Title: Political Economy and the Choice of Fishery Management Strategies
1Political Economy and the Choice of Fishery
Management Strategies
- Robert T. Deacon
- University of California, Santa Barbara
- Resources for the Future
- World Bank Workshop on Fishery Reform
- Dhaka, Bangladesh
- July 2011
2Introduction
- Trends in world fisheries
- Widespread biological decline
- Prediction that all worlds capture fisheries
will be collapsed by 2048. - Increases in fraction of fisheries FAO has
declared over-exploited - Dismal economic performance
- Potential rent in capture fisheries 80B/year
- Actual rent is -30B/year (loss).
3Introduction
- Reasons for both tragedies Lack of property
rights - Access to fish stocks traditionally based on rule
of capture - Encourages wasteful race to fish.
- Eliminates any incentive to protect or steward
the resource. - Sharp contrast to owned biological resources
- Stocks of owned animals (cattle, sheep, etc.) not
in danger - Aquaculture is expanding exponentially
- Both types of owned resources are generating
rents - Other unowned natural resources (common pool oil,
forests, groundwater) suffering same fate as
wild fish stocks.
4Introduction
- Glimmer of hope Spread of rights-based
management - Principle Manage resource by assigning secure
rights to use it - Rights-based approaches
- Quantitative catch rights assigned to individuals
(ITQs). - Spatially delineated rights (TURFs).
- Management rights assigned to user groups (Coops
and harvester assns.)
5Introduction
- Evidence of impact
- Biological status
- Fisheries managed with catch shares show no
sign of collapse stock status becomes stable or
improves. - Case studies show that bycatch diminishes when
ITQs are established. - Economic status
- Individual transferable quotas (ITQs) generate
rents visible in quota prices. - Experience with management by coops indicates
generation of profits. - ITQ and coop management improves product quality
for consumers. - Rights-based management reduces hazards in
fishing and excess costs in processing.
6Introduction
- Applying rights-based strategies
- Choice can depend on ecology of species
- TURFs vs. ITQs for sedentary vs. mobile species.
- Strategies can be combined to achieve full
potential - Individual transferable quotas (ITQs) combined
with marine protected area to avoid habitat
damage or protect critical nursery habitat. - Coops may use internal ITQs to allocate effort
among members. - TURFs may form coops to organize effort, monitor
and enforce, etc. - Choice depends critically on host country
political institutions - Focus of this presentation.
7General objective
- Identify politically viable approaches to
management reform - Find pathways to reform that are promising in
specific political / institutional contexts. - Draw on examples of successful approaches in
fisheries, e.g., coops, harvester assns., TURFs,
ITQs, - No presumption that a single approach is best in
all contexts. - Different instruments can be combined to achieve
objectives.
8Steps toward objective
- Link fishery reform strategies to political /
governance institutions - Identify dimensions of the fishery management
problem. - Describe current theories of political
institutions and governance. - Find a strategy for each management dimension
that is well suited to a given political context. - Emphasize fishery cooperatives
9- Essential features of a fishery cooperative /
harvester association - From REEP
10Ingredients
- Dimensions of management policy (and property
rights) - Management tasks
- Delineate exclusive rights to harvest
- Limit catch
- Monitor and enforce resource use rights sanction
violators - Specify who decides how, where, when harvesting
occurs. - Different tasks may be assigned to different
parties - Government agency vs. coop, vs individual
fishers, - Principle Assign tasks to align incentives for
rent capture.
11Ingredients
- Governance theories focused on distribution of
political power - If political power is broadly distributed,
governments coercive power likely to be used to
provide public goods - Economies of scale in providing public goods to
large populations - Public goods include courts, police general rule
of law - If political power is concentrated, governments
coercive power likely to be used to enrich
political elites - Transfers include transfer of resources to
political friends - Corruption likely when rule of law is absent.
References Acemoglu and Johnson, JPE, 2001
Bueno de Mesquita, et al, Cambridge Univ. Press,
2003 LaPorta, et al, JLEO, 1998 Lizzeri and
Persico, AER, 2001 Milesi-Ferretti, et al, QJE,
2002 Putnam, Princeton Univ. Press, 1993.
12Assigning tasks
- Delineating exclusive access
- If one relies on governments coercive power for
exclusion - Outcome depends on governments orientation
broad-based rule of law vs. rent transfer to
elites - Essential role for government authorize
legitimize exclusive rights - Rely on users for mechanics of exclusion.
