Title: The Capital Asset Pricing Model CAPM
1- The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
2Understand the implications of capital market
theory and the CAPM to compute security risk
premiums
- What have we done this far?
- We have been concerned with how an individual or
institution, acting on a set of estimates, could
select an optimum portfolio. - If investors act as we think, we should be able
to draw on the analysis to determine how the
aggregate of investors will behave, and more
importantly how prices, and returns at which
markets will clear are set - The development of general equilibrium models
allows us to determine the relevant measure of
risk for any asset and the relationship between
expected return and risk for any asset when the
markets are in equilibrium
3Capital Asset Pricing Theory
- What is capital asset pricing theory?
- It is the theory behind the pricing of assets
which takes into account the risk and return
characteristics of the asset and the market - What is the CAPM, i.e. the Capital Asset Pricing
Model? - It is an equilibrium model (i.e., a constant
state model) that underlies all modern financial
theory - It provides a precise prediction between the
relationship between the risk of an asset and its
expected return when the market is in equilibrium - With this model, we can identify mis-pricing of
securities (in the long-run)
4CAPM (continued)
- Why is it important?
- It provides a benchmark rate of return for
evaluating possible investments, and identifying
potential mis-pricing of investments - For example, an analyst might want to know
whether the expected return she forecast is more
or less than its fair market return. - It helps us make an educated guess as to the
expected return on assets that have not yet been
traded in the marketplace - For example, how do we price an initial public
offering?
5CAPM (continued)
- How was it derived?
- Derived using principles of diversification with
very simplified (i.e. somewhat unrealistic)
assumptions - Does it work, i.e. withstand empirical tests in
real life? - Not totally
- But it does offer insights that are important and
its accuracy may be sufficient for some
applications - Do we use it?
- Yes, but with knowledge of its limitations
6CAPM Assumptions
- CAPM by William Sharpe (1964), John Lintner
(1965), and Jan Mossin (1966) - What does the model assume (some are
unrealistic)? - Individual investors are price takers (cannot
affect prices) - Single-period investment horizon (an its
identical for all) - Investments are limited to traded financial
assets - No taxes, and no transaction costs (costless
trading) - Information is costless and available to all
investors - Investors are rational mean-variance optimizers
- Investors analyze information in the same way,
and have the same view, i.e., homogeneous
expectations
7Resulting Equilibrium Conditions
- Based on the previous assumptions
- All investors will hold the same portfolio for
risky assets the market portfolio (M) - The market portfolio (M) contains all securities
and the proportion of each security is its market
value as a percentage of total market value. M
will be on the efficient frontier - The risk premium on the market depends on the
average risk aversion of all market participants - The risk premium on an individual security is a
function of its covariance (correlation and ss
sm) with the market
8The Risk Premium of the Market Portfolio
- Recall y ( a proportion allocated to the risky
optimal portfolio M) - y E (rp) - rf / 0.01 A ?p 2
- In the simple CAPM, net borrowing lending
across all investors must be zero ? y 1 - with y 1, E (rp) - rf 0.01 A ?p 2
the risk premium on the market portfolio depends
on average degree of risk aversion and ?p 2
9Capital Market Line
E(r)
M Market portfolio rf Risk free rate E(rM) -
rf Market risk premium E(rM) - rf/sM Market
price of risk
CML
M
E(rM)
rf
The efficient frontier without lending or
borrowing
s
sm
10Expected Return and Risk of Individual Securities
- What does this imply?
- The risk premium on individual securities is a
function of the individual securitys
contribution to the risk of the market portfolio - Individual securitys risk premium is a function
of the covariance of returns with the assets that
make up the market portfolio
11CAPM Key Thoughts
- Key statements
- Portfolio risk is what matters to investors, and
portfolio risk is what governs the risk premiums
they demand - Non-systematic, or diversifiable risk can be
reduced through diversification. Investors need
to be compensated for bearing only systematic
risk (cannot be diversified away) - The contribution of a security to the risk of a
portfolio depends only on its systematic risk, as
measured by beta. So the risk premium of the
asset is proportional to its beta.
