Chapter 6: Meanvariance portfolio theory - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 38
About This Presentation
Title:

Chapter 6: Meanvariance portfolio theory

Description:

This is because the risk-free asset, by definition, has zero variance (std. ... Asset allocation is based on these optimized portfolio weights. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:229
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 39
Provided by: CBA127
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Chapter 6: Meanvariance portfolio theory


1
Chapter 6 Mean-variance portfolio theory
  • Investment Science
  • D.G. Luenberger

2
Single-period random cash flows
  • Chapters 1-3 deal with deterministic cash flows.
    From now on, wed like to deal with random cash
    flows. The payoffs of an investment are usually
    uncertain, i.e., random.
  • In this chapter, we restrict attention to the
    case of a single investment period.
  • That is, we invest a known amount of monies at
    time 0, X0, and expect a payoff at time 1, X1.
  • This single period can be a day, a month, a year,
    or 10 years.
  • This chapter treats payoff (return) uncertainty
    within the framework of mean-variance analysis.

3
Realized portfolio return
  • Rate of return for asset i, ri (X1i X0i) /
    X0i.
  • For n assets, the portfolio weight of asset i wi
    X0i / (X01 X02 X0n).
  • Thus, w1 w2 wn 1.
  • The rate of return for the portfolio, r w1 r1
    w2 r2 wn rn.

4
Expected portfolio return with ex ante
probabilities, I
  • Investing usually needs to deal with uncertain
    outcomes.
  • That is, the unrealized return is usually random,
    and can take on any one of a finite number of
    specific values, say r1, r2, , rS.
  • This randomness can be described in probabilistic
    terms. That is, for each of these possible
    outcomes, they are associated with a probability,
    say p1, p2, , pS.
  • p1 p2 , pS 1.
  • For asset i, its expected return is E(ri) p1
    r1 p2 r2 pS rS.
  • The expected rate of return a portfolio of n
    assets, E(r) w1 E(r1) w2 E(r2) wn
    E(rn).

5
Expected portfolio return with ex ante
probabilities, II
6
Variability measures with ex ante probabilities, I
  • The expected return provides a useful summary of
    the probabilistic nature of possible returns. It
    is the weighted average of possible returns with
    probabilities being the weights.
  • One can think of the expected return being a
    measure of benefits holding other factors
    constant, the higher the expected return, the
    better.
  • Of course, one would like to have a cost measure
    so that one can perform a cost-benefit analysis.
  • The usual cost measure for portfolio analysis is
    variance (and standard deviation) holding other
    factors constant, the lower the variance (and
    std.), the better.
  • Variance (and std.) measures the degree of
    possible deviations from the expected return.

7
Variability measures with ex ante probabilities,
II
  • Var(r) p1 (E(r) r1)2 p2 (E(r) r2)2
    pS (E(r) rS)2.
  • Std(r) Var(r)1/2.
  • These formulas apply to both individual assets
    and portfolios.

8
Variability measures with ex ante probabilities,
III
9
2-asset diversification, I
  • Suppose that you own 100 worth of IBM shares.
    You remember someone told you that
    diversification is beneficial. You are thinking
    about selling 50 of your IBM shares and
    diversifying into one of the following two
    stocks H1 and H2.
  • H1 and H2 have the same expected rate of return
    and variance (std.).

10
2-asset diversification, II
11
2-asset diversification, III
  • H1 and H2 have the same expected return and
    variance (std.).
  • Why adding H2 is better than adding H1?
  • The answer is correlation coefficient.
  • The correlation coefficient between IBM and and
    H2 is lower than that between IBM and H1.
  • That is, with respect to IBMs return behavior,
    the return behavior of H2 is more unique than
    that of H1.
  • Return uniqueness is good!

12
Correlation coefficient
  • Correlation coefficient measures the mutual
    dependence of two random returns.
  • Correlation coefficient ranges from 1 (perfectly
    positively correlated) to -1 (perfectly
    negatively correlated).
  • Cov(IBM,H1) p1 (E(rIBM) rIBM, 1) (E(rH1)
    rH1, 1) p2 (E(rIBM) rIBM, 2) (E(rH1)
    rH1, 2) pS (E(rIBM) rIBM, S) (E(rH1)
    rH1, S).
  • ?IBM, H1 Cov(IBM,H1) / (Std(IBM) Std(H1) ).

