Title: Political economy of reform
1Political economy of reform
2The importance of political constraints
- Political constraints appear to have played a
major role in the actual transition process in
all transition countries, especially in blocking
parts of the restructuring process. - Some examples
- Plans to cut subsidies to SOEs were canceled
- Fiscal subsidy cuts to firms transformed in in
hidden subsidies (bank credit and interenterprise
arrears) - Heavy worker resistance to closing inefficient
state enterprises.
3Introduction to Political economy of reform (PER)
- Political economy of transition belongs to a more
general field that tries to integrate political
science economics. - Also there is a general literature on political
economy of reform summarized by Dani Rodrik JEL
94) with the main conclusion not necessarily so
that authoritarianism allows for more sustained
economic reforms, it is rather the existence of a
deep crisis that forces government to really
reform).
4Introduction to Political economy of reform
(PER), cont.
- Political economy arguments are at the center of
discussion about speed and sequence of reform
(big bang vs. gradualism) - big bang ? window of opportunity
- gradualism ? build on reforms
- There is a trade off between a big bang strategy
where reforms are proposed simultaneously and
gradualism where they are realized in sequence
and the expected outcomes as well as the
realization of reforms will also depend on the
sequencing of reforms. - In what follows we always assume the existence of
complementarities between reforms. - Which type of approach can be seen as desirable
depends also on the type of uncertainty that
characterizes the process (individual uncertainty
vs. aggregate uncertainty).
5Theory of political economy of transition reform
- Normative PER ? decision making problems of
reformers subject to political constraints. - Based on Agenda-setting hypothesis ? government
has monopoly over design and sequencing of reform
packages (parliament votes on a take-it or
leave-it base or population in a referendum),
normative PER then develops general principles of
reform package. - Positive branch of PER ? analysis of clash of
interest groups.
6Ex-ante and ex-post political constraints
- Two types
- Ex-ante political constraints ? feasibility
constraints. Block decision-making and prevent
acceptance of reforms. - Ex-post political constraints ? backlash and
policy reversal - These two types of constraints must be dealt with
differently. - Ex-ante constraints ? compromises, credible
compensation for losers, decisions delayed. - Ex-post constraints ? attempts to create
irreversibility
7Political constraints without uncertainty
- (reforms with sure efficiency gains)
8How to relax political (ex-ante) constraints?
- a) compensating transfer to losers
- partial reform
- packaging reforms to get majority support
- creation of institutions making compensating
transfers credible in a sustained way - waiting for deterioration of the status quo (cf.
Dani Rodrik JEL paper)
9Compensating transfers to losers
- Compensating transfer is an obvious way to buy
off losers of reform. In the real world this is
not easily done. Difficulties - i) Redistributive transfer can have high
distortionary costs, especially in transition
countries, where fiscal administration is young,
large budget deficits are common and enforcing
tax collection is inefficient. - ?social safety net is an example, where we have
large distortions because of a lack of proper
targeting? - ii) Arguments of information assymmetry between
policy maker and economic agents who are
potential losers.
10Compensating transfers to losers cont.
- Example lay off of all workers of a SOE. ? How
should we compensate workers? Without asymmetric
information compensation structure should be
according to exit costs ? when there is
asymmetric information all workers have to be
paid the highest compensation (those who find
easily a job elsewhere will not reveal that gt
have to be paid highest compensation).
11Compensating transfers to losers cont.
- Likely solution Partial layoffs where workers
with highest exit costs keep their job. From an
efficiency point of view, this would be the least
desirable outcome as those with lowest outside
options remain in the firm. There are, however,
powerful arguments against this whole set-up, see
e.g. Gerard Pfanns work on downsizing, where
firm keeps the best workers in partial layoff. -
12Compensating transfers to losers cont.
- ???) Weak commitment power of decision makers
with regard to future compensating transfer. - ?Difference between CE and CIS former
established rapidly an UB system and other
elements of social safety net, unlikely that this
would be dismantled with a later government,
while latter did develop this system only
partially?
13Partial reform
- Obvious disadvantages
- Lower efficiency gains than in a complete
reform ?extreme case partial layoff of
essentially best people? - Losses of complementarities of bundled reforms
- In an extreme scenario, partial reform
generates little learning and might become pure
noise ? outcomes worse than status quo
absolutely and zero learning about results of
complete reform (for some time in 90s maybe
Ukraine comes closest to that!)
14Partial reform cont.
- Advantages
- i) Asymmetric information and heterogeneity of
exit costs and high efficiency costs of raising
funds to compensate losses. - If I only need to compensate low exit cost
worker then in connection with high costs of
raising funds, partial reform might be more
efficient than full reform. - ii) Building constituencies for further reforms.
