Title: Wage formation under low inflation
1Wage formation under low inflation
- EMU entails ambitious target for price stability,
which gives limited scope for nominal wage growth - What are the possible implications of low
inflation on unemployment and wage rigidity ?
2Effects of steady-state inflation on wage setting
- Downward nominal wage rigidity push up wages
- Staggered wage contracts
- trend inflation affects frequency and degree of
forward-lookingness of staggered wages - Near-rational wage setters
- Effort depends on reference wage
- Wage setters neglect low inflation, reducing wage
pressure - A floor to nominal wage growth
- incomplete contracts provide workers with scope
to inflict costs on firm even under existing
contract - multi-level wage setting
- Evidence on long run inflation unemployment
tradeoff - Will labour markets and wage setting institutions
adapt?
3Downward nominal wage rigidity DNWR
- Tobin (AER, 1972) - DNWR leads to higher
unemployment at low inflation - Co-ordination failure and concern for relative
wages (Keynes, 1936) - Fairness
- Survey evidence nominal wage cuts viewed as
unfair even in situations where the same real
wage reduction would be viewed as fair if caused
by price increase (Shafir et al, QJE, 1997,
Bewley, 1999) - Experimental evidence Fehr and Tyran (AER, 2001)
4Explanations of DNWR (cont.)
- Legal restrictions
- Nominal wages given in contracts that can only be
changed by mutual consent (MacLeod and Malcomson,
AER, 1993, Holden, EER, 1994). - Firms must force workers/unions to accept wage
cut by threats of layoffs, lock-out, closing down
plant, etc - Such contracts are closely related to employment
protection legislation may prevent holdup
inefficiency - U.S. law different workers viewed to accept wage
cut if they show up at work
5The standard model with no DNWR
Steady-state inflation has no effect on eq.
employment
6Effects of DNWR on aggregate employment
- Akerlof, Dickens and Perry (ADP) (1996)
- DNWR justified by fairness considerations
- Simulation model based on monopolistic
competition with wage and price setting, DNWR and
firm-specific shocks - Under low inflation, DNWR will push up wages in
firms experiencing negative shock - Holden (EER, 1994, Economica 2004)
- Invoke legal feature that nominal wages can only
be changed by mutual consent - Under positive inflation, workers must persuade
firm to accept wage rise gt workers have a
strategic disadvantage - under negative inflation, firms must persuade
workers to accept wage cut gt the firm has a
strategic disadvantage
7DNWR and low steady-state inflation
8The long run Phillips-curve
9Why does inflation put workers at a strategic
disadvantage?
- Assume wage outcome after strike or lock-out
100 - Assume costs of strike or lock-out 5
- Old contract wage 90 (inflation reduced real
value) - Threat of strike is credible, as this gives
higher payoff to the workers (100 5 95) than
the initial wage of 90 - But firm can offer 95 e, which gives higher
payoff to workers than a strike does gt workers
will accept - Bargaining outcome is 95 e, and no strike
takes place
10Strategic effect of inflation cont.
- Old contract wage 110
- negative inflation or negative shock implies that
wage must go down - Threat of lock-out is credible, as this gives
higher payoff to firm (100 5 105) than
initial wage does - But workers can offer 105 - e, which gives
higher payoff for firm than a lock-out does gt
firm will accept - Bargaining outcome is 105 e, and no lock-out
takes place - Bargaining outcome depends on initial wage gt
high inflation erodes value of old contract and
weakens workers.
11DNWR in organised and unorganised sector (Holden,
Economica, 2004)
- Collective agreements can only be changed by
mutual consent - Workers resistance to wage cuts (DNWR) depends
among other things on collective agreement
legislation - Individual labour contracts European law holds
that mutual consent is required to change
contract (US law firm may impose cut
unilaterally) - resistance to wage cuts (DNWR) depends on
strength of employment protection legislation
(EPL) - DNWR likely to be stronger in organised sector
12Simulation of long-run Phillips-curve (Holden,
Economica, 2004)
- Firm-specific shocks causes changes in relative
wages - Two percent annual growth in labour productivity
- Two percent increase in nominal wages in
organised sector unless firms threaten to use
lock-out (due to work-to-rule or go-slow threats
by workers) - Stronger DNWR in Europe due to higher bargaining
coverage and stricter EPL
13Long run Phillips-curve (Holden, Economica, 2004)
14Empirical studies documenting DNWR
- Fehr and Goette (2000) for Switzerland,
- Christofides/Leung (1999), Fortin/Dumont (2000)
for Canada, - Agell with co-authors (Lundborg, Bennmarker) for
Sweden, - Kimura and Ueda (1997) for Japan,
- Nickell and Quintini (2001) for the UK,
- Altonji and Devereux (1999), Lebow et al (2003)
for the US - Dessy (2002), Knoppik and Beissinger (2005) for
EU countries - Holden and Wulfsberg (2005) for OECD countries
- Increasing in strictness of EPL and in union
density, - decreasing in unemployment
15Norway individual nominal wage changes for
white-collar workers in 1996
16Effects of inflation on staggered wage contracts
- Ball, Mankiw, Romer (1988) high inflation leads
to more frequent wage adjustment and thus less
persistence - Ascari (2000) high inflation increases the
degree of forward-lookingness in wage setting,
and thus reduces persistence - Karanassou, Sala and Snower (2003)
- Time discounting implies that last part of
contract period is less important - Wages and prices will lag behind money growth.
