Title: Social Preferences, Norms and Culture
1Social Preferences, Norms and Culture
- Presentation to the Meetings of the
- Latin American Field Experiments Network
- November 21, 2008
- James Konow
1
2Disclosure Statement
- No previous studies conducted in or related to
Latin America - Laboratory experiments but no field experiments
- Latin American Field Experiments Network
2
3Disclosure Statement
- No previous studies conducted in or related to
Latin America - Laboratory experiments but no field experiments
- Latin American Field Experiments Network
- Plans to extend social preference research to the
field in Latin America
3
4Overview of Research
- Theme Moral preferences and their consequences
- Impartiality and moral bias
- Equity/accountability principle
- Multi-criterion theory of distributive justice
- Fairness and risk
- Reciprocity and moral bias
- Happiness and morality
- Moral principles and moral norms across cultures
- Intersection of empirical research with normative
ethics and public policy
4
4
5Accountability Principle
- Accountability Principle (JEBO 1996)
- An individuals fair allocation varies in direct
proportion to the value of the relevant variables
the individual controls (e.g., effort, choices)
but does not hold the individual accountable for
variables he/she cannot reasonably influence
(endowed resources, innate skills) - Implication fair allocations are proportional to
controllable contributions but equalize
differences that arise because of noncontrollable
variables
5
6Illustration
- Suppose Amy and Bob work at the same job, and Amy
is twice as productive as Bob - Amys earnings should be twice Bobs if this
productivity difference is due entirely to
factors they both control like effort, choices
about job training, etc. - Fair allocations are equal, however, if Amys
greater productivity is due entirely to variables
they both cannot control like endowed resources,
innate skills, etc. - Attitudinal survey supports the fairness of
allocations that comply with this principle and
unfairness of allocations that violate it
6
7Theory and Experiment
- Social preference theory and experimental test
(AER 2000) - Theory incorporates fairness, self-interest and
self-deception - Fairness corresponds to accountability
- Moral bias deviation of behavior from moral
principle because of self-interest - Moral bias has two possible sources
- Unadulterated (i.e., acknowledged) self-interest
- Self-deception believing it is fair to be unfair
- Weights placed on fairness, self-interest and
self-deception vary across individuals
7
7
8Experimental Test of Theory
- Dictator experiment consisting of two phases
- Phase 1
- All subjects generate earnings by preparing
letters for mailing - Subjects (A and B) are paired up, and their
earnings are credited to a joint account assigned
to each pair - Phase 2
- For each pair, one subject (called the Dictator)
is arbitrarily chosen to allocate the earnings
between the two subjects
8
9Spectator Decisions
- The subjects chosen as Dictators varied with the
treatment - Spectator treatments
- For each A,B pair, a third party subject (C) was
chosen to allocate earnings among A and B and was
paid a fixed fee unrelated to this decision - Predictions
- Dictators who are Spectators should be motivated
only by fairness, since they have no stake in the
earnings they are allocating - Spectator allocations will reveal whether or not
fairness corresponds to proportionality
9
10Results of Spectator Allocations
- Fraction of letters produced by A subjects are on
horizontal axis - Fraction of earnings allocated to A subjects are
on vertical axis - Proportional allocations lie on 45 degree line
10
11Stakeholder Decisions
- Stakeholder treatments
- One subject from each pair (A) was randomly
chosen to allocate earnings between A and B
(called the Recipient) no third party Dictator - Predictions
- These Stakeholders will act on a combination of
motives self-interest and fairness - There will be differences in the weight placed on
self-interest and fairness across individual
subjects
11
12Results of Stakeholder Allocations
- Fraction of letters produced by the Dictator (A)
are on horizontal axis - Fraction of earnings taken by the Dictator are on
vertical axis - Fair allocations lie on 45 degree line
- Self-interested ones lie in the shaded triangle
above this line
12
13When Variables Are Not under Control
- Two additional treatments in same study
contributions are not under individual control - Subjects now have enough time to prepare all
letters, i.e., they produce equal numbers of
letters - Money created differs, however, because of
arbitrary differences in the per letter credits
that always favored the A subjects - Results
- Spectator allocations do not differ significantly
from equality - Stakeholders typically take amounts between fair
(equal) shares and the whole pie
13
14Fairness and Self-Deception
- Self-deception has been put forth to explain
fairness related enigmas (Babcock and Loewenstein
1997) - Bargaining impasse (litigation, labor
negotiations) - If parties understand fairness, they should be
able to come to an agreement, even if it is not
their most favored outcome - Allocation decisions (voting on taxes, dictator
experiment) - How much unfairness is due to unadulterated
(acknowledged) self-interest and how much because
of self-deception? - This study contained first behavioral measure of
self-deception
14
15Measure of Self-Deception
- Treatment with Stakeholders where earnings
differences were not under individual control - Dictators (A) had higher per letter credits,
e.g., 75 cents per letter for the Dictator and 25
cents per letter for the Recipient (B) - Then unannounced second decision where Dictators
(A) made an allocation as Spectator between two
other subjects, C and D, whose per letter credits
were the same as A and B, respectively
15
16Predictions and Results
- Predictions
- Dictators (A) should allocate according to their
beliefs between C and D - If unfairness is pure acknowledged self-interest,
A should divide earnings equally between C and D - If self-deception is at work, A should give C an
amount close to what A took previously and an
amount to D that is close to what A gave to B
previously - Results
- Almost two-thirds of unfairness is due to
self-deception - This is in spite of a very sterile laboratory
context that is not conducive to self-deception
16
17Related Research Questions
- Generality Does the Accountability Principle
exhaust our moral intuition about justice or
ethics in general? - Reciprocity Is there a moral bias in
reciprocity? - Happiness Are ethical people happier?
