Title: Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly
1Chapter 16Game Theory and Oligopoly
2Figure 16.1 The monopoly equilibrium
3The monopoly equilibrium
- This chapter uses the following linear market
demand curve p100-y - Assume that each firm in the industry has a
marginal/average/unit cost of 40. - MR 100-2y
- Profits are maximized by charging the price
associated with the optimal level of output -the
level of output where MRMC. - Total profits (TP) TR TC.
4Duopoly as a Prisoners Dilemma
- A Duopoly is an oligopoly in which there are only
two firms in the industry.
5Table 16.1 Duopoly profit matrix
6From Table 16.1
- L is the dominant strategy for both the First and
the Second Firm - Thus, the Nash-equilibrium combination is (L, L)
in which both firms produce 20 units and have a
profit of 200. - Yet, if they could agree to restrict their
individual outputs to 15 units a piece, each
could earn 450.
7The Oligopoly Problem
- Oligopolists have a clear incentive to collude or
cooperate. - Oligopolists have a clear incentive to cheat on
any simple collusive or cooperative agreement. - If an agreement is not a Nash equilibrium, it is
not self-enforcing.
8The Cournot Duopoly Model
- Central features of the Cournot Model
- Each firm chooses a quantity of output instead of
a price. - In choosing an output, each firm takes its
rivals output as given.
9Figure 16.2 Finding a Cournot best-response
function
10From Figure 16.2
- The First firms best response function is
y130 y2/2 - The Second firms best response function is
y230 y1/2 - Taken together, these two best response functions
can be used to find the equilibrium strategy
combination for Cournots model.
11Figure 16.3 The Cournot equilibrium
12The Cournot Model Key Assumptions
- The profit of one firm decreases as the output of
the other firm increases (other things being
equal). - The Nash equilibrium output for each firm is
positive.
13Isoprofit Curves
- All strategy combinations that give the first
firm the chosen level of profits is known as an
indifference curve or isoprofit curve. - Profits are constant along the isoprofit curve.
14Figure 16.4 Isoprofit or indifference curves
15From Figure 16.4
- y1 maximizes profits for the first firm, given
the second firms output of y2. - Any strategy combinations below the isocost curve
gives the first firm more profit than the Nash
equilibrium. - The result above relates to the key assumption
that the first firms profit increases as the
second firms output decreases.
16Figure 16.5 Joint profit not maximized in Nash
equilibrium
17Cournots Model Conclusions
- In the Nash equilibrium of this general version
of the Cournot model, firms fail to maximize
their joint profit. - Relative to joint profit maximization, firms
produce too much output in the Nash equilibrium.
18The Cournot Model with Many Firms
- With only one firm in the market, the
Cournot-Nash equilibrium is the monopoly
equilibrium. - As the number of firms increase, output
increases. As a result, price and aggregate
oligopoly profits decrease. - When there are infinitely many firms, the Cournot
model is, in effect, the perfectly competitive
model.
19The Cournot Model with Compliments
- The Cournot-Nash equilibrium in which firms
produce the same good is not Pareto-optimal, as
the firms produced too much. - The Cournot-Nash equilibrium in which firms
produce complements is not Pareto-optimal, as the
firms produced too little.
20The Bertrand Model
- The Bertrand model substitutes prices for
quantities as the variables to be chosen. - The goal is to find the Nash (the Bertrand-Nash)
equilibrium strategy combination when firms
choose prices instead of quantities.
21The Bertrand Model Firms Best Response Function
- Finding the best response function entails
answering the question Given p2, what value of
p1 maximizes the first firms profit. - Four possibilities exist
- 1. If its rival charges a price greater than the
monopoly price (MP), the first firms best
response is to charge a lower price (than MP) so
it can capture the entire market.
22The Bertrand Model Firms Best Response Function
- 2. If its rival charges a price less than the per
unit cost of production (p2), the first firms
best response is to choose any price greater than
this because firm one will attract no business
and incur a zero profit. This outcome is superior
to matching or undercutting p2, and posting
losses.
23The Bertrand Model Firms Best Response Function
- 3. If the second firms price is greater than the
per unit cost of production and less than the
monopoly price. - If p1lt p2, the first firm captures the entire
market and its profits increase as its price
increases. - When p1 p2, the two firms split the profit.
- When p1gt p2, the first firms profit is zero
because it sells nothing when its price exceeds
the second firms price. - (see Figure 16.6).
