoff or related provisions
  • There is no officially certified national
    popular vote winner.
  • Would the compact hold, especially in the event
    of an extremely close/disputed (with respect to
    the national popular vote) election?
  • In every election, some states in the compact
    would have to cast electoral votes for the
    candidate that lost the popular vote in that
    state.
  • In some (close) elections, such electoral votes
    would be decisive.
  • In particular, would the compact hold in the
    event that there would otherwise be an election
    inversion (the very event the NPVP is designed to
    preclude)?

27
Why Do We Have an Electoral College?
  • The answer goes back to 1787 and the framing of
    the U.S. Constitution.
  • The charge to the Constitutional Convention was
    to revise and strengthen the Articles of
    Confederation.
  • Under the A of C, the only central government
    institution was Congress.
  • Each state legislature appointed Congressional
    delegates.
  • Each state delegation had one vote (the same rule
    was used in the Constitutional Convention).
  • A 9/13 supra-majority was required for
    substantive matters.
  • 13/13 unanimity was required to amend the A of C.
  • Congress had very limited powers in particular,
  • It could not lay and collect taxes, and
  • It could not pass laws that directly exercised
    its powers.
  • In both respects, Congress had to rely on the
    cooperation of state legislatures.
  • There was no national executive or judiciary.

28
Why Do We Have an Electoral College? (cont.)
  • The Constitution
  • expanded the powers of Congress and
  • allowed Congress to exercise its powers by
    passing laws that bound individuals directly, and
  • that would be executed by a national executive
    (President), who also had other independent
    powers, and
  • that would be enforced by a national court
    system.
  • The executive (and judiciary) would also check
    and balance the naturally predominant
    legislature.

29
Designing The Original Electoral College
  • Designing the mode of selecting the President was
    one of the most difficult tasks that confronted
    the framers.
  • Their most famously difficult task was designing
    the scheme of representation for a new national
    legislature.
  • The difficulty in the legislative case lay in the
    fact that most delegates knew what they wanted,
    but different delegates wanted different things
  • small-state delegates wanted to preserve the
    principle of state equality, while
  • large-state delegates wanted state representation
    proportional to state population (and/or wealth).
  • In contrast, the difficulty in the executive case
    was that most delegates were not at all sure what
    they wanted,
  • though the small-state versus big-state conflict
    remained a factor).

30
Designing The Original Electoral College
  • The menu of options for Presidential selection
  • Selection by states,
  • But this would be too much like the Article
    Confederation
  • Selection by the Congress,
  • which was the default option found in both VA
    and NJ plans.
  • But many feared it would make the President too
    dependent on and (if eligible for re-election)
    subservient to Congress.
  • How would a bicameral Congress (as provided for
    by the Great Compromise) elect a President?
  • House only
  • Senate only
  • concurrent ballot
  • joint ballot
  • Selection by some kind of popular election
  • which presented many practical difficulties.
  • Some kind of mixed system, which might
    distinguish between
  • a first round of selection (nomination) and
  • a second round of selection (election or
    runoff), and
  • might use intermediate electors.

31
Designing The Original EC (cont.)
  • The perceived advantages of an Electoral College
    of intermediate electors
  • unlike Congress, the EC would perform a single
    task i.e., cast votes for President -- and
    would then disband, so
  • the President would be subservient to neither
    Congress nor the Electoral College and
  • unlike popular election, the EC
  • avoided difficult questions about the extent of
    suffrage, and
  • allowed a compromise between the large vs. small
    states through its fine details, and
  • and public opinion could be informed and refined
    through representation.
  • Since legislative election was the default
    choice, it is more accurate to say the framers
    settled on the EC
  • as an alternative to legislative election, rather
    than
  • as an alternative to popular election.

32
The Original Electoral College Rules
  • Each state selects a number of electors equal
    in number to its total (House Senate)
    representation in Congress (H 2).
  • The legislature of each state determines the mode
    of selection of the electors from its state, the
    most likely options being
  • Election/appointment by the legislature itself,
  • popular election from districts, and
  • popular election on a state-wide general ticket.
  • Congress has the power to determine
  • when electors are selected, and
  • when electors cast their votes (which must be the
    same day for all states).
  • Originally, Congress gave the states a window of
    about 30 days within which to select electors.

