Title: Single Firm Conduct: Same Conduct, Different Views
1Single Firm Conduct Same Conduct, Different Views
- John Briggs
- Trevor Soames
- Ronald Stern
- Prof. Bruce Kobayashi
- Scott Sher
- James Kress
2Single Firm Conduct Same Conduct, Different Views
- Emil Paulis
- Director, DG Competition
- European Commission
- Brussels, Belgium
3Single Firm Conduct Same Conduct, Different Views
- Trevor Soames
- Managing Partner (Brussels)
- Howrey LLP
4Multiple Enforcers
Â
5Single Firm Conduct Same Conduct, Different Views
- Ronald A. Stern
- Vice President and Senior Antitrust Counsel
- General Electric Company
- Washington, DC
6Single Firm Conduct Same Conduct, Different Views
- Dr. Bruce A. Kobayashi
- Assoc. Dean of Academic Affairs
- George Mason University
- School of Law
7Single Firm Conduct Same Conduct, Different Views
- Scot Sher
- Partner
- Wilson Sonsini Goodrich Rosati
- Reston, Virginia
8Fundamental Differences Section 2 (US) Article
82 (EU)
- Policy Differences
- US More concerned about errors that will
stifle competition (false negatives) - EU More concerned about errors that will lead
to under-enforcement (false positives) - Proof of Harm
- US Plaintiff must demonstrate ACTUAL harm to
competition - EU Plaintiff needs to show only POTENTIAL harm
to competition - Evidentiary Standards
- US Ratchets up the analysis quantum of proof
is high - EU Lower evidentiary standards intent evidence
is relevant
9Exclusive Dealing
- US
- Trending away from simple structural
presumptions. - Market share and duration less important
- Move to analysis of effect on market (Dentsply
Gilbarco Microsoft) - EU
- Ostensibly, per se illegal for dominant firms to
engage in exclusive dealing arrangements - British Airways It is not necessary to
demonstrate that the abuse in question had a
concrete effect on the markets. It is sufficient
. . . To demonstrate that the abusive conduct . .
. TENDS to restrict competition . . . Or . . . IS
CAPABLE of doing so. - Major differentiation Burdens and standards.
10Is the picture so clear in the US? NOT REALLY
- There is quite a bit of confusion in the U.S. as
well as to what constitutes unlawful exclusive
dealing - Are one year exclusives presumptively lawful?
(Gilbarco Dentsply) - Is it necessary to demonstrate that the
foreclosed competitors are efficient? (Dentsply
LePages) - Do you need to demonstrate complete foreclosure
to END USERS, or simply foreclosure of
DISTRIBUTION? - Role of Business Justifications
11Is the picture so clear in the U.S., continued
- LePages
- In addition to exclusive dealing, you have the
question of bundled rebating - Finds above-cost bundled pricing illegal
- Questions
- efficiency of competitors?
- LePages had 67 market share POST scheme.
- Counter-Concerns If stores perceive they need
scotch tape from 3M, why not buy both from 3M,
lowering transaction costs and getting full
bundle. Is this legit competition?
12TyingIs there convergence?
- Whats a Tie?
- Conditioning the sale of one product (tying
product) on the purchase of a less favored
product (tied product) - US
- Traditional Rule If a party has market power,
tying is per se illegal (Jefferson Parrish) - EU
- Traditional Rule If a party has market power,
tying is per se illegal (Tetra Pak).
13Tying, Continued
- And then there was Microsoft
- US Rule of Reason for Technology Ties
- EU Rule of Reason for Technology Ties
- BUT
- The language in the Commissions decision in
Microsoft suggests a far higher burden for
defendants - E.g., Potential to foreclose competition
serious risk of foreclosing competition. - In the United States, the balancing test requires
a plaintiff to demonstrate ACTUAL harm to
competition
14Again, is the law so clear in the U.S.?NOT REALLY
- Even though a modified per se approach still
governs, business justifications can save the
day. - Jerrold Electronics new product goodwill
- In re Data General pass through cost
efficiencies - Beware Independent Ink
15Does the Sherman Act, Section 2 Apply to the New
Economy?