12Expected Return Beta Relationship
- Expected return - beta relationship of CAPM
- E(rM) - rf E(rs)
- rf - 1.0
bs - In other words, the expected rate of return of an
asset exceeds the risk-free rate by a risk
premium equal to the assets systematic risk (its
beta) times the risk premium of the market
portfolio. This leads to the familiar
re-arrangement of terms to give (memorize this) - E(rs) rf bs E(rM) - rf
13The CAPM
- The expected return-beta relationship
- E(ri) rf ?i E(rM) - rf , where ?i cov(ri,
rM) /?M2. - ?M 1 ?i gt 1 aggressive, ?i lt 1
defensive - The beta of a stock measures the stocks
contribution to the variance of the market
portfolio measures only systematic risk - CAPM the securitys risk premium is directly
proportional to both the beta the risk premium
of the mkt port.
14The Security Market Line
- Notice that instead of using standard deviation,
the SML uses Beta - SML Relationships
- b COV(ri,rm) / sm2
- Slope SML E(rm) rf market risk
- premium
E(r)
SML
E(rM)
rf
SML rf bE(rm) - rf
ß
ß
1.0
M
15CML and SML
- Beta and Standard Deviation
- Total risk of a share Market risk of the share
- Specific Risk
- Total risk of a portfolio Market risk of the
portfolio - Specific Risk(negligible)
16Example SML Calculations
- Put the following data on the SML. Are they in
equilibrium? - Market data E(rm) - rf .08 rf .03
- Asset data bx 1.25 by .60
- Calculations
- bx 1.25 so E(r) on x
- E(rx) .03 1.25(.08) .13 or 13
- by .60 so E(r) on y
- E(ry) .03 .6(.08) .078 or 7.8
17Graph of Sample Calculations
E(r)
SML
Rx13
.08
Rm11
Ry7.8
They are in equilibrium
3
ß
1.0
1.25
.6
ß
ß
ß
m
y
x
18Disequilibrium Example
- Suppose a security with a beta of 1.25 is
offering expected return of 15 - According to SML, it should be 13
- Under priced offering too high of a rate of
return for its level of risk. Investors
therefore would - Buy the security, which would increase demand,
which would increase the price, which would
decrease the return until it came back into line. - fairly priced assets plot on the SML
- under-priced assets plot above the SML
- over-priced assets plot below the SML
19Disequilibrium Example
E(r)
The return is above the SML, so you would buy it
SML
15
As more people bought the security, it would push
the price up, which would bring the return down
to the line.
Rm11
rf3
ß
1.0
1.25
20CAPM and Index Models
- CAPM Problems
- It relies on a theoretical market portfolio which
includes all assets - It deals with expected returns
- To get away from these problems and make it
testable, we change it and use an Index model
which - Uses an actual index, i.e. the SP 500 for
measurement - Uses realized, not expected returns
- Now the Index model is testable
21The Index Model
- With the Index model, we can
- Specify a way to measure the factor that affects
returns (the return of the Index) - Separate the rate of return on a security into
its macro (systematic) and micro (firm-specific)
components - Components
- ? excess return if market factor is zero
- ßiRm component of returns due to movements in
the overall market - ei component attributable to company specific
events - Ri a i ßiRm ei
- (Notice the similarity to the Single Index model
discussed earlier)
22Alpha
- The difference between the fair and actually
expected rates of return on a stock. - SML E(ri) rf ?i E(rM) - rf
- E(ri) - rf ?i E(rM) - rf
- Ex. ? 1.2 rf 5 E(rM) - rf 8 E(ri)
16 - SML E(ri) 5 1.2 (8) 14.6 fair return
- ? 16 - 14.6 1.4 gt 0.
23Does the CAPM hold?
- There is much evidence that supports the CAPM
- There is also evidence that does not support the
CAPM - Is the CAPM useful?
- Yes. Return and risk are linearly related for
securities and portfolios over long periods of
time - Yes. Investors are compensated for taking on
added market risk, but not diversifiable risk - Perhaps instead of determining whether the CAPM
is true or not, we might ask Are there better
models?