13
2-asset diversification, IV
14
? 1
15
? -1
16
2-asset diversification, V (p. 153)
17
So, these are what we have so far
  • All portfolios (with nonnegative weights) made
    from 2 assets lie on or to the left of the line
    connecting the 2 assets.
  • The collection of the resulting portfolios is
    called the feasible set.
  • Convexity (to the left) given any 2 points in
    the feasible set, the straight line connecting
    them does not cross the left boundary of the
    feasible set.

18
2-asset formulas
  • It also turns out that there are nice formulas
    for calculating the expected return and standard
    deviation of a 2-asset portfolio. Let the
    portfolio weight of asset 1 be w. The portfolio
    weight of asset 2 is thus (1 w).
  • E(r) w E(r1) (1 w) E(r2).
  • Std(r) (w2 Var(r1) 2 w (1 w)
    cov(1,2) (1 w)2 Var(r2))1/2.

19
Now, let us work on ? 0, i.e., Cov0
20
What if one can short sell?
  • The previous calculations do not use negative
    weights that is, short sales are not considered.
  • This is usually the case in real-life
    institutional investing.
  • Many institutions are forbidden by law from short
    selling many others self-impose this constraint.
  • When short sales are allowed, the opportunity set
    expands. That is, more mean-variance
    combinations can be achieved.

21
Short sales allowed, ? 0
22
The general properties of combining 2 assets
  • In real life, the correlation coefficient between
    2 assets has an intermediate value you do not
    see 1 and -1.
  • When the correlation coefficient has an
    intermediate value, we can use the 2 assets to
    form an infinite combination of portfolios.
  • This combination looks like the curve just shown.
  • This curve passes through the 2 assets.
  • This curve has a bullet shape and has a left
    boundary point, i.e., convexity.

23
Ngt2 assets, I
  • When we have a large number of assets, what kind
    of feasible set can we expect?
  • It turns out that we still have convexity given
    any 2 assets (portfolios) in the feasible set,
    the straight line connecting them does not cross
    the left boundary of the feasible set.
  • When all combinations of any 2 assets
    (portfolios) have this property, the left
    boundary of the feasible set also has a bullet
    shape.

24
Ngt2 assets, II
  • The left boundary of a feasible set is called the
    minimum-variance set because for any value of
    expected return, the feasible point with the
    smallest variance (std.) is the corresponding
    left boundary point.
  • The point on the minimum-variance set that has
    the minimum variance is called the
    minimum-variance point (MVP). This point defines
    the upper and the lower portion of the
    minimum-variance set.
  • The upper portion of the minimum-variance set is
    called the efficient frontier (EF).

25
Ngt2 assets, III
  • Only the upper part of the mean-variance set,
    i.e., the efficient frontier, will be of interest
    to investors who are (1) risk averse holding
    other factors constant, the lower the variance
    (std), the better, and (2) nonsatiation holding
    other factors constant, the higher the expected
    return, the better.

26
N-asset diversification (p. 166)
27
Selecting an optimal portfolio from Ngt2 assets
  • Given the efficient frontier (EF), selecting an
    optimal portfolio for an investor who are allowed
    to invest in a combination of N risky assets is
    rather straightforward.
  • One way is to ask the investor about the
    comfortable level of standard deviation (risk
    tolerance), say 20. Then, corresponding to that
    level of std., we find the optimal portfolio on
    the EF, say the portfolio E shown in the previous
    figure.
  • CAL (capital allocation line) the set of
    feasible expected return and standard deviation
    pairs of all portfolios resulting from combining
    the risk-free asset and a risky portfolio.