- Strategy make status quo less attractive
- Divide rule by example 2/3 of workers have
to be laid off in a sector, a majority of workers
need to agree to this. By having small layoffs,
where laid-off are not fully compensated, one
might get a majority of workers to agree if it is
clear that compensation packages will be worse
down the line (then even those immediately laid
off might agree).
15Packaging reforms to gain majority support
- In some cases (in case without uncertainty), a
big bang reform packaging several reforms
together may obtain support by the majority while
individual reforms would be blocked, even if it
was optimal to implement reforms sequentially. - This will be the case, for example, when a reform
damaging a majority is proposed as part of a
package benefiting a majority. - Ex. Fiscal and trade reform (Martinelli and
Tommasi, 1997). 3 groups one always gains, one
always loses, one gains only from one (trade). - Optimal solution first fiscal reform ? trade
reform together excessive unemployment rather
than smooth adjustment. BUT taken separately,
no majority. - Putting the two reforms together, if the total
outcome for 3 is still positive, also group 3
supports the package, so there is a majority and
the package is approved.
16Creation of institutions making compensating
transfers credible in a sustained way
- Policy maker can create institutions with a
commitment to transfers - Extending voting, i.e. enfranchising the poor, is
such an institution, median income lt mean wage,
one-man-one-vote-system might guarantee that
redistribution is here to stay. - See also the introduction of massive income
support system in CE for non-employment
17Waiting for deterioration in the status quo
- Dani Rodriks paper in JEL gives some examples of
that when the status quo is deteriorated, then it
is relatively easy to push through a sustained
reform effort. So waiting for the deterioration
of the status quo might be a strategy (hard to
believe though that such a deterioration will not
strongly affect future reform path) - On the other hand, one reason Balcerowicz et al.
could push through a big bang program was that
the status quo was greatly deteriorated.
18Political constraints with uncertainty
19Ex-ante and ex-post political constraints, cont.
- Ex-ante and ex-post constraints will be the same
if no uncertainty and no reversal costs. - However,Fernandez and Rodrik (1991) show that,
ex-ante and ex-post constraints may differ
substantially in the presence of uncertainty. - Aggregate uncertainty uncertainty about
economy-wide effect of reform - Individual uncertainty uncertainty who will be
winners and losers - Aggregate uncertainty reversal costs ? harder
to implement reform. - For reforms to take place they have to satisfy
both the ex-ante (majority must be benefiting
from it) and the ex-post political constraints
(not risking to be reversed). - For this reason they speak of status quo bias
against reforms. - It is interesting to note that in this model
majorities shift over time. This aspect is very
important in determining the optimal sequencing
of reforms.
20Individual uncertainty
- When uncertainty is purely individual or
idiosyncratic, it is known in advance whether
there will be reform reversal or not if reforms
are adopted, given the (known) ex-ante
probability of gaining or losing from reform. - If there is reversal, no reform will be adopted
provided reversal costs are big enough. - In this framework, big bang is never dominated by
gradualism and in some cases strictly dominates
gradualism (thanks to bundling) - No interim reversal under gradualism and no
reversal after two reforms (payoff identical to
big bang if there is no discounting effect
otherwise big bang dominates because of
complementarities) - Interim reversal under gradualism and reversal
after two reforms (no reform tried) - Interim reversal under gradualism but no reversal
after two reforms interim status quo bias
(gradualism dominated by big bang if it has a
positive outcome).
21Aggregate uncertainty
- With aggregate uncertainty, it is not clear
anymore what will be the final outcome of reform.
In this case we have several possible outcomes
both for big bang and gradualism. - This is a reflection of the ignorance about the
transition process as well as the ignorance of
agents involved. It is also a reflection of the
possible existence of multiple equilibria. - If we assume the existence of complementarities,
the net present value of the partial reform is
always considered to be lower to the present
value of the full reform, as we miss the
benefits of complementarities (interim
suffering). - However, it is also true that observing the
outcome of the partial reform may give
information about the potential outcome of a full
reform and allow us to reverse the reform before
having implemented the full reform (at a lower
cost).
22Aggregate uncertainty, cont.
- Big bang can still be optimal when
- There is very high interim suffering
- There is no learning from partial reform
- The expected outcome of the big bang package is
positive and large. - Gradualism is more likely to be optimal when
- First reform is informative (probability of early
reversal lt1 and gt0) - Learning has to be fast enough
- Early reversal is less costly than full reversal.
23Aggregate uncertainty, cont.