33
The Original Electoral College (cont.)
  • The Electoral College never meets as a group in
    one place.
  • Rather electors meet and vote in their own state
    capitals
  • Electors were originally required to
  • cast two votes for two different candidates,
  • at least one of whom had to be a resident of
    another state,
  • In effect, electors could vote for one favorite
    son but were required also vote for at least one
    national candidate.
  • Once cast, the electoral votes are each are
    transmitted to Congress,
  • to be counted before a joint session presided
    over by the President of the Senate (Vice
    President of U.S.).
  • To be elected by the Electoral College, a
    candidate was originally required to receive
  • votes from a majority of electors and
  • more votes than any other candidate.
  • Given this double vote system, these requirements
    were logically distinct.
  • In particular, more that one candidate could
    receive the required majority.

34
The Original Electoral College (cont.)
  • If no candidate met both requirements, the
    election would be thrown into the House of
    Representatives.
  • The House chooses
  • between the two (or more) tied candidates, in the
    event both (or all) received votes from a
    majority of electors, or
  • (in the original EC) among the top five
    candidates, in the event no candidate received
    votes from a majority of electors.
  • Voting in the House is by state delegation, with
    each delegation casting one vote.
  • Balloting continues until some candidate is
    supported by a majority of state delegations.

35
The Fatal Flaw in the Original Electoral College
  • However, the Committee was concerned that some
    electors might throw away their second votes.
  • It believed a second office had to be at stake to
    induce electors to take their second votes
    seriously.
  • For this reason (only), it proposed the office of
    Vice President.
  • The Vice Presidency was introduced only for the
    sake of a valuable mode of election which
    required two to be chosen at the same time,
  • which largely explains the awkward and largely
    impotent place this office occupies in the
    overall constitutional scheme.
  • This turned out to be a miscalculation that
    produced a fatal flaw in the original EC,
  • and created what historian Richard McCormick has
    called a hazardous game of Presidential
    selection.

36
The Electoral College An Example
  • THE ORIGINAL ELECTORAL COLLEGE BEFORE THE 12th
    AMENDMENT AND USING THE PROVISIONAL APPORTIONMENT
    OF HOUSE SEATS
  • House Size 65
  • Number of Electors 65 (2 13) 91
  • Number of Electoral Votes 2 91 182
  • Maximum Vote Any Candidate Can Receive 91 (one
    vote from every elector)
  • Required Majority 46 (one vote from a majority
    of electors)
  • If no one gets 46 votes or if there is a tie
    among those who do
  • Required Vote in House 7
  • In any event, the runner-up becomes Vice
    President
  • Note these numbers were never actually used.

37
Expectations Concerning the Original EC
  • This original Electoral College system was
    designed to operate in a non-partisan
    environment.
  • It therefore was expected that
  • typically there would be many potential
    Presidential candidates,
  • who would not declare themselves as such, let
    alone actively campaign for the office, and
  • electors would choose among these candidates on
    the basis of their character and connections, not
    party affiliation or policy promises.
  • Therefore, it was also expected that electoral
    votes would be widely scattered and the House
    contingent procedure would be used 19 times out
    of 20 (George Masons estimate), so
  • big states would have the dominant role in
    screening/nominating candidates (in the EC),
    while
  • small states would have equal role in most
    final/runoff elections (in the House).

38
Expectations Concerning the EC (cont.)
  • However, James Madison (a big-state advocate)
    thought/hoped that big state electors would
    coordinate their electoral votes so as to keep
    the election out of the House (where small states
    would have the advantage).
  • Madison, not Mason, was correct in his
    expectation, but not for the reason he gave.
  • It was generally hoped and expected that electors
    would typically be
  • popularly elected
  • from single-member districts (like most state
    legislators, delegates to the state ratifying
    conventions, members of the British House of
    Commons, and as was expected also for members of
    the new U.S. House) and
  • that they would be well-informed local notables
    who would act as representative trustees of their
    states and districts.

