Title: Chapter 5: Production and Cost
1Chapter 5 Production and Cost
- Brickley, Smith, and Zimmerman, Managerial
Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th
ed.
2Chapter Objectives
- Describe production function and distinguish
between returns to scale and returns to a factor - Use isocosts and isoquants to illustrate
production trade-offs - Employ short and long run cost curves to describe
firm characteristics - Productions functions, choice of inputs, costs,
profit maximization, cost estimation, and factor
demand curves
3Production Functions
- A production function is a descriptive relation
that links inputs with output. - It specifies the maximum feasible output that can
be produced for given amounts of inputs. - Production functions are determined by the
available technology
4Production functions
- A production function specifies maximum output
from given inputs for instance, given current
technology, an automobile supplier is able to
transform inputs like steel, aluminum, plastics,
and labor into finished auto parts. - In its most general form, the production function
is expressed as - Where Q is the quantity produced and x1, x2, .xn
are various inputs used in the production process
5Production functions
- To simplify the exposition, suppose that the auto
part in this example is produced from just two
inputs steel and aluminum. - An example of a specific production function in
this context is QS1/2A1/2 - Where S is pounds of steel, A is pounds of
aluminum, Q is the number of auto parts produced
6Production functions
- With this production, 100 pounds of steel and 100
pounds of aluminum will produce 100 auto parts - And 400 pounds of steel and 100 pounds of
aluminum will produce 200 auto parts, and so on
Please see page 131 for complete details and
calculations - 1001/2 X 1001/2 10 X 10 100
- 4001/2 X 1001/2 20 X 10 200
7Returns to scale
- Defined The relation between output and a
proportional variation of all inputs together - With a constant returns to scale used in our
previous example, a 1 percent change in all
inputs results in a 1 percent change in output.
If the firm increases both inputs from 100 to
101, it produces 101 auto parts instead of 100 - Increasing returns to scale QSA
- Decreasing returns to scale QS1/3A1/3
- Constant returns to scale QS1/2A1/2
8Returns to scale
- Increasing returns to scale QSA a 1 percent
change in all inputs results in a greater than 1
percent change in output - Decreasing returns to scale QS1/3A1/3 a 1
percent change in all inputs results in a less
than 1 percent change in output - Constant returns to scale QS1/2A a 1 percent
increase in inputs results in 1 percent change in
output - Next slide shows this relationship between costs
and returns to scale
9Long-Run Production Costs
Alternative Long-Run ATC Shapes
Economies Of Scale
Constant Returns To Scale
Diseconomies Of Scale
Average Total Costs
Long-Run ATC
q1
q2
Output
Long-Run ATC Curve Where Economies Of Scale Exist
10Returns to a Factor
- Refers to the relationship between output and the
variation in a single input, holding other inputs
fixed. - Returns to a factor can be expressed as total,
marginal or average quantities - The total product of an input is the schedule of
output obtained as that input increases, holding
other inputs fixed - The marginal product of an input is the change in
total output associated with a one-unit change in
the input, holding other inputs fixed - The average product is the total product divided
by the number of units of the inputs employed
11Returns to a factor page 132, Table 5.1
- Production function QS1/2A1/2
12Law of Diminishing Marginal Product
- The law of diminishing marginal returns explains
this relationship between total, marginal and
average product, - Which states that the marginal product of a
variable factor eventually will decline as its
use is increased holding other factors fixed,
page 133 - Next slide shows this relationship through cost
curves
13Returns to a factora common case Figure 5.1,
page 134
14Short-Run Production Relationships
- Total Product (TP)
- Marginal Product (MP)
- Average Product (AP)
15Law of Diminishing Returns
- Rationale
- Tabular Example
0 10 25 45 60 70 75 75 70
- 10.00 12.50 15.00 15.00 14.00 12.50 10.71 8.75
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
10 15 20 15 10 5 0 -5
Increasing Marginal Returns
Diminishing Marginal Returns
Negative Marginal Returns
16Law of Diminishing Returns
TP
Increasing Marginal Returns
Diminishing Marginal Returns
Negative Marginal Returns
AP
MP
17Choice of Inputs - Production isoquants
- Most production function allow some substitution
among inputs different combinations of inputs
that can be used to produce the same output - Isoquants portray technical combination of inputs
to produce a given level of output - Shape of isoquants indicates substitutability
between input
18Isoquants Curve
- Iso, meaning the same, and quant from quantity
- An isoquant show all input combinations that
produce the same quantity of output assuming
efficient production efficiency allows you to
produce maximum quantity (on the curve) with
given inputs. Any points inside or outside the
curve may be attainable but are inefficient - There is a different isoquant curve for each
possible level of production. Figure 5.2, page
135 shows the isoquants for 100, 200 and 300 auto
parts for the production function QS1/2A1/2
19Optimal input combinationisoquants Figure 5.2,
page 135
20Differing input substitutabilityisoquants -
Figure 5.3, page 136
21Differing input substitutabilityisoquants -
Figure 5.3, page 136
- Production functions vary in terms of how easily
inputs can be substituted for one another. -
- Right Angle (fixed proportions, no substitutes)
inputs may be used in fixed proportions and no
substitute is possible - Straight Lines (perfect substitutes) at the other
extreme are perfect substitutes, where inputs can
be freely substituted for one another. Here,
isoquants are straight lines. - Normal Case (Convex to the origin, curvature line
but are not right angles) Most production
functions have isoquants that are between the two
extremes. The isoquants in the normal cases.
