Title: Oligopoly
1Oligopoly
2Oligopoly - Competition among the Few
- In an oligopoly there are very few sellers of the
good. - The product may be differentiated among the
sellers (e.g. automobiles) or homogeneous (e.g.
gasoline). - Entry is often limited either by legal
restrictions (e.g. banking in most of the world)
or by a very large minimum efficient scale (e.g.
overnight mail service) or by strategic behavior. - Sill assuming complete and full information.
3How Oligopolists Compete
- In an oligopoly
- firms know that there are only a few large
competitors - competitors take account of the effects of their
actions on the overall market. - To predict the outcome of such a market,
economists must model the interaction between
firms and so often use game theory or game
theoretic principles.
4Three Basic Models
- Competition in quantities Cournot-Nash
equilibrium - Competition in prices Bertrand-Nash equilibrium
- Collusive oligopoly Chamberlin notion of
conscious parallelism - It is very useful to know some basic game theory
to understand these models as well as other
oligopoly models.
5Game Theory Setup
- List of players all the players are specified in
advance. - List of actions all the actions each player can
take. - Rules of play who moves and when.
- Information structure who knows what and when.
- Payoffs the amount each player gets for every
possible combination of the the players actions.
6A Classic Two Player, Two Action Game - The
Prisoners Dilemma
Chris
Lie
Confess
Lie
-1, -1
-6, 0
Roger
Confess
0, -6
-5,-5
- Rogers best response function
- If Chris lies, then Roger should confess (check
out left column, 1st entries) - If Chris confesses, then Roger should confess
(right column, 1st entries) - Confess is a dominant strategy for Roger
- Chriss best response function
- If Roger lies, then Chris should confess (see top
row, 2nd entries) - If Roger confesses, then Chris should confess
(bottom row, 2nd entries) - Confess is a dominant strategy for Chris
7A Classic Two Player, Two Action Game - The
Prisoners Dilemma
Chris
Lie
Confess
Lie
-1,-1
-6, 0
Roger
Confess
0, -6
-5,-5
- There is a single dominant strategy equilibrium
- Rogers confesses and
- Chris confesses
- They both go to jail for 5 years
- Note the game is played simultaneously and
non-cooperatively! - Ways to sustain the cooperative equilibrium (lie,
lie) - different payoff structures
- repeated play and trigger strategies
8Question Will There Always Be A Dominant
Strategy Equilibrium?
- AnswerNO!
- Then what?
- Look for Nash Equilibrium.
9Nash Equilibrium
- Named after John Nash - a Nobel Prize winner in
Economics. - The Nash Non-cooperative Equilibrium of a game is
a set of actions for all players that, when
played simultaneously, have the property that no
player can improve his payoff by playing a
different action, given the actions the others
are playing. - Each player maximizes his or her payoff under the
assumption that all other players will do
likewise.
10Another Example - The Price Game
Chris
Low
High
Low
20, 20
60, 0
Roger
High
0, 60
100, 100
- Rogers best response function
- If Chris goes low, then Roger should go low
(check out left column, 1st entries) - If Chris goes high, then Roger should high (right
column, 1st entries) - There is no dominant strategy for Roger
- Chriss best response function
- If Roger goes low, then Chris should go low (see
top row, 2nd entries) - If Roger goes high, then Chris should go high
(bottom row, 2nd entries) - There is no dominant strategy for Chris
11Another Example - The Price Game
Chris
Low
High
Low
20, 20
60, 0
Roger
High
0, 60
100, 100
- Rogers best response function
- If Chris goes low, then Roger should go low
- If Chris goes high, then Roger should high
- Chriss best response function
- If Roger goes low, then Chris should go low
- If Roger goes high, then Chris should go high
- Two Nash Equilibria (low, low) and (high, high)
- Respective Nash equilibrium payoffs (20,20) and
(100,100) - Which equilibrium will prevail? Good question.
12Another Example - The Simultaneous Entry Game
Roger - the entrant
enter
not enter
Chris - the incumbent
fight
fight
accommodate
accommodate
(Roger 0,Chris 0)
(Roger 2, Chris 2)
(Roger 1,Chris 5)
(Roger 1,Chris 5)
- Get two Nash equilibria
- (enter, accommodate) and (not enter, fight)
13Another Example - The Sequential Entry Game
Roger - the entrant
enter
not enter
Chris - the incumbent
fight
fight
accommodate
accommodate
(Roger 0,Chris 0)
(Roger 2, Chris 2)
(Roger 1,Chris 5)
(Roger 1,Chris 5)
- Still get two Nash equilibria
- (enter, accommodate) and (not enter, fight)
- Only one, however, is credible (enter,
accommodate)
14Another Two Player, Two Action Example
- The game has two players 1 2.