39
The Hazardous Game President Selection under the
Original Electoral College
  • There were problems from the very start.
  • From the outset, electors and those who selected
    them (and most everyone else) thought of a
    presidential election, not as an occasion to cast
    two votes for two worthy presidential candidates,
    but as an occasion to elect a Presidential-Vice
    Presidential ticket.
  • In the very first election of 1789, it was
    generally agreed that
  • George Washington should be the first President,
    and
  • John Adams should be the first Vice President.
  • Most or all electors were expected to cast one
    vote for Washington and one vote for Adams.

40
The Hazardous Game (cont.)
  • But this expectation was precarious
  • If just one elector were to cast one vote for
    Adams and one vote for anybody but Washington,
    Adams would be elected President and Washington
    would be relegated to the Vice Presidency.
  • On the other hand, if every elector did in fact
    cast one vote for Washington and one for Adams,
    there would be an electoral vote tie, sending the
    election to the House.
  • Indeed, Alexander Hamilton (who disliked Adams)
    was afraid that some New England electors would
    withhold votes from Washington, thereby making
    Adams president.
  • In anticipation of this, he urged some other
    electors to withhold votes from Adams.
  • In fact, all electors voted for Washington but
    quite a few did not vote for Adams,
  • so in fact the agreed upon ticket was elected.

41
  • The Election of 1789
  • Not literally unanimous
  • Double-vote system
  • NC and RI had not yet ratified
  • NY failed to cast electoral votes
  • Scattering of second votes
  • Fears that northerners wanted to make Adams
    President

42
The Election of 1792
  • We see beginnings of the Federalist-Republican
    two-party system in the second (Vice
    Presidential) votes

43
Schattschneiders Law
  • The framers expectations did not anticipate the
    development of a national two-party system.
  • Schattschneiders Law if you create a large
    popularly elected legislative body,
  • party caucuses will arise in the legislature, and
  • political parties will develop in the electorate.
  • Caucuses and parties are organized attempts to
    win by concentrating votes (through a bloc vote
    in the legislature or nominating process in
    elections) on a few motions or candidates,
  • They arise because ambitious politicians find it
    expedient to conspire with others to win these
    contests.

44
Duvergers Law
  • Duvergers Law If you have single-winner
    elections, you get (in equilibrium) two political
    parties, i.e.,
  • two rival organized attempts, each trying to
    concentrate votes on a single candidate.
  • Conversely, parliamentary systems using
    proportional representation in large districts
    tend to produce and sustain multi-party systems.
  • In part, Duvergers Law is driven by strategic
    (or tactical) voting by ordinary voters who are
    reluctant to waste their votes by voting for
    third candidates/parties that have no real chance
    of winning.

45
Duvergers Law (cont.)
  • In much greater part, Duvergers Law is driven by
    the strategic calculations of ambitious
    candidates and parties.
  • If a party splits and runs two (more or less
    clone) candidates, they will be spoilers against
    each other and throw the election to the other
    party.
  • This prospect of electoral disaster creates a
    huge incentive for even a highly factionalized
    party to unite behind a single candidate.
  • Conversely, if there are three significant
    candidates or parties are contesting an election,
    there is a huge incentive for two of them to
    make deal under which one makes a strategic
    withdrawal in favor of the other (in return for
    something).
  • In general, each party in a competitive two-party
    system has a huge incentive to remain united and
    not split into rival factions that run candidates
    in general elections.
  • With respect to the Electoral College system,
    Duvergers Law implies that (contrary to the
    Framers expectations) the House contingent
    procedure will be bypassed at least 19 times out
    of 20.

46
The Hazardous Game1796
  • The first contested Presidential election
  • Federalists John Adams (MA) Thomas Pickney
    (SC)
  • Republicans Thomas Jefferson (VA) Aaron Burr
    (NY)
  • They were nominated by their respective
    Congressional Caucuses.
  • Note the regionally (North South) balanced
    tickets.
  • Each party nominated elector candidates pledged
    to vote their partys candidates.
  • Intra-Federalist maneuvering
  • Hamilton (continuing to feud with Adams)
    unsuccessfully urged some Southern electors to
    vote for Pickney anybody but Adams
  • However, some Northern electors learned about
    this and withheld votes from Pickney.
  • The electoral vote outcome was very close
  • Federalists won 71 electors, all of whom voted
    for Adams, giving Adams the required majority of
    70 for election as President.
  • Republicans won 68 electors, all of whom voted
    for Jefferson.
  • But the withholding of second votes from Pickney
    lowered his vote total to 59, dropping him to
    third place behind Jefferson,
  • So the defeated Republican Presidential candidate
    became Vice President.
  • Burr won only 30 votes.