Convexity implies that the substitutability of
one input for another declines as less of the
first is used
22Isocost Lines
- Given that there are many ways to produce a given
level of output, how does a manager choose the
most efficient input mix? - The answer depends on the costs of the inputs TC
Ps S Pa A Total Cost price of steel times
quantity of steel price of aluminum times
quantity of aluminum (5.5, page 136)
23Isocost lines - Figure 5.4, page 137
- Isocosts portray combinations of inputs that
entail the same cost iso same, cost of
different combinations of inputs - Isocost lines for different expenditure levels
are parallel (holding the price of inputs
constant) - In this example Price of steel is 0.50 per pound
and Price of aluminum is 1 per pound. The
figure shows isocost lines for 100 and 200 of
expenditures. The slope of the line is -1 times
the ratio of the input prices in this example,
-0.5. - The farther away the line from the origin, the
higher the total cost - Isocosts change as input prices change
24Isocost lines holding the prices of inputs
constant, p137
25Isocost lineschanges in input prices (TC 100)
- Figure 5.5, page 138
26Optimal input mix - 5.8, page 139
- Where MPi is the marginal product of input i and
Pi is the price of input i. - This means that last dollar spent on each input
bring the same amount of output. Ratio is equal.
Any other combination will not minimize costs - Where MRP MRC (marginal resource product and
costs are equal
27Cost minimization - Figure 5.6, page 138
28Cost Minimization Figure 5.6, page 138
- The input that minimizes the cost of producing
any given output Q, occurs where an isocost line
is tangent to the relevant isoquant - In this example, the tangency occurs at (S, A).
This is where combination of inputs can be
achieved at lowest cost. - The firm would prefer to be on an isocost line
closer to the origin because of lower costs
closer to origin. - However, the firm would not have sufficient
resources to produce Q. - The firm could produce Q using other input
mixes, such as (S, A). However, the cost of
production would increase.
29Optimal input mixinput price changes - Figure
5.7, page 140
30Optimal input mixinput price changes - Figure
5.7, page 140
- This figure illustrates how the optimal input mix
for producing a given output, Q, changes as the
price of an input increases and the firm uses
less steel and more aluminum to produce the
output. - This effect is called substitution effect
- The strength of the substitution effect depends
on the curvature - the greater the curvature, the less the firm will
substitute between two inputs because - It will resemble right angle isoquant in which
substitution is not possible
31Costs
- We have analyzed how firms should choose their
input mix to minimize costs of production - We now extend this analysis to focus more
specifically on costs of producing different
levels of output - Analysis of these costs plays an important role
in output and pricing decisions
32Cost concepts
- Total cost
- relation between total cost and output
- Marginal cost
- change in total cost when output rises one unit
- Average cost
- total cost divided by total output
- Opportunity cost
- value of best alternative resource use
33Cost curves - Figure 5.8, page 141
34Short run versus long run
- Short run
- at least one input is fixed
- cost curves are operating curves
- Long run
- all inputs are variable
- cost curves are planning curves
- Fixed costs--incurred even if firm produces
nothing - Variable costs--change with the level of output
35Short-run cost curves - Figure 5.9, p144
36Long-run average costenvelope of short-run
average cost curves page 145
37Long-run average and marginal cost curves Figure
5.11, page 146
38Additional cost concepts
- Minimum efficient scale
- plant size at which long-run average cost first
reaches its minimum point (Q) - Economies of scope
- cost of producing a joint set of products is less
than cost of producing separately in separate
firms - Learning curves
- costs decline with production experience
39Learning Curves
- For some firms, the long-run average cost of
producing a given level of output declines as the
firm gains production experience due to improved
production processes, proficiency of workers and
experience on the job - A learning curve displays the relation between
average cost for a given period, Q, and
cumulative past production volume - Figure 5.12, page 148 presents an example where
there are significant learning effects in the
early stages of production. Eventually however,
these effects frequently become minimal as the
firm continues to produce the product
40Learning curve
41Economies of Scale Versus Learning Effects Figure
5.13, page 148
- Economies of scale imply reductions in average
cost as the quantity being produced within the
production period increase - Learning Effects imply a shift in the entire
average cost curve down The average cost for
producing a given quantity in a production period
decreases with cumulative volume
42Economies of scale versus learning effects
43Economies of scale versus learning effects
- Example Please read Economies of Scale and
Learning Effects in the Chemical Processing
Industry top pink box, page 149
44Economies of Scope
- Thus far we have focused on the production of a
single product. Most firms, however, produce
multiple products. - Economies of scope exist when the cost of
producing a set of products jointly within one
firm is less than the cost of producing the
products separately across independent firms
45Economies of Scope
- Economies of scope help explain why firms produce
multiple products. - For instance, PepsiCO is a major producer of soft
drinks yet it also produces a wide range of
snack foods (for example, corn chips, and
cookies). - These multiple products allow PepsiCo to leverage
its product development, distribution, and
marketing systems.