- Player 1 can move up or down (actions).
- Player 2 can move left or right (actions).
- If player 1 moves up and player 2 moves left
then player 1 gets 1 and player 2 gets 0
(payoffs). - The table shows all possible action pairs and
their associated payoffs.
15Player 1s Best Strategies
- If player 2 plays right, the best strategy
(action) for player 1 is to play up. - In this case player 1 will get a payoff of 1,
underlined.
16Player 2s Best Strategies
- If player 1 plays up then player 2s best
strategy (action) is to play right. - In this case, player 2 gets a payoff of 2,
underlined.
17Nash Equilibrium
- The table shows the best strategy (actions) for
player 1 against both of player 2s possible
actions (underlined first numbers). - The table also shows the best strategy (actions)
for player 2 against both of player 1s possible
actions (underlined second numbers). - Notice that both numbers are underlined in the
cell up,right. This is the Nash Equilibrium. - If player 1 plays up the best thing for player
2 to do is play right and vice versa.
18A Non-cooperative Outcome (Cournot-Nash Duopoly -
Competition in Quantities)
- Developed by Antoine Augustin Cournot in 1838.
- In a two firm oligopoly (called a duopoly), if
both firms set their output levels assuming that
the other firms strategic choice variable
(quantities in Cournot competition) is fixed, the
equilibrium outcome is a Cournot Nash
Non-cooperative Equilibrium. (Note Cournot
solved this oligopoly model many years before
Nash invented the equilibrium definition we are
using here).
19Setup of the Duopoly Problem Monopoly Outcome
- The table at the right shows the monopolists
best choice for the simple market demand curve
shown, assuming only whole quantities can be
chosen. - The monopolist maximizes profits at X3, P14,
with economic profits of 21. - Assuming only whole quantities can be produced,
the competitive equilibrium is X6, P8, the
last price at which economic profits are not
negative (FC0 and MC7 for all X).
20Duopoly Game Competition in Quantities
- Suppose that there are two firms X and Y with
identical total cost curves that are the same
ones shown for the monopolist in the previous
slide total cost7Xi - The payoff matrix above shows the economic
profits of Firm X (left entry) and Firm Y (right
entry) for each possible quantity supplied of 0
to 4 units. - The payoff for a firm is determined by finding
the price that prevails for the total quantity
supplied (Firm X Firm Y), then multiplying each
quantity by this price and subtracting the firms
total costs for that quantity. - Note demand price is PD20-2X where XXX XY
- Example Firm X supplies 3 and Firm Y supplies 1
- so X4 and P12 - Firm Xs payoff (3 x 12) - 21 15
- Firm Ys payoff (1 x 12) - 7 5
21Duopoly Game Nash Equilibrium in Quantities
- The boxes marked in yellow are the best moves for
Firm X given the indicated quantity supplied by
Firm Y. - The boxes marked in green are the best moves for
Firm Y given the indicated quantity supplied by
Firm X. - The payoff for the cell (X supplies 2, Y supplies
2) is (10, 10). This cell is the Nash
Non-cooperative Equilibrium for this game because
it represents the best move for Firm X given that
Firm Y chooses its best move and the best move
for Firm Y given that Firm X chooses its best
move. - Duopoly outcome Total quantity supplied 2 2
4. Market price 12. Total economic profits
10 10 20. - Monopoly outcome Total quantity supplied 3.
Market price 14. Total economic profits 21. - Competitive outcome Total quantity supplied 6.
Market price 8. Total economic profits 6.
22Properties of the Cournot-Nash Equilibrium for
Duopoly
- When the duopolists compete in quantities, we can
compare the outcome to both the monopoly and
competitive outcomes. - Each duopolist produces less than a monopolist in
the same market but together they produce more
than the monopolist and less than the amount two
competitive firms would have produced with the
same cost structure and demand curves. - The sum of the economic profits of each duopolist
is less than the economic profits of a monopoly
in the same market. - The market price is less than the one a
monopolist would charge but more than the
competitive price. - Deadweight loss is less than for a monopoly in
the same market but still positive, thus greater
than the deadweight loss from a competitive
market.
23Duopoly Game Competition in Prices (J. Bertrand
1883)
- Firm X and Y have the same cost structure and
face the same market as in the previous example. - Now, instead of playing a game in quantities,
they play a game in prices allowing only the
choices indicated. - The payoff matrix above shows the economic
profits of Firm X (left entry) and Firm Y (right
entry) for each possible price chosen 8, 10,
12, 14, 16. - If the two firms choose the same price they split
the market in half otherwise, the firm that
chooses the lower price sells the market quantity
and the other firm sells nothing. - Example Firm X charges 12 and Firm Y charges
12 - Market X 4, both firms sell 2 units at 12 and
have total costs of 14. - Firm X payoff Firm Y payoff 2 x 12 - 14
10. - Example Firm X charges 10 and Firm Y charges
8. - Market X 6, Firm Y sells all 6 units, Firm X
sells nothing. - Firm X payoff 0 Firm Y payoff 6 x 8 - 42
6.