- Gradualism in this context has the option of
learning and early reversal at lower cost that is
absent in big bang. - This can prove a significant advantage,
especially when costs associated to reversal in
big bang are high in the case of a bad aggregate
outcome. - It is interesting to note that the option value
of early reversal raises a wedge between the
ex-ante expected payoff of a gradualist program
and that of a big bang strategy. - In this case gradualism might be ex-ante
attractive even if big bang is not. - ? a gradualist strategy can be a useful way to
overcome the status quo bias of reform! - On the other side, the fact that big bang has
larger reversal costs makes reversal less likely
and this might be considered a positive
characteristics.
24Aggregate uncertainty, cont.
- This model can have interesting implications in
terms of timing of transition programs. If the
default payoff declines with time, and the
expected payoff of gradualism is larger than that
of Big Bang - A gradualist program will start earlier
- Big bang program will be observed on countries
where crisis perceptions are greater (after
missed opportunities of gradualism Hungary and
China vs. Poland and Russia).
25Aggregate uncertainty, cont.
- This model can have interesting implications in
terms of timing of transition programs. If the
default payoff declines with time, and the
expected payoff of gradualism is larger than that
of Big Bang - A gradualist program will start earlier
- Big bang program will be observed on countries
where crisis perceptions are greater (after
missed opportunities of gradualism Hungary and
China vs. Poland and Russia). - Going back to political constraints, we can
identify an ex-ante/ex-post trade off between big
bang and gradualism - ? looking at ex-post political constraints big
bang is preferable (reduces the probability of
reversals window of opportunity) - looking at ex-ante political constraints,
instead, gradualism has the advantage of reducing
resistance to the adoption of reforms (as it is
more easily reversible).
26Aggregate uncertainty, cont.
- The previous results were obtained in a
representative agent framework (all individuals
had identical perceptions about the probability
distributions associated with various aggregate
outcomes). - It is possible, however to imagine an alternative
framework, where agents have different subjective
beliefs about the likelihood of given aggregate
outcomes (reformers vs. conservatives). - In such a framework, gradualism might be the best
solution to allow reformers to start the reform
process even in presence of a majority of
conservatives with a preference for the status
quo. - More generally, the flexible approach to reforms
provided by gradualism may explain why
politicians often take a gradual approach to
large-scale reforms even in presence of
complementarity of reforms.
27Complementarity and momentum of reforms
- Complementarities can allow gradualism to build a
momentum for reforms that might not be built in
case reforms were separable. - It may be good to start with a reform having a
high likelihood of bringing benefits to a
majority, in order to build support for more
difficult reforms - Example of momentum under gradualism
- decollectivization in agriculture (China 1978).
From 1 in 1979 to 90 in 1984. Increased
agricultural output - support of rural constituencies for second phase
dual-track price system (market prices on excess
production - to achieve support for reforms in
cities) - New constituencies for further reform
restructuring of SOEs with layoffs and
privatization. - ? We go back to the issue which sequence is best?
28Optimal sequencing
- What is the optimal sequence of reforms when
gradualism dominates a big-bang strategy? - Three aspects are particularly important in
defining a correct sequencing of reforms - Unbundling of reform package in given sequences
should not lead to the loss of informativeness - Sequencing should make the reform process ex-ante
acceptable - Sequencing should aim at building constituencies
and momentum for further reform and satisfy
ex-post political constraints. - Note Objectives 2 and 3 may or may not be
conflicting with each other in determining an
optimal sequencing of reforms.
29Optimal sequencing, cont.
- Different expected outcome if we have two
reforms with positive expected outcomes it is
better to start with the one showing the highest
expected outcome (lower probability of
first-period reversal and increased probability
of both being achieved) - Differences in riskiness introducing the risky
reform first increases the option value of
reversibility (increased volatility), increasing
the expected outcome. - Differences in constituencies the sequencing of
reforms may affect reform reversibility after
implementation of a first reform, depending on
the expected costs and benefits of reform
continuation for the pivotal voter, by affecting
the identity of the pivotal voter at the
interim stage (the implementation of the first
reform may cause the pivotal voter to change).
30Optimal sequencing, cont.
- Exogenous vs. endogenous reelection or future
support and related literature the case for big
bang or gradualism or a particular reform
sequencing may be influenced by the nature of
the probability of reelection. - If the loss of power of the incumbent government
is caused by exogenous forces, the advantage of a
big bang approach is that the government can
constrain a potential successor government by
choosing today policies more difficult to
reverse. - On the other side, if policymakers face an
endogenous probability of reelection, they should
work to build constituencies by starting with
more popular reforms. In this case, political
backlash may be just the consequence of wrong
sequencing.
31Optimal sequencing, cont.
- Observed patterns in transition economies
(creation of support) - Development of small private sector
- Best firms privatized first (profit channel vs.
job creation channel) - Setting up new institutions (political reform and
other institutional changes) - Phase of restructuring and closing money-losing
enterprises is generally delayed.