24Figure 16.6 Finding a Bertrand best-response
function
25The Bertrand Model Firms Best Response Function
- 4. Suppose the second firm sets its price exactly
equal to the per unit costs. - Then if the first firm sets a lower price it will
incur a loss on every unit it sells and profits
will be negative. If the first firm sets a price
above the per unit, it will sell no units and
profits are zero. If the first firm sets price
equal to the per unit costs, it breaks even.
26The Bertrand-Nash Equilibrium
- The Bertrand-Nash equilibrium strategy
combination has the second firm and the first
firm charging a price equal to the per unit cost
of production. - At this equilibrium, each firms profit is
exactly zero.
27The Collusive Model of Oligopoly
- The collusive model of oligopoly is when
oligopolists decide to collude on a joint
strategy. - In the Cournot and Bertrand models, the
equilibriums are individually rational but
collectively irrational, as firms have a clear
incentive to collude. - However, if firms do manage to form a collusive
agreement, there is a clear private incentive for
each party to cheat.
28The Collusive Model of Oligopoly
- In the Cournot model, the individual incentive to
cheat on the collusive agreement increases as the
number of parties to the agreement increases. - This means that the larger the number of firms in
an industry, the less likely is a collusive
equilibrium. - If the number of firms is large enough, some firm
or firms will succumb to the temptation to cheat,
thereby destroying the collusive agreement.
29Experimental Evidence
- Taken together, experiments suggest that no
single model is applicable to all oligopoly
situations. - Perhaps the most economists can hope for is a
selection of oligopoly models, each applicable to
a particular range of economic circumstances.
30The Limited-Output Model
- In the long run, the number of firms (market
structure) is endogenous. - The number of firms in an industry is determined
by economic considerations. - The key process in determining the long-run
equilibrium is the possibility of entry.
31The Limited Output Model
- Limited output models or limited price models
focus on the theory of the oligopoly in the long
run, where the number of firms is determined
endogenously and there is the possibility of
entry.
32Barriers to Entry
- A natural barrier to entry is setup costs.
- Assume all firms incur setup costs of S
- In any period, the rate of interest (i)
determines the set up cost (K)KiS - Adding fixed costs to variable costs (40y) gives
total cost function - C(y)K40Y
33Inducement to Entry
- If the fixed costs (K) are a barrier to entry,
what is an inducement to entry? - An inducement to entry is the excess of revenue
over variable costs.
34Figure16.7 The inducement to entry
35Inducement to Entry
- The entrants best response function is
yE30-y/2 - The entrants residual demand function is
Pe(100-y)-ye - The price that will prevail if the entrant
produces ye units is Pe70-y/2 - Profit per unit is Pe - 4030-y/2
36Inducement to Entry
- The inducement to entry, ye times (pe-40) is
then (30-y/)2. - This expression gives the revenue over variable
costs that the entrant would earn if established
firms continued to produce y units after entry. - Entry will occur if inducement to enter exceeds K.
37Inducement to Entry
- Call the smallest value of y, such that no entry
occurs, the limit output (yL). - (30-yL/2)2K
- Solving for YL YL 60-2K1/2
- If K100, YL40 units, If K225, YL30 units,
etc. - (see Figure 16.8)
-
38Inducement to Entry
- The no entry condition says entry will not occur
if the output of established firms is greater
than or equal to the limit output (yL) - The limit price (pL) is the price associated with
the limit output. - In this example
- pL100-yL or pL 402K1/2
39Figure 16.8 Identifying the limit price and the
limit output
40Strategic Choice of Industry Output
- The existing level of industry output (y) and
development costs (K) are barriers to entry. - If y is less than the limit output yL, the firm
will enter the industry. - If y is equal to or more than the limit output
yL, the firm will not enter the industry.
41Strategic Choice of Industry Output
- We have calculated that if K225, then yL30
(the monopoly output). - Thus, if setup costs are 225 or higher, the
monopoly output of 30 will successfully deter
entry a natural monopoly scenario.
42Strategic Choice of Industry Output
- If Klt 225, the ordinary monopolist output will
not deter entry (yLgt30). - In this case the monopolist will produce exactly
yL units of output. - Since it has already incurred the setup cost, its
objective is to maximize revenues over variable
costs (gross profits).
43Critique of the Model
- The postulate that entrants take the current
industry output as a given is the major weakness
of the limited-output model. - A potential entrants concern is not with present
but the future output of the sitting (currently
in the industry) monopolist.
44Critique of the Model
- When a sitting monopolist produces the limit
output, its decision is intended as a credible
warning to potential entrants that it will
continue to produce the limit output in the
future. - If entrants take this warning seriously, they
will stay out of the market.