Title: Lecture 3 Understanding Inequality: Structure and Dynamics
1Lecture 3Understanding InequalityStructure and
Dynamics
- Course on Poverty and Inequality Analysis
- Module 5 Inequality and Pro-Poor Growth
- Francisco H. G. Ferreira
- DECRG
2Roadmap
- Distributions
- The Determinants of Inequality a conceptual
overview - Inequality Decomposition Analysis
- Income Distribution Dynamics statistical
analysis - Income Distribution Dynamics towards economic
decompositions - Summing up
33.1. Distributions
- Social welfare, poverty and inequality summarize
different features of a distribution. - Distribution of welfare indicator per unit of
analysis. - Discrete y y1, y2, y3, ., yN
- Continuous The distribution function F(y) of a
variable y,defined over a population, gives the
measure of that population for whom the variable
has a value less than or equal to y.
4The density function f(x)
The distribution function
5The quantile function yF-1(p)
6The Lorenz curve
or
7The Generalized Lorenz curve
83.2. The Determinants of Inequality a
conceptual overview
- Inequality measures dispersion in a distribution.
Its determinants are thus the determinants of
that distribution. In a market economy, thats
nothing short of the full general equilibrium of
that economy. - One could think schematically in terms of
- y a.r
- This suggests a scheme based on assets and
returns - Asset accumulation
- Asset allocation / Use
- Determination of returns
- Demographics
- Redistribution
93.2. The Determinants of Inequality a
conceptual overview
103.2. The Determinants of Inequality a
conceptual overview
- Modeling these processes in an empirically
testable way is quite challenging. - Though there are G.E. models of wealth and income
distribution dynamics - Historically, empirical researchers have used
shortcuts, such as - decomposing inequality measures by population
subgroups, and attributing explanatory power to
those variables which had large between
components - Decomposing inequality by income sources, to
understand which contributed most to inequality,
and why - Decomposing changes in inequality into changes in
group composition, group mean and group
inequality.
113.3 Inequality Decomposition Analysisa. By
Population Subgroups
Not all inequality measures are decomposable, in
the sense that I IW IB. The Generalized
Entropy class is.
Examples include Theil L Theil T 0.5 CV2
123.3 Inequality Decomposition Analysisa. By
Population Subgroups
Let ? (k) be a partition of the population into k
subgroups, indexed by j. Similarly index means,
n, and subgroup inequality measures. Then if we
define
where
Then, E EB EW.
13An Example from Brazil
The Rise and Fall of Brazilian Inequality
1981-2004
14A cross-country example Race and ethnicity
decompositions.
Source WDR 2006
153.3 Inequality Decomposition Analysisa. By
Population Subgroups
- The methodology was developed by
- Bourguignon, F. (1979) "Decomposable Income
Inequality Measures", Econometrica, 47,
pp.901-20. - Cowell, F.A. (1980) "On the Structure of
Additive Inequality Measures", Review of Economic
Studies, 47, pp.521-31. - Shorrocks, A.F. (1980) "The Class of Additively
Decomposable Inequality Measures", Econometrica,
48, pp.613-25. - Reviewed in
- Cowell, F.A.and S.P. Jenkins (1995) "How much
inequality can we explain? A methodology and an
application to the USA", Economic Journal, 105,
pp.421-430. - Example from
- Ferreira, F.H.G., Phillippe Leite and J.A.
Litchfield (2001) The Rise and Fall of
Brazilian Inequality 1981-2004, World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper 3867.
163.3 Inequality Decomposition Analysisb. By
Income Sources
- Shorrocks A.F. (1982) Inequality Decomposition
by Factor Components, Econometrica, 50,
pp.193-211. - Noted that
could be written as
Correlation of income source with total income
Share of income source
Internal inequality of the source
173.3 Inequality Decomposition Analysisb. By
Income Sources
Source Ferreira, Leite and Litchfield, 2006.
184. Income Distribution Dynamicsa. Scalar
decompositions
Mookherjee, D. and A. Shorrocks (1982) "A
Decomposition Analysis of the Trend in UK Income
Inequality", Economic Journal, 92, pp.886-902.
Pure inequality
Group Size
Relative means
19The (obligatory) example from Brazil
The Rise and Fall of Brazilian Inequality
1981-2004
204. Income Distribution Dynamicsb. A More
Disaggregated Look
- In practice, decompositions of changes in scalar
measures suffer from serious shortcomings - Informationally inefficient, as information on
entire distribution is collapsed into single
number. - Decompositions do not control for one another.
- Can not separate asset redistribution from
changes in returns. - With increasing data availability and
computational power, studies that decompose
entire distributions have become more common. - Juhn, Murphy and Pierce, JPE 1993
- DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux, Econometrica, 1996
213.4. Income Distribution Dynamicsb. The
Oaxaca-Blinder Decomposition
- These approaches draw on the standard
Oaxaca-Blinder Decompositions (Oaxaca, 1973
Blinder, 1973) - Let there be two groups denoted by r w, b.
- Then and
- So that
- Or
- Caveats (i) means only (ii) path-dependence
(iii) statistical decomposition not suitable for
GE interpretation.
returns component
characteristics component
223.4. Income Distribution Dynamicsb. Juhn,
Murphy and Pierce (1993)
Juhn, Murphy and Pierce (1993)
where
Define
Then
Returns component
Unobserved charac. component
Observed charac. Component.