24Duopoly Game Bertrand-Nash Equilibrium in Prices
- The boxes marked in yellow are the best moves for
Firm X given the indicated quantity supplied by
Firm Y. - The boxes marked in green are the best moves for
Firm Y given the indicated quantity supplied by
Firm X. - The payoff for the cell (X charges 8, Y charges
8) is (3, 3) and the payoff for the cell (X
charges 10, Y charges 10) is (7.5, 7.5). Both
cells are the Nash Non-cooperative Equilibria for
this game. - Duopoly competition in prices in this market does
not have a unique equilibrium (a common
occurrence in game theory). - This game predicts that the market price
fluctuates between 8 and 10. - This game predicts that the market quantity
fluctuates between 4 and 6. - It is not uncommon for the competition in
quantities game to give different results from
the competition in prices game.
25Performance Bertrand vs. Cournot
- When the duopolists compete in prices, we can
compare the outcome to both the monopoly and
competitive outcomes, but it can be more
difficult to find an equilibrium. - Classic results (when an equilibrium exists and
is unique). - N1 then XBN XSM and PBN PSM
- Ngt1 then XBN X and PBN P
- Bertrand compared to Cournot.
- N1 then XCN XSM and PCN PSM
- Ngt1 then X gt XCN gt XSM and Plt PCN lt PSM
- N gets large enough, XCN X and PCNP
- Results have different implications for
anti-trust action. - Should MCI be able to merge with Sprint? N goes
from 3 to 2. - Should Coke be allowed to merge with Dr. Pepper?
Should Pepsi be allowed to merge with 7-Up? - Good questions.
26A Cooperative Outcome (Collusion)
- The duopolists can do better than the Nash
Non-cooperative Equilibrium. - Because the equilibrium is non-cooperative, we
have ruled out the possibility of collusion
between the two firms. - Collusion means that the firms explicitly
cooperate in choosing a market price and the
division of output between them. - If the duopolists collude and divide up the
market privately, they can produce the monopoly
quantity and divide the monopoly economic
profits. - Since the monopoly economic profits are more than
the sum of the duopoly profits, the duopolists
are better off if they collude. - When we allow the possibility of collusion the
game can turn out differently.
27Duopoly Game Collusion
- In our previous example Firm X and Firm Y can
cooperate and agree to charge 14 and to produce
3 units between them. - They will earn the monopoly profits of 21 in
this case. - There is 1 of additional profit compared to the
quantity game and at least 6 of additional
profit compared to the price game. - Any division of this extra profit between the two
firms makes both firms willing to collude rather
than play the non-cooperative game. - The possibility of collusion is excluded from the
non-cooperative games by the assumption that the
firms strategies consist of either choosing a
quantity or choosing a price. - Collusion involves choosing a market quantity (or
price), production quotas for each member and a
division of the monopoly profit between the two
firms.
28Collusion Problems
- Frequently, side payments are essential to the
cooperative solution. Especially when the cartel
members have different cost structures. - OPEC example Iran and Saudi Arabia.
- Irans marginal costs increase more quickly than
do Saudi Arabias. - Suppose they do not cooperate and end up at the
Cournot-Nash solution Get profits such that
?SA ?I ?joint - Suppose they cooperate and implement the monopoly
solution Get profits such that ?SA ?I
?joint - Since Iran has the crummy marginal cost curve, it
will be told not to produce very much in the
collusive arrangement. - Could be that ?SA gt ?SA and ?joint gt ?joint
but ?I gt ?I ! - If joint cartel profit is larger than the joint
non-cooperative profit, then there is enough to
make side payments to Iran to get Irans
cooperation. - Will the side payments be made? Are they legal?
Good questions.
29Collusion Problems
- Side payments aside, there is also a compelling
incentive to cheat on the cartel arrangement. - Cheating often means that someone is violating
the cartels production limits - producing more
than they agreed to. - More ends up on the market than was supposed to.
- The price ends up lower than it was supposed to.
- The cartel starts to experience dissention.
- Steps are taken to shore up the cartel agreement.
- This strong internal tendency to cheat led Milton
Friedman to once opine that cartels were nothing
more than a flash in the pan. - How successful are cartels? How often do they
form? Are they able to substantially raise the
market? For how long? - Good questions.