Title: Coinage Debasements in Burgundian Flanders, 1384 1482
1Coinage Debasements in Burgundian Flanders, 1384
- 1482
- Monetary or Fiscal Policies?
2(No Transcript)
3Definitions of Debasement
- Coinage debasement is the reduction of the
precious metal content silver or gold in not
just the coin itself but in the unit of the money
of account - MONEY OF ACCOUNT the penny, the shilling, and
the pound - With 12d (pence) to the shilling, and 20 s
(shillings) to the pound, so that 240d 1
4How Debasements are effected
- (1) By a reduction in the fineness i.e., in the
percentage of fine silver or gold in the coin, by
adding proportionately more copper - (2) By a reduction in the coins weight
- (3) By an increase in the nominal
money-of-account value of the coin - - reserved normally only for gold coins and high
value silver coins
5Debasements monetary policies?
- This paper seeks to answer two questions
- (1) were the coinage debasements in Burgundian
Flanders (1384-1482) undertaken principally as
monetary or fiscal policies and - (2)were they beneficial or harmful?
- In a recent monograph, Sargent and Velde contend
that monetary objectives governed almost all
medieval debasements, especially to remedy the
chronic shortages of petty coins.
6Late-medieval bullion famines'
- Despite overwhelming evidence that Burgundian
Flanders, along with most of north-west Europe in
the later 14th and 15th centuries, experienced
severe monetary scarcities and liquidity crises,
especially in the periods ca. 1390 - ca. 1415
and ca. 1440 - ca. 1470, both periods of severe
deflations, there is no compelling evidence that
the Burgundian rulers debased their coinages on
the basis of any such monetary policies.
7Coinage debasements as fiscal policies
- My thesis is the Burgundian rulers of Flanders,
in competition with neighboring princes,
undertook their debasements primarily as
aggressive fiscal policies, specifically to
finance warfare. - Debasements, however, were also undertaken as
defensive policies as noted below
8How Debasements increased a princes mint
revenues
- Their goal was to increase their seigniorage
revenues, the tax imposed on bullion brought to
their mints, by two means - (1) by increasing the tax rate itself, and
- (2) by enticing an increased influx of bullion
into their mints, - both by the debasement techniques themselves
- and by auxiliary bullionist policies to prevent
bullion exports and divert them to the mints
9Conditions for effective debasements
- (1) that merchants supplying bullion received
more coins of the same face value and thus with a
greater aggregate money-of-account value than
before (or than from other mints) - (2) that the public accepted such debased coins
at the same face value, by tale and - (3) that the merchants spent their increased
supply of coins quickly, before any ensuing
inflation eroded those gains.
10Debasements and Inflation
- This study further demonstrates that the
inflationary consequences of debasements were
always less than those predicted by the
mathematical formula - ?T 1/(1 - x) 1
- possibly because those debasements failed to
counteract the prevailing forces of monetary
contraction and deflation in the later 14th and
15th centuries (1390s to the 1480s).
11Defensive Reasons for Debasements
- to protect their mints from foreign competition,
i.e., from aggressive debasements - to protect their domestic money supplies from
influxes of debased and also counterfeit
imitations - i.e., to counteract Greshams Law that cheap
money drives out dear money
12Debasements and Warfare
- If aggressive coinage debasements were primarily
fiscal policies to finance warfare, in
late-medieval Europe, monetary contractions and
related deflations were often also the products
of warfare - From bullionist policies related to warfare with
almost universal bans on bullion exports - From disruptions of trade routes that impeded
coin and bullion flows - And from increased hoarding
13SOME BRIEF CONCLUSIONS ON FLEMISH DEBASEMENTS
- GENERALLY MORE HARMFUL THAN BENEFICIAL
- (1) Failed to provide any long term remedy for
the combined problems of chronic monetary
scarcities (bullion famines) and deflation - - indeed Burgundian rulers generally ended their
rounds of debasements with severely deflationary
coinage renforcements (restoring some of the lost
silver to the coinage)
14Conclusions 2
- (2) The combination of coinage debasements and
related bullionist measures generally served only
to worsen the monetary scarcities by impeding
bullion flows and coinage circulations - And also by encouraging hoarding by withdrawing
coins from circulation, which ipso facto impeded
coinage circulation - Note the monetary flows are often more important
the monetary stocks
15Conclusions 3
- (3) To the extent that debasements did lead to
some degree of inflation, that inflation reduced
real incomes of most members of the society
since wages, rents, and other fixed incomes
lagged behind consumer prices - - and that imposed an additional tax burden on
the entire society (known as the seigniorage tax)
16Conclusions 4
- (4) Debasement injured creditors, in a similar
fashion, by reducing the real values of both
their principal (capital invested) and their
investment returns whether interest, rent,
dividends, profits - - in that respect Burgundian coinage debasement
damaged Flanders international economic
relations epecially with the Italians and the
Hanseatic Germans
17Conclusions 5
- (5) Coinage debasements and renforcements as well
sometimes provoked social unrest, indeed even
industrial strikes - Industrial unrest amongst wage earners was
understandable if, following a debasement,
consumer prices rose more than did nominal wages - But paradoxically, strikes were more common after
coinage renforcements when the prince or town
government imposed wage cuts as part of the
monetary reforms
18Why were England and Spain Exceptions?
- England, 1351 1542
- defensive debasements only (Edward IV, 1464-65,
as a partial exception) before the Great
Debasement of Henry VIII and Somerset (1542-1552) - Export taxes on wool and cloth exports as
substitute? - Spain 1497 1686
- No debasements of gold and silver coinages
- But massive issues of copper vellon coins from
1599 - Quinto tax on silver imports but important only
from 1550s
19(No Transcript)
20(No Transcript)
21Flemish Coinage Terms
- (1) Values in money-of-account
- 1 penny or 1 d groot 24 mites 12d or 1s
parisis - (2) Fineness reckoned out of 12 deniers
argent-le-roy, with 24 grains per denier - 23/24 or 95.833 pure silver
- (3) Weight reckoned in terms of the taille or
number cut from the Marc de Troyes of 8 onces - 244.753 grams
22Traite of the Marc de Troyes
- Official money-of-account value of the coinage
struck from one marc argent le roy - Traite (taille value)/percent fineness
- taille (number of coins struck to the marc) the
face value of the coin/ divided by - The finenesss of the coin (in deniers and grains)
- E.g. 68.0 2/ (6/12) 136d 22s 8d groot
23 Debasement and Inflation a reduction in the
silver content of a coin increases the
corresponding traite value of silver by the
reciprocal ?T 1/(1 - x) 1 ? T change
in the traite x change (reduction) in the
silver content (as a decimal) Nov. 1428
debasement of silver double groot by 11.8
1/(1 - 0.118) - 1 (1/0.882) - 1 1.133 - 1
13.3. increase in the value of the traite.
24(No Transcript)
25 26(No Transcript)
27(No Transcript)
28(No Transcript)
29(No Transcript)
30(No Transcript)
31(No Transcript)
32(No Transcript)
33(No Transcript)