233.4. Income Distribution Dynamicsb. DFL and BFL
How and why does fA(y) differ from fB(y)?
One could decompose fB(y) - fA(y) into
where
A similar (but distinct) decomposition would be
obtained with
243.4. Income Distribution Dynamicsb. DiNardo,
Fortin and Lemieux (1996)
Essentially, DFL propose estimating a
counterfactual income distribution such as
By appropriately reweighing the sample, as
follows.
where
253.4. Income Distribution Dynamicsb.
Bourguignon, Ferreira and Lustig (2005).
Partition the set of covariates T into V and W,
where V can logically depend on W.
Replace the joint distribution of covariates by
the appropriate product of conditional
distributions, and the joint distribution of W.
Define a counterfactual distribution fsA?B(y
ks, ?A). I.e.
Note that the order of conditioning will
affect interpretation.
263.4. Income Distribution Dynamicsb.
Bourguignon, Ferreira and Lustig (2005).
For each counterfactual distribution fs, the
difference between fA and fB can be decomposed as
follows   And it follows that
273.4. Income Distribution Dynamicsb.
Bourguignon, Ferreira and Lustig (2005).
- Estimate - for each country or time period -
simple econometric models of earnings,
occupational structure, education and fertility
choices. - Simulate the effects of importing the parameter
estimates of each model from county A into
country B (individually or jointly). - Decompose distributional differences into
- Price effects
- Occupational structure effects
- Endowment (or population characteristic) effects
283.4. Income Distribution Dynamicsb. Brazil,
1976-1996. (Ferreira and Paes de Barros, 1999)
Level 1 y G (V, W, ? ?) Â Aggregation
rule  Earnings  Occupational
Choice   Level 2 V H (W, ?
?) Â Education MLE (E?A, R, r, g, nah
?) Â Fertility MLC ( nch ?E, A, R, r, g, nah
?) Â Â
29Comparing g(p) and gs(p) (i) The price effect.
30Comparing g(p) and gs(p) (ii) The price effect
and the occupational structure effect combined.
31Comparing g(p) and gs(p) (i) Price, Occupation,
Education and Fertility effects.
323.5. Income Distribution Dynamics a. towards
economic decompositions?
- Generalized Oaxaca-Blinder decompositions such as
those discussed above, whether parametric or
semi-parametric, suffer from two shortcomings - Path-dependence
- The counterfactuals do not correspond to an
economic equilibrium. There is no guarantee that
those counterfactual incomes would be sustained
after agents were allowed to respond and the
economy reached a new equilibrium.
33(a) Partial Equilibrium Approaches
- The first step towards economic decompositions,
in which the counterfactual distributions may be
interpreted as corresponding to a counterfactual
economic equilibrium, is partial in nature. - One example comes from attempts to simulate
distributions after some transfer, in which
household responses to the transfer (in terms of
child schooling and labor supply) are
incorporated. - Bourguignon, Ferreira and Leite (2003)
- Todd and Wolpin (2005)
- (These two papers differ considerably in how they
model behavior. Todd and Wolpin are much more
structural.)
34(b) General Equilibrium Approaches
- However, a number of changes which are isolated
in statistical counterfactuals such as changes
in returns to education, or in the distribution
of years of schooling are likely to have
general equilibrium effects. - Similarly, certain policies one might like to
simulate may require a general equilibrium
setting. - There are two basic approaches to generate
GE-compatible counterfactual income distributions
(and thus counterfactual GICs) - Fully disaggregated CGE models, where each
household is individually linked to the
production and consumption modules. E.g. Chen and
Ravallion, 2003, for China. - Leaner macroeconomic models linked to
microsimulation modules on a household survey
dataset. E.g. Bourguignon, Robilliard and
Robinson, 2005, for Indonesia.
35Distributional Impact of Chinas accession to the
WTO. (Chen Ravallion, 2003)
GE-compatible counterfactual GICs corresponding
to a specific policy.
36(b) General Equilibrium Approaches (continued).
- In the Macro-Micro approach, some key
counterfactual linkage variables are generated in
a leaner macro model, whose parameters may have
been calibrated or estimated from a time-series,
and then fed into sector-specific equations
estimated in the household survey, to generate a
counterfactual GIC.
Macro model
Linkage AggregatedVariables (prices, wages,
employment levels)
Household income micro-simulation model
37The distribution of the impacts of the 1999
Brazilian devaluation (Ferreira, Leite, Pereira
and Pichetti, 2004)
383.6. Summing up
- There has long been an interest in understanding
changes in (or differences across) income
distributions. - Static and dynamic decompositions of certain
measures of inequality (by population subgroup or
income source) can shed some light on the
structure of inequality, and on the importance
of covariates. - But decompositions of scalar indices are
inherently informationally constrained.
Disaggregated statistical decompositions based on
entire counterfactual distributions
(parametrically or semi-parametrically) help shed
more light on changes (and to separate the
effects of returns, participation and composition
effects). - A step beyond this sort of statistical analysis
is to build counterfactual distributions that
correspond to economic equilibria. If sensibly
estimated, these would allow inference of
causality and hence policy simulations. - Some progress on simple partial equilibrium
models. - Harder with general equilibrium approaches, where
CGEs or macro models are subject to many
criticisms.