24Boeings Historical Beta
25Problem CAPM
- Suppose the risk premium on the market portfolio
is 9, and we estimate the beta of Dell as bs
1.3. The risk premium predicted for the stock is
therefore 1.3 times the market risk premium of 9
or 11.7. The expected return on Dell is the
risk-free rate plus the risk premium. For
example, if the T-bill rate were 5m the expected
return of Dell would be 51.39 16.7. - a. If the estimate of the beta of Dell were only
1.2, what would be Dells required risk premium? - b. If the market risk premium were only 8 and
Dells beta was 1.3, what would be Dells risk
premium?
26Answer
- a. If Dells beta was 1.2 the required risk
premium would be (remember the risk premium is
the expected return less the risk-free rate) - E(rs) rf bs E(rM) - rf or the expected
return on Dell 5 1.2 (9) 15.8 - Dells risk premium (over the risk free rate)
- 15.8 - 5 10.8
- b. If the market risk premium was 8
- E(rs) rf bs E(rM) - rf
- E(r) of Dell 5 1.3 (8) 15.4
- Dells new risk premium is 15.4 5 10.4
27Using the Markowitz model to do Active Portfolio
Management
- The Markowitz portfolio selection model requires
- E(ri) N
- var(ri) N ? need (N2
3N)/2 estimates - cov(ri, rj) (N2 - N)/2
- Ex. If N 100, we need 10,300/2 5,150
estimates. - 500,
125,750 - Another difficulty in applying the Markowitz
model to portfolio optimization is that errors in
the assessment or estimation of correlation
coefficients can lead to nonsensical results.
28Using the Markowitz model to do Active Portfolio
Management
- Moreover, using seemingly reasonable estimates of
expected returns and covariances can lead to
unreasonable portfolio weights. - Small errors in mean or covariance estimates lead
to unreasonable weights - A remedy for both of these problems is to use (1)
a single factor model to calculate asset
covariances, (2) and use the CAPM to determine
what market expectations must be, and then
combine your views with the CAPM-derived
estimates to get portfolio weights. - The key input we will need for both of these is
the set of asset ßs. So, first, we must consider
the problem of estimating ßs.
29The Single Factor Model
- By the properties of regression, the residuals
have a mean of zero, and are uncorrelated with
the returns on the SP 500. - Thus, the return on Microsoft is decomposed into
- A constant term.
- Movements in the SP 500 index return.
- Movements in a component unrelated to market
movements.
30Specification of a Single Index Model
- Is this a good model?
- A model is of little use unless we can test a way
to measure the factor we say affects security
returns. It is not testable in its above form.
To make it testable, we - Use the rate of return on a broad index of
securities, such as the SP 500, for a proxy. So
now ßiM becomes ßiRm, or M is equal to the return
on the market - The expected holding period return E(Ri) becomes
ai, because that is the stocks excess return
assuming the markets excess return is zero - So the new testable model becomes
- RiaißiRmei or substituting (ri-rf)
aißi(rm-rf) ei
31Active Portfolio Management
- An alternative approach is to accept market
opinion and simply hold the market portfolio. - Calculate ßs for the securities we plan to hold
- Using these ßs, calculate E(ri)s and ?i,js by
using the single index model (and the CAPM) - Using these estimates and the Markowitz portfolio
optimization tools, determine our optimal
portfolio weighs
32A single Index Model
- Use the mkt index return to proxy for F F ?
rM - ri - rf ?i ?i rM - rf ei, or
- Ri ?i ?i RM ei, where Ri ri - rf,
RM rM rf - Each security has two sources of risk market
risk and firm-specific risk - For the index model
- E(ri) N
- ?i N
- var(ei) N ? need (3N 1) estimates
- ?M2 1
- Ex. If N 100, we need 301 estimates (vs.
5,150)
33A single Index Model
- var(Ri) ?i2 ?i2 ?M2 ?2(ei),
- Because cov(RM, ei) 0,
- cov(Ri, Rj) cov (?i RM, ?jRM) ?i ?j ?M2.
- Because cov( ei, ej) 0.
- Advantages
- Reduce the number of inputs for diversification
- Easier for security analysts to specialize
- The index model suggests a simple way to compute
covariance. - However, the single index model oversimplifies
sources of real-world uncertainty and misses some
important sources of dependence in stock returns.