Thus inflation reduces wage and price pressure,
increasing aggregate employment - Long run tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment
17Near-rational wage setters (ADP, 2000)
- Workers effort depends on wage relative to
reference level - Near-rational workers and firms will underweight
inflation in the updating of the reference wage - No underweighting of inflation for zero inflation
or for high inflation (underweighting too costly) - Underweighting of inflation, and thus lower wage
pressure, for low rates of inflation - Blinder Price stability is so low inflation
that it ceases to be a factor in influencing
decisions
18The long run Phillips-curve
19A floor to nominal wage growth
- Incomplete contracts and work-to-rule (Moene, EJ,
1990, Holden, Economica, 1989, OEP, 1997) - workers may inflict costs on firm even under
existing contract, e.g. by strictly adhering to
working rules - firm may reduce bonus payments etc
- if workers can inflict larger costs on firm than
vice versa, nominal wages will increase - the floor to nominal wage growth is lowered by
increasing bonus payments and other types of
flexible remuneration
20Multi-level wage setting and inflation - I
- Central wage setters want wage moderation but
DNWR prevails - Wage growth at local level (wage drift) due to
work-to-rule - Under high inflation, there is room for both
central wage increase and wage drift DNWR does
not bind - Multi-level wage setting implies wage moderation
- Under low inflation, wage drift leaves no room
for central wage increase DNWR binds - Multi-level wage setting implies strong wage
pressure - Rødseth (1985), Rødseth and Holden (1990),
Calmfors (1993), - Holden (1998) formalisation and evidence for
1961-1985/92 a floor to nominal wage growth at
central level 1.5 (Denmark) to 3.9 (Sweden)
21Multi-level wage setting and inflation version
II
- Central wage setters want wage moderation
- Solidaristic wage setting compression of
relative wages at the central level - Wage growth at local level (wage drift) necessary
to restore relative wages to market values - Multi-level wage setting requires high inflation
and devaluations - Without solidaristic wage setting, less need for
inflation - Hibbs and Locking (LE, 1996), Iversen (1999)
22Evidence of permanent tradeoff between inflation
and unemployment
- Standard view no such tradeoff exists
- Yet considerable evidence in favour of a
permanent tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment - Panel of EU-countries Karanassaou et al (2003a)
- The US Akerlof et al (1996), Karanassou (2003b),
Ahmed and Rogers (JME, 2000) - Sweden LundborgSacklèn (2001)
- Bullard and Keating (JME 1995) significant
long-run positive response of real output to
inflation in European countries with low
inflation in period 1960-90
23Will labour markets and wage setting institutions
adapt to low inflation?
- Under low inflation, nominal wage cuts will be
more frequent, and thus no longer be viewed
unfair (Mankiw 1996, Gordon,1996) - But fairness and legal restrictions are
complementary - legal restriction prevent wage cuts from being
frequent, preventing erosion of the fairness
argument - fairness argument prevents change of legal
restriction
24Will labour markets and wage setting institutions
adapt to low inflation? (cont)
- Firms are likely to change remuneration systems
so as to increase flexibility - reduces base wage to which DNWR applies
- improves firms bargaining position and reduces
floor to wage growth - Lebow et al (2000) US firms able to circumvent
some, but not all, DNWR by varying benefits
25Will labour markets and wage setting institutions
adapt to low inflation? (cont)
- Firms choice of contracts (Holden, 2001)
- Fixed wage contracts or temporary employment ?
- Fixed wage contracts provides incentives for
investment and training - Temporary employment facilitates efficient
mobility - Inflation erodes real value of fixed wage
contracts over time, so that badly matched
workers may quit - Low inflation makes fixed wage contracts more
rigid, but fewer firms will choose fixed wage
contracts
26Evidence of adaption to low inflation
- Switzerland early 1990s persistent DNWR in spite
of low inflation and high and increasing
unemployment (Fehr and Goette, 2001) - Sweden early 1990s persistent DNWR in spite of
high and increasing unemployment (Agell and
Lundborg, 2003).
27Concluding remarks
- Rigorous theoretical explanations for downward
nominal wage rigidity (DNWR) (fairness and legal
restrictions) - Strong empirical evidence that downward nominal
wage rigidity prevails in many countries - Not clear at what rate of inflation DNWR will
bite - productivity growth provides room for nominal
wage growth - changes in relative wages requires aggregate wage
growth - reason to expect a floor on nominal wage growth
- Labour markets will adapt to some extent
- Evidence that DNWR is persistent even under high
unemployment (Switzerland and Sweden)