- Methodology Can empirical research using
spectators inform ethics and public policy? - Robustness Do social preferences differ across
cultures? - Risk Is it fair to reward risk-taking or to
compensate risk-takers for their losses? - Moral education Can people be taught to think or
act more ethically?
17
18Multi-criterion Theory of Justice
- Accountability Principle sometimes conflicts with
moral intuition should engineers and janitors
earn the same, even if their only differences are
innate? - Distributive justice involves trade-offs between
three principles (JEBO 2001, JEL 2003) - Accountability (or Equity), Efficiency and Need
- Accountability is the quintessence of justice it
is what is distinctive even if it is not always
most important - The importance of each principle depends in
patterned ways on the context, i.e., information
about the relevant variable(s) and the people
affected
18
19Equity and Need
- Dictator allocates 10 in two treatments (Mixed
Feelings 2008) - Standard treatment Recipients are fellow
students - Charity treatment Recipients are charities
19
20Reciprocal Altruism
- Distributive justice is about outcomes
- People also care about intentions, i.e., did
someone intend to hurt (or help) me or was it
accidental? - People reciprocate intentions, i.e., are more
than fair to those who are kind to them and less
than fair to those who are unkind to them - Several studies demonstrate that stakeholders
punish unkindness more vigorously than they
reward kindness
20
21Social Preferences and Moral Biases
- Dictator study of distributive and reciprocal
preferences with stakeholders and spectators
(Croson and Konow, JEBO in press) - Stakeholders punish unkindness more than they
reward kindness for two reasons - Moral bias they are more inclined to punish and
less inclined to reward than spectators effect
of self-interest - Reciprocal asymmetry even spectators punish more
than they reward
21
22Happiness and Morality
- Are more generous people happier and, if so, why?
- Dictator study uses psychological measures of
short-run and long-run happiness (Konow and
Earley, JPubE 2008) - More generous people have higher long-run
happiness - Generosity does not make people happier in the
short run, in fact, it sometimes makes them less
happy - Money does not buy happiness or produce more
generous behavior - Conclusion Acts of generosity are like
investments that are costly in the short-run but
produce a return of higher average happiness in
the long-run
22
23Impartial Spectator Method
- Spectator method potentially helpful tool for
empirical investigation of social preferences,
public policy deliberations and philosophical
discussions - Informed by Adam Smiths Theory of Moral
Sentiments - Providing relevant information to spectators
creates consensus, which is valued in empirical
social science and by leading philosophical
schools of thought about impartiality
(forthcoming Social Choice and Welfare) - Spectator method can reduce stakeholder bias and
create consensus, which can inform ethics, public
policy, deliberative democracy and public
opinion research (Moral High Ground 2008)
23
24Cross Cultural Evidence on Justice
- Two stage Dictator experiment with production
replicated in the US and Japan (Konow, Saijo and
Akai, Morals and Mores 2008) - Distinction between morals and mores
- Morals are impartial moral preferences, i.e.,
preferences of spectators - Mores are moral norms, i.e., distributive
preferences of stakeholders in personal
relationships, which includes consideration of
stakes and of level of anonymity - Prediction in the context of distributive
justice, morals correspond to accountability and
mores cause a shift toward equality
24
25Conclusions on Morals and Mores
- Patterns that hold for both US and Japanese
subjects - Spectators allocate proportionately according to
accountability - Having a stake moves allocations toward equality
- Knowing and being known by others shifts
allocations further toward equality - US, but not Japanese, stakeholders exhibit a
significant moral bias - Interesting not only what is significant, but
also what is not demographic and cultural
variables almost never matter - Values and norms are the same in very different
countries, although the willingness to act on
them differs across these two countries
25
26Fairness and Risk-Taking
- Two stage dictator experiment (Cappelen, Konow,
Sørensen and Tungodden, 2008) - Subjects decide between risky or safe
alternatives, and the risky outcome is randomly
determined - Subjects are paired and dictators allocate the
earnings - Dictators fall into three distinct and very
different groups based on whether they consider
choices and/or luck in making their allocations - Plurality of fairness views does not bode well
for social consensus on whether to reward
risk-taking or compensate losses of unlucky
risk-takers (Wall Street bailout)
26
27Does Ethics Training Encourage Morality?