47
The Election of 1796 (cont.)Electors 138
Electoral votes 276, Required majority 70
48
The Election of 1796 (cont.)
  • Sectionalism is evident, despite the sectionally
    balanced tickets.
  • Many states did not select electors by popular
    vote.
  • Most state electoral votes are cast
    winner-take-all.

49
Lessons from the Hazardous Game
  • Electors are expected to be party men,
  • i.e., pledged electors.
  • However, Samuel Miles (Fed., PA) violated his
    pledge (first faithless elector).
  • An angry Federalist supporter complained What,
    do I chuse Samuel Miles to determine for me
    whether John Adams or Thomas shall be President?
    No! I chuse him to act, not to think.
  • State legislative elections (perhaps coming a
    year or more in advance of Presidential
    elections), become very important for politicians
    with national ambitions, because
  • legislatures chose how to select electors and may
    change the method from election to election and
  • legislatures may choose to appoint the electors
    themselves.

50
Lessons from the Hazardous Game (cont.)
  • A party that controls a state legislature may not
    want to risk a popular election for electors.
  • States using legislative election increased to 10
    in 1800.
  • And if a controlling party is confident it can
    win popular election, the particular mode of
    popular election can be manipulated (e.g., to
    winner-take-all) to short-term party advantage.
  • Jefferson to Monroe (1800)
  • All agree that an election by districts would be
    best if it could be general, but while ten states
    choose either by their legislatures or by a
    general ticket, it is folly or worse for the
    other six not to follow.

51
The Hazardous Game 1800
  • Largely a repeat of 1796
  • same candidates (except one Pickney replaced by
    another) and
  • same battle lines.
  • However, the strategic implications of the EC
    rules were (even) better understood
  • manipulation of elector selection and
  • danger of withholding too many votes.
  • The election of 1800 was as close as 1796 but
    tipped the other way.
  • Republicans won 73 electors vs. 65 for
    Federalists.
  • The Republicans (unlike the Federalists) failed
    to withhold one Vice Presidential electoral
    vote.
  • Jefferson 73
  • Burr 73
  • Adams 65
  • Pickney 64
  • Jay 1

52
(No Transcript)
53
The Hazardous Game 1800 (cont.)
  • But the original EC rules did not distinguish
    between Presidential vs. Vice-Presidential
    electoral votes.
  • So the election was thrown into House, under
    the contingent procedure,
  • choosing between the tied candidates Jefferson
    and Burr only.
  • Burr did not chose to withdraw.
  • Four electoral votes from GA had been improperly
    certified but the intent of the voters was
    clear (four votes for each of Jefferson and
    Burr).
  • Had they been disqualified as invalid, no
    candidate would have received the required 70
    electoral votes, in which case
  • the House could have chosen any of the five
    candidates as President.
  • But Vice President Jefferson, presiding over the
    counting of electoral votes, counted himself
    and Burr in.
  • Note that the single Federalist elector who voted
    for Adams and Jay could have voted for Adams and
    Burr,
  • in which case Burr would have immediately been
    elected President on the basis of electoral votes
    (with no House election) and
  • Jefferson would have remained Vice President.