- The basic principles are the same. The Sherman
Act was, as many have said, you know, a charter
of economic freedom, and that those basic
principles do have to be applied regardless of
changes in the economics of the underlying
businesses or the structure of the markets. - ....
- My basic instinct, and it's nothing more than
that, is that the principles are there and the
issue is simply application in a new context.
16EU and US Perspectives on Strategic Pricing By
Dominant Firms
- James G. Kress
- Partner
- Howrey LLP
17Significant Disclaimers
- No claim that U.S. antitrust law and policy
regarding the treatment of dominant firms is - Superior
- Transparent
- Applied Consistently
- Static
18A Question of Perspective
- The successful competitor having been urged to
compete, must not be turned upon when he wins - Dominant firm not required to pull its
competitive punches or hold pricing umbrella
over heads of its rivals - Even the largest firms may engage in hard
competition, knowing that this will enlarge their
market shares
- Dominant firm bears special responsibility not
to impair competition - Although dominant firm entitled to take
reasonable steps to protect its commercial
interest, it does not countenance acts whose
actual purpose is to strengthen that . .
.position
19A Question of Perspective
- Firms intend to do all the business they can, to
crush their rivals if they can to penalize this
intent is to penalize competition itself. - Depriving the leading firm in an industry of the
incentive to exert its best efforts . . . may
compel the very sloth antitrust laws intended
to prevent.
- Competitive effects not required because
establishing the anticompetitive object and
anticompetitive effect are one and the same
thing." - Condemning fidelity-building rebate system
that tends to prevent customers from obtaining
supplies from competitors without showing any
concrete effect on the markets concerned
20Michelin II
- 2003 Decision of European CFI
- Market Truck and Bus tires in France
- Michelin is dominant in that market
- Challenged Conduct
- Quantity rebates based on sliding scale
applicable to all purchasers - Not based on customers historical performance or
reaching certain targets - Not applied in discriminatory manner
- Rebates had significant variation in levels,
applied to all sales in one year period -
21Michelin II Rebates
- Loyalty rebates those that require customer to
obtain stock exclusively or almost exclusively
from dominant firm violate Art. 82. - Market share rebates
- Quantity rebates based on individualized targets
- Quantity rebates based solely on volume
generally not considered to foreclose
competition, UNLESS . . . - rules for granting the rebate reveal that the
system is not . . . economically justified but .
. . to prevent customers from obtaining supplies
from competitors.
22Michelin II Holding
- Program was loyalty-inducing in that quantity
rebate system tended to prevent dealers from
being able to select competitors offerings
freely at any time . . .without suffering any
appreciable economic disadvantage. - Is this per se illegality?
- For the purposes of applying Art. 82,
establishing the anti-competitive object and
anti-competitive effect are one and the same
thing. If it is shown that dominant firms
conduct was intended to limit competition, that
conduct will also be liable to have such an
effect.