46Economies of Scope versus Economies of Scale
- Are different concepts. Economies of scope
involves cost savings that result from joint
production - Whereas economies of scale involve efficiencies
from producing higher volumes of a given products - It is possible to have economies of scope without
having economies of scale and vice versa - Please read two examples Apartment Management
p149 and DSP production, p 150
47Profit maximization
- Thus far, we have focused on the costs of
producing different levels of output - However, what level of output should a manager
choose to maximize firm profits? - To answer this question, we return to the concept
of marginal analysis initially introduced in
chapter 2
48Profit maximization
- A firm should increase output as long as marginal
revenue exceeds marginal cost - A firm should not increase output if marginal
cost exceeds marginal revenue, instead it should
cut back the production - At the profit-maximizing level of output,
- MRMC
49Optimal output and changes in marginal cost -
Figure 5.14, page 151
50Optimal output and changes in marginal cost -
Figure 5.14, page 151
- This figure illustrates that a decrease in
marginal cost (from MC0 to MC1) raises the
optimal level of output of the firm (from Q0 to
Q1) - Opposite would be true if MC would have shifted
upward - At the profit-maximizing level of output,
- MRMC
51Factor demand curve - Figure 5.15, p 152
52Factor demand curve - Figure 5.15, p 152
- The demand curve for a factor of production is
the marginal revenue product curve (MRP) for the
input - The MRP (marginal revenue product) is defined as
MP (marginal product) of the inputs times the MR
(marginal revenue) - It represents the additional revenue that comes
from using one more unit of input. - The firm maximizes profits where it purchases
inputs up to the point where the price of the
input (MC) equals its MRP (MR)
53Optimal Combination of Resources
- Two questions are considered
- The Least-Cost Combination Rule (1)
- The cost of any output is minimized when the
ratios of marginal product to price of the last
units of resources used are the same for each
resources
54Least cost rule
- The cost of producing any specific output can be
reduced as long as equation 1 does not hold. - Any firm that combines resources in violation of
the least-cost rule would have a higher-than
necessary average total cost (ATC) at each level
of output. (X-inefficiency)
55Profit Maximization Rule (2)
- MRP (Resource) MRC (Price of Resource)
- Minimizing cost is not sufficient for maximizing
profit. A firm can produce any level of output in
the least costly way by applying earlier equation
1. - But the profit maximizing position in equation 2
includes the cost-minimizing condition of 1 and
not the other way around
56Profit Maximization Rule (2)
- Note that in equation 2 that it is not sufficient
that MRPs of the two resources be proportionate
to their prices(MRC) - MRPs must also be equal to 1
- Example 15/5 9/3 ratios are equal but profits
are not maximized. Resources are underemployed.
MRP MRC - 5/5 3/3 1 where profits are maximized
57Profit Maximizing
- The profit maximizing position in equation 2
includes the cost-minimizing condition of
equation 1 - That is, if a firm is maximizing profit according
to equation 2, then it must be using the
least-cost combination of inputs to do so. - A firm operating at the least cost according to
equation 1 may not be operating at the output
level that maximizes its profits
58Cost Estimation
- Our discussion indicates that a detailed
knowledge of costs is important for managerial
decision making - Short term costs play an extremely important role
in operating decisions - For instance, when the MR MC, profits increase
by expanding production - Alternatively, if MR increases profits
59Cost Estimation
- Long-run costs, in turn, provide important
information for decisions on optimal plant size
and location. - For instance, if economies of scale are
important, one large plant is more likely optimal
with the product transported to regional markets.
- Alternatively, if scale economies are small,
smaller regional plants, which reduce
transportation costs, are more likely optimal - If managers are to incorporate costs in their
analysis in this manner, they must have accurate
estimates of how short-run and long-run costs are
related to various factors both within and beyond
the control of the firm.
60Cost Estimation
- Managers often use estimates of cost curves in
decision making. - A common statistical tool for estimating these
curves is regression analysis. - A regression estimates the relation between costs
and output - One common problem in statistical estimation is
the difficulty of obtaining good information on
the opportunity costs of resources. - Another problem with estimating cost curves
involves allocating fixed costs in a multiproduct
plant. - Cost accountants track the costs and estimate
product costs.
61The End
- Please dont forget to take online fill in the
blank quizzes - Please remember to review all of the concept
questions that you have received before taking
the test - Send me an email if you have any questions or
concerns