54
The Hazardous Game 1800 (cont.)
  • Until 20th Amendment (1933), a newly elected
    Congress did not convene until late in the year
    following Congressional elections.
  • So the 1800 Presidential election was thrown into
    the lame duck House elected in 1798, which was
    still controlled by the Federalists (55-50),
    though Republicans controlled the House elected
    in 1800.
  • There were 16 state delegations, so 10 votes were
    required for election.
  • Each delegation would decide how to vote by
    majority vote within the delegation.
  • Republicans controlled 8 state delegations.
  • Federalists controlled 6 state delegations.
  • Two state delegation were equally split.
  • Evidently, all Republican representatives
    supported Jefferson as the intended Presidential
    candidate.
  • Likewise, all Federalist representatives
    supported Burr, in order to deny the presidency
    to more formidable Jefferson.
  • The two internally tied delegations had to
    abstain.
  • For 35 ballots, the House deadlocked Jefferson 8
    and Burr 6 with 2 abstentions.
  • Ultimately, the four Federalists within in the
    tied delegations abstained, resulting in
    Jeffersons election on the 36th ballot.

55
Contingent Procedure in the House, 1801
56
The 12th Amendment
  • After the 1800 fiasco, Congress proposed, and the
    states quickly ratified (in time for 1804
    election), the 12th Amendment to the
    Constitution.
  • Electors now cast separate (single) votes for
    President and Vice President.
  • The required electoral vote majority for
    President (and for Vice President) is a simple
    majority of votes cast ( number of electors),
    which at most one candidate can achieve.
  • If no candidate receives the required simple
    majority for President, the House (still voting
    by state delegations) chooses from among the top
    three vs. top five candidates.
  • If no candidate receives the required majority
    for Vice President, the Senate (voting
    individually) chooses from among the top two
    candidates.
  • Early drafts of the amendment included a
    requirement that electors be popularly elected
    from districts, but this provision was later
    dropped.
  • The 12th Amendment remains the constitutional
    language governing Presidential elections.

57
The Transformation of the Electoral College
  • By the 1830s, the Electoral College, already
    formally modified by the 12th Amendment, had been
    further transformed into the kind of
    (essentially) automatic popular vote counting
    system that exists today.
  • This transformation
  • was driven largely by the development of a
    two-party system, and
  • was brought about without any further
    constitutional amendments or (with one minor
    exception) change in federal law,
  • but rather by changes in state laws and party
    practice.

58
Elements of the Transformation (cont.)
  • In early elections, the mode of selecting
    Presidential electors was regularly manipulated
    by party politicians in each state, on the basis
    of partisan calculations.
  • By 1832, Presidential electors were almost
    universally selected by popular (vs. legislative)
    vote (and by much expanded electorates).
  • South Carolina was the lone hold out.
  • By 1836, the mode of popular election in every
    state was (following Jeffersons strategic
    advice) the general ticket (or party slate),
    rather than election from districts (or by some
    kind of proportional representation).
  • This induced the almost universal
    winner-take-all rule for the casting electoral
    votes at the state level.
  • However, at the present time two small states (ME
    and NE) use the Modified District Plan.

59
Mode of Elector Selection
60
Mode of Elector Selection (cont.)
  • Why were state legislatures willing to give up
    the power to select Presidential electors?
  • The intensity of party competition declined after
    1800.
  • There was a minor split in Democratic-Republican
    ranks in 1812.
  • DeWitt Clinton sought the Presidency as an
    Independent Democratic-Republic and was
    endorsed by the Federalists.
  • Democrats did the same in 1872 when Horace
    Greeley ran as a Liberal Republican.
  • Legislative appointment of electors was
    disrupting state legislative elections.
  • cf. the willingness of state legislatures to
    ratify the 17th Amendment (popular election of
    U.S. Senators)

61
Mode of Elector Selection (cont.)
  • Why were state legislatures willing to give up
    the power to select Presidential electors?
  • The intensity of party competition declined after
    1800.
  • Legislative appointment of electors was
    disrupting state legislative elections.
  • cf. the willingness of state legislatures to
    ratify the 17th Amendment (popular election of
    U.S. Senators)
  • Why did election of electors by districts give
    way to election of electors at-large (usually on
    a slate or general ticket)?
  • Partisan strategic considerations,
  • as expressed by Jefferson to Monroe in 1800.
  • More important state strategic considerations.
  • No matter what other states may do, each state
    could enhance its influence in Presidential
    politics by casting electoral votes on a
    winner-take-all basis.
  • There is no equilibrium until all states use
    the winner-take-all method.
  • It turns out that this equilibrium results in a
    new balance of Electoral College voting power
    that is more favorable to the large states, more
    than counterbalancing the small-state advantage
    in apportionment of electoral votes.