28
What if one can invest in the risk-free asset?
  • So far, our discussions on N assets have focused
    only on risky assets.
  • If we add the risk-free asset to N risky assets,
    we can enhance the efficient frontier (EF) to the
    red line shown in the previous figure, i.e., the
    straight line that passes through the risk-free
    asset and the tangent point of the efficient
    frontier (EF).
  • Let us called this straight line enhanced
    efficient frontier (EEF).

29
Enhanced efficient frontier (EEF)
  • With the risk-free asset, EEF will be of interest
    to investors who are (1) risk averse,and (2)
    nonsatiation.
  • Why EEF pass through the tangent point? The
    reason is that this line has the highest slope
    that is, given one unit of std. (variance), the
    associated expected return is the highest
    consistent with the preferences in (1) and (2).
  • Why EEF is a straight line? This is because the
    risk-free asset, by definition, has zero variance
    (std.) and zero covariance with any risky asset.

30
The one-fund theorem, I
  • When the risk-free asset is available, any
    efficient portfolio (any point on the EEF) can be
    expressed as a combination of the tangent
    portfolio and the risk-free asset.
  • Implication in terms of choosing risky
    investments, there will be no need for anyone to
    purchase individual stocks separately or to
    purchase other risky portfolios the tangent
    portfolio is enough.

31
The one-fund theorem, II
  • Once an investor makes the above investment
    decision, i.e., finding the tangent portfolio,
    the remaining task will be a financing
    decision. That is, including the risk-free asset
    (either long or short) such that the resulting
    efficient portfolio meets the investors risk
    tolerance.
  • The financing decision is independent of the
    investment decision.
  • The one-fund theorem is a powerful result. This
    result is the launch point for Chapter 7 the
    CAPM.

32
EEF vs. EF
  • EEF is almost surely better off than EF, except
    for the tangent portfolio.
  • In other words, adding the risk-free asset into a
    risky portfolio is almost surely beneficial.
  • Why? hint correlation coefficient.

33
Portfolio theory in real life, I
  • Portfolio theory is probably the mostly used
    modern financial theory in practice.
  • The foundation of asset allocation in real life
    is built on portfolio theory.
  • Asset allocation is the portfolio optimization
    done at the asset class level. An asset class is
    a group of similar assets.
  • Virtually every fund sponsor in U.S. has an asset
    allocation plan and revises its (strategic)
    asset allocation annually.

34
Portfolio theory in real life, II
  • Most fund sponsors do not short sell.
  • They often use a quadratic program to generate
    the efficient frontier (or enhanced efficient
    frontier) and then choose an optimal portfolio on
    the efficient frontier (or enhanced efficient
    frontier).
  • See p. 160-162 for quadratic programming.
  • Many commercial computer packages, e.g., Matlab,
    have a built-in function for quadratic
    programming.
  • This calculation requires at least two sets of
    inputs (estimates) expected returns and
    covariance matrix of asset classes.
  • The outputs from the optimization include
    portfolio weights for asset classes. Asset
    allocation is based on these optimized portfolio
    weights.

35
Parameter estimation based on historical, ex
post, returns
  • The discussion about expected return, covariance,
    correlation coefficient, etc., so far has based
    on ex ante probabilities. But these
    probabilities and associated outcomes are not
    observable.
  • In real life, the estimation of expected returns
    and covariances is based on realized (historical)
    returns.

36
Formulas based observable, historical returns, I
  • If historical returns, r1, r2, , rT, are
    used, the expected return is simply the average
    return E(r) (r1 r2 rT) / T, where T is
    the number of observations.
  • The covariance between asset A and asset B is
    calculated as (1 / (T 1)) (E(rA) rA,1)
    (E(rB) rB,1) (E(rA) rA,2) (E(rB) rB,2)
    (E(rA) rA,T) (E(rB) rB,T).

37
Formulas based observable, historical returns, II
  • Note that the variance of an asset is simply the
    covariance between the asset and itself. Thus,
    the variance of A is (1 / (T 1)) (E(rA)
    rA,1) (E(rA) rA,1) (E(rA) rA,2) (E(rA)
    rA,2) (E(rA) rA,T) (E(rA) rA,T).

38
Calculations based on historical returns
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com