23Concord Boat v. Brunswick
- Market Stern-drive engines for boats
- Brunswick at all times dominant
- gt 75 market share when conduct commenced
- Challenged conduct
- Vertical acquisitions of boat companies
- 3 rebate programs with boat builders
- Market share rebates (1-3)
- Rebates for longer term market share commitments
(1-2) - Volume discounts (up to 5)
24Concord Boat
- Plaintiffs argued that structured rebates
amounted to golden handcuffs, and a tax in
the form of foregone rebates imposed on
purchasers for dealing with rivals - Court applied classic Brooke Group predatory
pricing law to structured rebate claims. - Pricing below Average Variable Cost
- Likelihood of Recoupment
25Concord Boat
- Emphasized need for great caution when dealing
with claims of lower prices in any form - low prices benefit consumers regardless of how
those prices are set (ARCO). - No claim that prices were below Brunswick cost
- Dealers remained free to walk away took better
deals when offered could buy up to 40 from
others without losing all discounts
26British Airways
- 2003 Decision of European CFI (Virgin Atlantic)
- Market UK market for air travel agency services
- BA more than 50 share
- Conduct Incentive Compensation
- Performance award based on increasing BA ticket
sales one year to next - Market share growth incentives with 3 agencies
- Monthly performance awards based on agent
exceeding benchmark of monthly sales for prior
year -
27BA Theories of Abuse
- Article 82 challenge based, in part, on
exclusionary impact on competing airlines given
the loyalty-inducing structure of incentive plans - Rebates linked to volumes of purchases from
dominant firms are generally lawful, except - where 1 the criteria and rules for granting
that rebate show that system is not based upon an
economically justified consideration but 2
tends, like a fidelity rebate, to prevent
customers from obtaining supplies from rival
producers. -
28BA Exclusionary Effects
- Effects not necessary to demonstrate that the
abuse in question had a concrete effect on the
markets concerned. - Likelihood of Success the fact that the
hoped-for result exclusion is not achieved is
not sufficient to prevent a finding of abuse of a
dominant position. - Rebuttable Presumption The fact that BAs
rivals grew and prospered during the period in
question - In the absence of those practices, it may
legitimately be considered that the market shares
of those competitors would have been able to grow
more significantly. -
29JBDL v. Wyeth-Ayerst Labs
- Market Oral Estrogen Replacement Therapy (ERT)
- Wyeth (Premarin) market share 68-75
- Significant price increases after entry by
competitor - Evidence of actual exclusion from some
formularies - Monopoly not disputed on SJ
- Conduct alleged foreclosure of rival ERT drug
by Duramed based on (a) exclusive placement
contracts with some PBMs (b) structured rebates
on multiple Wyeth drugs dependent on Premarin
30Wyeth - Intent
- (1) Treated as undisputed Wyeths intent and
desire to thwart Cenestins market share growth
through PBM contracting practices - (2) Undisputed evidence that a manufacturer
desires or intends to maintain or increase its
market share at the expense of a new competitor,
does not by itself create a triable issue of
whether Wyeths chosen means to achieve that
desire violated the Sherman Act.
31Wyeth
- Initially, the Court rejects Wyeths somewhat
simplistic argument that its lack of predatory
pricing mandates dismissal of the Section2
claims. Plaintiffs essential complaint is that
Wyeths contracts rebates plus limited
exclusivity prevented Cenestin from becoming a
competitive threat, and thus allowed Wyeth to
unlawfully raise its Premarin prices after
Cenestins introduction. - Court seeks guidance in Lepages, Concord Board,
Dentsply, Conwood . . .
32Wyeth
- LePages Multi-tiered bundled rebates plus
exclusivity with large retailers - The Third Circuit decision also leaves unclear
(at least to this Court) the precise nature of
3Ms violation of Section 2. The verdict imposed
a heavy penalty on 3M without producing
consistent guidance for what is permissible price
competition . . . - Concord Board Strong support for application of
Brooke Group test, without endorsing above cost
pricing via rebates as per se lawful. - Dentsply Distinguishable because thwarted all
competition from dealer network where
overwhelming majority of teeth sold. - Conwood No such tortious conduct involved
here.
33Wyeth Horns of a dilemma
- Thus, this Court finds itself faced with
somewhat imprecise and certainly conflicting
standards by which to judge Plaintiffs
allegations of Wyeths monopolistic behavior.
LePages obviously favors letting a jury sort it
out, using the same imprecise, conflicting
Section 2 standards transformed into jury
instructions. Concord Boat, on the other hand,
illustrates the dangerous possibility of a
tremendous waste of time and resources of all
involved here in permitting a jury to sort it
out when the appellate court may well find that
there is no jury issue here.
34Wyeth
- Holding
- Given near impossible task for jury to divine
metaphysical differences between exclusionary
conduct and competition on the merits when
dealing with strategic pricing practices, and
risks of chilling beneficial price competition,
Court determines that Concord Boat is correct. - Grants summary judgment
35