Title: Econ 805 Advanced Micro Theory 1
1Econ 805Advanced Micro Theory 1
- Dan Quint
- Fall 2009
- Lecture 4
2Today Necessary and Sufficient Conditions For
Equilibrium
- Problem set 1 online shortly
- Last lecture integral form of the Envelope
Theorem holds in equilibrium of any Independent
Private Value auction where - The highest type wins the object
- The lowest possible type gets expected payoff 0
- Today necessary and sufficient conditions for a
particular bidding function to be a symmetric
equilibrium in such an auction
3Todays General Results
- Consider a symmetric independent private values
model of some auction, and a bid function b T ?
R - Define g(x,t) as one bidders expected payoff,
given type t and bid x, if all the other bidders
bid according to b - Under fairly broad (but not all) conditions
- everyone bidding according to b is an
equilibrium - b strictly increasing and g(b(t),t)
g(b(t),t) òtt FN-1(s) ds
4Necessary Conditions
5With symmetric IPV, b strictly increasing implies
the envelope theorem
- If everyone bids according to the same bid
function b, - And b is strictly increasing,
- Then the highest type wins,
- And so the envelope theorem holds
- So what were really asking here is when a
symmetric bid function must be strictly increasing
6When must bid functions be increasing?
- Equilibrium strategies are solutions to the
maximization problem maxx g(x,t) - What conditions on g makes every selection x(t)
from x(t) nondecreasing?
7When must bid functions be increasing?
- Recall supermodularity and Topkis
- Strong Set Order two sets A, B. A ³SSO B if
for every x gt x,(x Î B and x Î A) ? (x Î B and
x Î A). - (What this means visually.)
- A function g X x T ? R has increasing
differences if for every x gt x, the difference
g(x,t) g(x,t) is nondecreasing in t - Topkis if g(x,t) has increasing differences and
t gt t, thenx(t) ³SSO x(t) - This means there exists some selection x(t) from
x(t) which is monotonic - But it does not guarantee that every selection is
monotonic, so it doesnt answer our question - We need something stronger than increasing
differences in some ways (although what we use is
weaker in others)
8Single crossing and single crossing differences
properties (Milgrom/Shannon)
- A function h T ? R satisfies the strict single
crossing property if for every t gt t, - h(t) ³ 0 ? h(t) gt 0
- (Also known as, h crosses 0 only once, from
below) - A function g X x T ? R satisfies the strict
single crossing differences property if for every
x gt x, the function h(t) g(x,t) g(x,t)
satisfies strict single crossing - That is, g satisfies strict single crossing
differences if - g(x,t) g(x,t) ³ 0 ? g(x,t) g(x,t) gt
0 - for every x gt x, t gt t
- (When gt exists everywhere, a sufficient
condition is for gt to be strictly increasing in
x)
9What single-crossing differences gives us
- Theorem. Suppose g(x,t) satisfies strict single
crossing differences. Let S Í X be any subset.
Let x(t) arg maxx Î S g(x,t), and let x(t) be
any (pointwise) selection from x(t). Then x(t)
is nondecreasing in t. - Proof. Let t gt t, x x(t) and x x(t).
- By optimality, g(x,t) ³ g(x,t) and g(x,t) ³
g(x,t) - So g(x,t) g(x,t) ³ 0 and g(x,t)
g(x,t) 0 - If x gt x, this violates strict single crossing
differences
Milgrom (PATW) theorem 4.1, or a special case
of theorem 4 in Milgrom/Shannon 1994
10Strict single-crossing differences will hold in
most symmetric IPV auctions
- Suppose b T ? R is a symmetric equilibrium of
some auction game in our general setup - Assume that the other N-1 bidders bid according
to bg(x,t) t Pr(win bid x) E(pay
bid x) - t W(x) P(x)
- For x gt x,
- g(x,t) g(x,t) W(x) W(x) t
P(x) P(x) - When does this satisfy strict single-crossing?
11When is strict single crossing satisfied
byg(x,t) g(x,t) W(x) W(x) t
P(x) P(x) ?
- Assume W(x) ³ W(x) (probability of winning
nondecreasing in bid) - g(x,t) g(x,t) is weakly increasing in t, so if
its strictly positive at t, its strictly
positive at t gt t - Need to check that if g(x,t) g(x,t) 0, then
g(x,t) g(x,t) gt 0 - This can only fail if W(x) W(x)
- If b has convex range, W(x) gt W(x), so strict
single crossing differences holds and b must be
nondecreasing (e.g. T convex, b continuous) - If W(x) W(x) and P(x) ¹ P(x) (e.g.,
first-price auction, since P(x) x), then
g(x,t) g(x,t) ¹ 0, so theres nothing to check - But, if W(x) W(x) and P(x) P(x), then
bidding x and x give the same expected payoff,
so b(t) x and b(t) x could happen in
equilibrium - Example. A second-price auction, with values
uniformly distributed over 0,1 È 2,3. The
bid function b(2) 1, b(1) 2, b(vi) vi
otherwise is a symmetric equilibrium. - But other than in a few weird situations, b will
be nondecreasing
12b will almost always be strictly increasing
- Suppose b(-) were constant over some range of
types t,t - Then there is positive probability
- (N 1) F(t) F(t) FN 2(t)
- of tying with one other bidder by bidding b
(plus the additional possibility of tying with
multiple bidders) - Suppose you only pay if you win let B be the
expected payment, conditional on bidding b and
winning - Since t gt t, either t gt B or B gt t, so
either you strictly prefer to win at t or you
strictly prefer to lose at t - Assume that when you tie, you win with
probability greater than 0 but less than 1 - Then you can strictly gain in expectation either
by reducing b(t) by a sufficiently small amount,
or by raising b(t) by a sufficiently small
amount - (In addition when T has point mass
second-price first-price)
13So to sum up, in well-behaved symmetric IPV
auctions, except in very weird situations,
- any symmetric equilibrium bid function will be
strictly increasing, - and the envelope formula will therefore hold
- Next when are these sufficient conditions for a
bid function b to be a symmetric equilibrium?