- Evidence from case studies
- User-based exclusion generally ineffective in
developing and developed countries - User-implemented catch limits rare in developing
countries - User-implemented catch limits fairly prominent
and often effective in developed countries. - May be due to difference in security of claims to
future rents.
13Assigning tasks
- Monitoring, enforcing, sanctioning
- State vs. user enforcement results in different
incentives - User enforcement collective incentive, but face
free-rider problem - Govt. enforcement enforcers may have little
stake in effective enforcement, may use authority
for rent-seeking - Evidence from case studies of fisheries, forests,
irrigation - User-based enforcement generally more effective,
particularly when government legitimizes - Mixed evidence on users ability to overcome
free-riding - User-adopted sanctions more effective than govt.
(irrigation) - Limitation Studies do not control for political
systems.
14Assigning tasks
- Allocating catch, coordinating effort to avoid
conflicts - Consistent evidence that user-groups can solve
these problems - Case studies from numerous developing and
developed country fisheries - Experimental evidence subjects can coordinate
when allowed to communicate even without
commitment mechanism. - Systems examined amount to coops or harvester
associations.
15Examples
- User-based management in a weak rule of law
state Mexicos lobster cooperatives - Harvester coops in Baja California, formed in
1930s. - Authoritarian national government apparently
uninterested in fishery. - State authority legitimizes coops right of
exclusion. - Performance of fishery and cooperatives
- Stocks and catches stable since 1980s
- Coops manage effort limits enforce compliance
with regulations - Fishery certified as sustainable by MSC in
2004. - Possible key to success Benign neglect by
central government.
16Examples
- Namibias approach Enabling rent capture by
broad stakeholder groups - Namibian independence in 1990
- Pre-independence fishing largely uncontrolled,
exploited by foreigners. - New government strongly democratic.
- Independent Namibias fishery policy
- Declare and defend 200 mile limit
- Design management to broadly distribute rents
among population - Some short run inefficiency, but prevents capture
by political elites. - Fisheries performing well biologically and
economically.
17Examples
- Modifying top-down policy is strong rule of law
state to enable innovation by users Chignik
(U.S.) coop - Prior management regime
- Limited entry, TAC limit, season closure
- Race to fish, inefficient use of effort, poor
economic performance. - Chignik harvesters coop formed in 2002
- Membership voluntary profits shared equally
- State assigned share of TAC, depending on
membership - Coop eliminated race to fish, rationalized
effort, coordinated fishing, generated rents. - Violated regulations declared illegal after 3
years.
18Examples
- Overcoming regulatory rigidity by empowering
users in strong rule of law countries. - Yaquina Bay (U.S.) herring roe fishery
- Originally limited entry with TAC allowed permit
holders to divide TAC among themselves. - Ended race to fish, encouraged user-support
research on stocks. - Challenger Scallop Enhancement Co. (New Zealand)
- 38 catch quota owners formed a company to manage
fishery collectively - CSEC now sets catch limits, coordinates harvest
areas, reseeds depleted areas, invests in
research. - Paua management by user groups (New Zealand)
- Quota owners formed association to coordinate
actions. - Share information on stock locations, impose size
limits, reseed depleted areas, reduce incidental
mortality.
19Conclusions
- What can we recommend?
- Recognize governments motivation when choosing
policy - Motives depend on underlying political
institutions broad-based vs. narrowly-focused
political power. - Government is not a generic entity consider
different levels of government. - Assign greater management responsibility to users
when governments are unreliable. - Assigning rents to users encourages stewardship
and rent generation - Evidence of stewardship by ITQ quota owners and
coops. - Research on performance should account for
institutional differences. - Important for assessing performance of user-based
vs. government monitoring, enforcement,
sanctioning. - Case study and experimental work should be
designed to include these factors.
20Examples
- Contracting to achieve environmental objectives
in weak rule of law states Debt-for-nature swaps - Goal overcome lax or nonexistent enforcement of
property rights. - Conservation NGOs fund enforcement of laws on
paper parks in Latin America and elsewhere. - Assets are nominally owned by host government.
- Swaps are structured to
- Avoid including host government as party (due to
sovereignty) - Make it costly for host government to reneg
- Minimize possibility host government can seize
conservation assets.