- Three part study (unpublished results)
- Traditional instruction in moral philosophy does
not systematically affect everyday moral
judgments - Targeted morality lectures impact behavior, but
in specific ways moral reasoning increases
generosity, whereas enlightened self-interest
increases cooperation - Community service increases generosity, although
this effect appears entirely to current service
activities - Ethics instruction, both formal and experiential,
can increase morality (behavior), but the
duration of its effects are in doubt, suggesting
ethics instruction must be ongoing
27
28Does Ethics Training Encourage Morality?
- Three part study (unpublished results)
- Traditional instruction in moral philosophy does
not systematically affect everyday moral
judgments - Targeted morality lectures impact behavior, but
in specific ways moral reasoning increases
generosity, whereas enlightened self-interest
increases cooperation - Community service increases generosity, although
this effect appears entirely to current service
activities - Ethics training, both formal and experiential,
can increase morality (behavior), but the
duration of its effects are in doubt, suggesting
ethics instruction must be ongoing
28
29Current and Future Work Environment
- Theme Environment and Moral Norms
- Incipient work Norms, Green Agents and
Environmental Policy (Brekke, Konow and Nyborg,
in progress) - Questions
- Does the framing of a public goods problem affect
the interpretation of the appropriate fairness
norm and, therefore, the level of cooperation? - Do norms differ between spectators or
stakeholders? - Possible future work
- How does the framing of the public goods problem
affect cooperation in Latin American countries? - How are these framing effects triggered in the
field?
29
30Current and Future WorkProcedural Justice
- Distributive justice concerns outcomes fairness
in the allocation of social and economic goods - Procedural justice concerns fairness of the
processes, rules and procedures by which the
outcomes are obtained - The same outcome might be viewed as fair or
unfair, depending on how it came about - Example Frey et al. (JPE 1997) find acceptance
of local siting of nuclear waste repositories
depends significantly on process
30
31Experiments on Procedural Justice
- Lottery game (unpublished results)
- Subjects state bids to opt out of a lottery
- Individual decision affects only the
decision-maker and Matched decision affects
decision-maker and counterpart - Contrast between Individual and Matched decisions
reveals a small preference for fair outcomes
beyond fair process (fair expected values)
31
32Experiments on Procedural Justice, continued
- Spite game (unpublished results)
- Multiple round experiment
- Productive task
- High productivity subjects matched with Low
productivity subjects - Ultimatum-like game without information about
productivity discrete choice of equal or
proportional offers rejection results in unequal
earnings - Second ultimatum game with productivity
information - Results High productivity Proposers more likely
to make proportional offers when know, Low
Proposers more likely to equalize, subjects do
not prefer more information
32
33Future Work onProcedural Justice
- Cross-cultural experiments on procedural justice
- Do comparable samples of Latin American subjects
consider the same procedures fair as North
American ones? - Field experiments on procedural justice
- What evidence is there of preferences for
procedural justice in the field? - Can one conduct a series of nested experiments
of procedural justice experiments across the lab
and field?
33
34Future Work onProcedural Justice
- Cross-cultural experiments on procedural justice
- Do comparable samples of Latin American and North
American subjects consider the same procedures
fair? - Field experiments on procedural justice
- What evidence is there of preferences for
procedural justice in the field? - What evidence might emerge from a series of
nested experiments of procedural justice
experiments across the lab and field?
34