32Speed of reform and endogenous investment
- The design of the reform package can affect the
final outcomes that can be attained. - For example, the speed of reform (big bang vs.
gradualism) can affect the response of foreign
investment to the reform process itself. - In his book, Roland derives two main results
- When the level of investment DOES NOT affect the
reversal probability, the investment response
under gradualism is ALWAYS higher before
uncertainty resolution, because of the lower
option value of waiting (you lose less) - When the level of investment DOES affect the
probability of reversal, then both gradualism and
big bang may generate higher investment response
before TOTAL uncertainty resolution. (Gradualism
better when probability of good states is lower).
Before ANY uncertainty resolution, however, in
this case more irreversibility is created and
investment is higher under big bang.
33Back to Normative PER
34Normative PER cont.
- Increasing ex-post constraints, lowering the
possibility of reversal - Normally low ex-ante constraints go hand in hand
with high ex-post constraints. Has we have seen,
however, good sequencing and well-designed
compensation schemes will make reversal more
unlikely. - Sometimes the strategy was used to take advantage
of a window of opportunity and make a reform
irreversible.
35Normative PER cont.
- Ex. Mass privatization in Russia, insider
privatization but here irreversibility (very hard
to give it back to the state) is very strong
existing state structures had been deliberately
weakened gt impossible to organize a reversal. - The downside of this irreversibility in the
Russian case asset stripping, weak performance,
? inequality and corruption, ? capture of the
state by oligarchs gt ? welfare. gt Greater
reversibility with a better privatization policy
might have meant a smaller fall in welfare.
36And, finally, positive PER
37Positive PER
- Explains differences in rent seeking and how
special interests may capture regulatory bodies.
In general we look at institutions affecting
costs and benefits of rent seeking. - Some questions
- Is it easier (or preferable) to pass reforms when
the executive branch of government has relative
autonomy, or is it better to have it closely
checked by the legislature? - Is a presidential regime preferable to a
parliamentary regime in terms of deciding
reforms? - Is it better to have coalition governments or
majoritarian governments to pass reforms? - Is a large number of veto players a good or a bad
thing (blocking good/bad reforms)? - Normally these things are exogenous, but in
transition they are more or less endogenous.
38Positive PER, cont.
- Hellman (1998) democratic transition countries
more fragmented party systems, coalition
governments, uninsulated executives ? most
progress with reforms. - Hypothesis better accountability /closeness of
politicians to voters / less capture by vested
interest groups. - Drawback mechanisms of checks and balances
creating accountability can also create
attrition/ paralysis of decision. - Reformers are usually seen as special
politicians having in mind the success of
efficiency-enhancing reforms. In this case,
insulating them from the pressure of interest
groups might be a good thing. - Drawback possible insulation also from voters
and opportunity for well organized interest
groups or for the opportunistically oriented
politician (to commit abuse).
39Positive PER, cont.
- Example
- One interesting paper makes point that e.g. in
Russia (and this can be extended to Ukraine)
oligarchs are interested in weak property rights
gt they then can easily convert social and state
assets into private ones for their own use. - ? Oligarchs try to capture state regulatory
bodies to prevent the establishment of strong
property rights (unexpected result- maybe a
priori one would have thought that the rich are
interested in secure property rights). - Differences in the strategy of rent seeking
between e.g. Poland and Russia is not fully
explained yet - ? Poland has a collective memory of capitalist
society but also within socialism powerful social
networks catholic church, solidarity trade
union, nothing of the kind in Russia and FSU. gt
one might speculate whether this lack of social
networks made it easier for insiders and
nomenklatura to capture the state.
40Positive PER, cont.
- ? Understanding properties of various political
institutions in generating efficiency-enhancing
reforms is an important orientation of future
research.
41Conclusions
42PER and performance
- ? Wide differences in economic performance can be
explained as consequences of different reforms
implemented under different political
constraints. - Other possible aspects
- Geopolitics and economic performance.
- 1.
- CE shift to Western Europe (shedding satellite
image) and linking in with EU gt after initial
output fall, fall into lawlessness, corruption,
and extreme state capture could be prevented. - It is not so in Russia, where we have the lost
empire syndrome.
43PER and performance cont.
- 2. PER and disruption of CMEA trade.
- Collapse of CMEA trade was not purely exogenous.
- EBRD and IMF tried a dual-track approach as far
as trade was concerned (2nd track additional
trade with western businesses). When CE countries
wanted to freely trade with West, SU insisted on
world prices for all its trade gt CMEA broke
down. - Conscious policy choice by e.g. CR and Poland to
see trade with West as a priority.