14Sufficiency
15What are generally sufficient conditions for
optimality in this type of problem?
- A function g(x,t) satisfies the smooth single
crossing differences condition if for any x gt x
and t gt t, - g(x,t) g(x,t) gt 0 ? g(x,t) g(x,t) gt 0
- g(x,t) g(x,t) ³ 0 ? g(x,t) g(x,t) ³ 0
- gx(x,t) 0 ? gx(x,td) ³ 0 ³ gx(x,t d)
for all d gt 0 - Theorem. (PATW th 4.2) Suppose g(x,t) is
continuously differentiable and has the smooth
single crossing differences property. Let x
0,1 ? R have range X, and suppose x is the sum
of a jump function and an absolutely continuous
function. If - x is nondecreasing, and
- the envelope formula holds for every t,
- g(x(t),t) g(x(0),0) ò0t gt(x(s),s) ds
- then x(t) Î arg maxx Î X g(x,t)
- (Note that x only guaranteed optimal over X, not
over all X)
16But
- Establishing smooth single-crossing differences
requires a bunch of conditions on b - We can use the payoff structure of an IPV auction
to give a simpler proof - Proof is taken from Myerson (Optimal Auctions),
which were doing on Thursday anyway
17Claim
- Theorem. Consider any auction where the highest
bid gets the object. Assume the type space T
has no point masses. Let b T ? R be any
function, and define g(x,t) in the usual way. If - b is strictly increasing, and
- the envelope formula holds for every t,
- g(b(t),t) g(b(0),0) ò0t FN-1(s) ds
- then g(b(t),t) ³ g(b(t),t), that is, no bidder
can gain by making a bid that a different type
would make. - If, in addition, the type space T is convex, b
is continuous, and neither the highest nor the
lowest type can gain by bidding outside the range
of b, then everyone bidding b is an equilibrium.
18Proof.
- Note that when you bid b(s), you win with
probability FN-1(s) let z(s) denote the expected
payment you make from bidding s - Suppose a bidder had a true type of t and bid
b(t) instead of b(t) - The gain from doing this is
- g(b(t), t) g(b(t), t) t FN-1(t) z(t)
g(b(t),t) - (t t) FN-1(t) t FN-1(t) z(t)
g(b(t),t) - (t t) FN-1(t) g(x(t),t) g(x(t),t)
- Suppose t gt t. By assumption, the envelope
theorem holds, so - (t t) FN-1(t) òtt FN-1(s) ds
- òtt FN-1(s) FN-1(t) ds
- But F is increasing (weakly), so FN-1(t) ³
FN-1(s) for every s in the integral, so this is
(weakly) negative - Symmetric argument holds for t lt t
- So the envelope formula is exactly the condition
that there is never a gain to deviating to a
different types equilibrium bid
19Proof.
- All thats left is deviations to bids outside the
range of b - With T convex and b continuous, the bid
distribution has convex support, so we only need
to check deviations to bids above and below the
range of b - Assume (for notational ease) that T 0,T
- If some type t deviated to a bid B gt b(T), his
expected gain would be - g(B,t) g(b(t),t) g(B,t) g(b(T),t)
g(b(T),t) g(b(t),t) - The second term is nonpositive (another types
bid isnt a profitable deviation) - We also know g(x,t) t Pr(win bid x) z(x)
has increasing differences in x and t, so for B gt
b(T), if g(B,t) g(b(T),t) gt 0, g(B,T)
g(b(T),t) gt 0 - So if the highest type T cant gain by bidding
above b(T), no one can - By the symmetric argument, we only need to check
the lowest types incentive to bid below b(0) - (If b was discontinuous or T had holes, we would
need to also check deviations to the holes in
the range of b) - QED
20So basically, in well-behaved symmetric IPV
auctions,
- b T ? R is a symmetric equilibrium if and only
if - b is increasing, and
- b (and the g derived from it) satisfy the
envelope formula
21Up next
- Recasting auctions as direct revelation
mechanisms - Optimal (revenue-maximizing) auctions
- Might want to take a look at the Myerson paper,
or the treatment in one of the textbooks - If you dont know mechanism design, dont worry,
well go over it