62
Winner-Take-All
  • Most states use a general ticket system in which
    votes chose among party slates of elector
    candidates.
  • Vote for one slate of
    electors
  • Democratic electors
  • Republican electors
  • Minor party electors
  • This effectively guarantees that a states
    electoral votes are cast winner-take-all.
  • However, earlier in some states electors ran as
    individuals on a generalized plurality basis.
  • Vote for no more than four elector candidates
  • D1 R1
  • D2 R2
  • D3 R3
  • D4 R4
  • Typically almost every voter would vote for all
    Democratic elector candidates or all Republican
    elector candidate, again producing a
    winner-take-result.

63
Almost Winner-Take-All
  • However, when the Presidential contest within the
    state was very close, small discrepancies among
    the votes for elector candidates might produce a
    divided electoral vote
  • D1 93,456 R1 91,993
  • D2 93,381 R2 91,553
  • D3 92,358 R3 90,852
  • D4 91,679 R4 90,761
  • In this case, the electoral vote would be divided
    3 for the Democratic ticket and 1 for the
    Republican ticket.
  • By convention, the popular vote for President
    in this state would be recorded as
  • Democratic ticket 93,456
  • Republican ticket 91,993

64
Bypassing the Contingent Procedure
  • Given a two-party system accommodated by the 12th
    Amendment, it is virtually assured that one or
    other Presidential (and Vice Presidential)
    candidate will receive the required majority of
    electoral votes.
  • Thus Madison hope to keep the election out of the
    House is realized,
  • not by coordination among the big states, but
  • by coordination (a nominating process) within
    each of two political parties.
  • In this way, the Electoral College system was
    transformed into something in two ways more
    favorable to large states than the Framers
    expected, i.e.,
  • not only do large states gain more power in the
    first (electoral vote) stage (due to
    winner-take-all electoral votes), but also
  • the second (House contingent election stage)
    stage (where small states have equal power) is
    almost always bypassed.

65
Inverse Duvergers Law and the Election of 1824
  • The inverse of Duvergers Law implies that
  • if one of the parties in a two-party system is
    greatly weakened, or is unable or unwilling to
    compete for votes effectively,
  • the dominant party is very likely to break apart,
    because the external threat that otherwise keeps
    it together is removed.
  • The election of 1824 (the second and last time an
    election was thrown into the House) is the
    exception that proved the rule that a two-party
    system bypasses the contingent procedure.
  • The Federalist Party had collapsed and the
    Democratic-Republican Party was unchallenged.
  • Consequently there was no longer pressure for
    D-Rs to unite behind a single Presidential-Vice
    Presidential ticket.
  • Four candidates, all nominally belonging to the
    same D-R party, sought the Presidency.
  • Unsurprisingly, no candidate received a majority
    of the electoral votes and the election was
    thrown into the House.

66
The Election 1824 (cont.)
  • The four candidates were
  • John Quincy Adams (Secretary of State)
  • Henry Clay (U.S. Representative and Speaker)
  • William Crawford (Secretary of the Treasury)
  • Andrew Jackson (hero of the Battle of New
    Orleans and representative of the common
    man)
  • Presidential election results (first
    round)
  • Electoral Votes
    Popular Votes
  • Jackson 99 41
  • Adams 84 31
  • Crawford 41 11
  • Clay 37 13
  • Others 0
    4
  • Bear in mind that six states still appointed
    electors and that states that used popular
    election varied considerably with respect to the
    extent of franchise.

67
The Election of 1824 (cont.)
  • The compromise candidate Clay (most everyones
    second choice, who probably could have defeated
    each other candidate in a straight fight) was
    squeezed out of third place in the electoral vote
    ranking by Crawford.
  • Under the 12th Amendment, the House could chose
    only from among top three candidates.
  • Clay probably would have been elected president
  • if the House could still chose among the top five
    candidates or
  • if Crawford had not been a candidate (i.e.,
    Crawford was a spoiler to Clay).
  • Even if Adams or Jackson h
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com