Title: Reflections on Water Pricing and Tariff Design
1Reflections on Water Pricing and Tariff Design
- Prof. Dale Whittington
- University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill
- Prof. John Boland
- The Johns Hopkins University
- April 3, 2001
2Outline of Presentation
- Objectives of water pricing and tariff design
- Alternative Tariff Structures - Definitions
- Observations on Increasing Block Tariffs (IBTs)
3Water Tariff
- The set of prices, charges and taxes used to
generate revenue and - The rules and regulations which govern their use
4Average Residential Water Tariffs - Selected
Asian Cities (US / m3 ,1997)
Price US/m3
Cities
0.70
Jakarta
Singapore, Hong Kong
0.50
Bangkok, Kuala Lumpur, Taipei
Manila, Seoul
0.20
Ho Chi Minh, Colombo, Lahore
Calcutta, Delhi, Beijing, Mumbai, Shanghai,
Karachi, Dhaka
0.00
5Functions of the Tariff
- Determines level and pattern of revenue
- Contributes to ability to attract capital
- Creates incentives affecting the production and
use of services - Influences the value of the services received and
the total cost of production - Allocates cost among customers, groups of
customers, and over time
6Purposes of the Tariff
- Economic Efficiency
- Fairness (a perception)
- Equity (a testable hypothesis)
- Revenue sufficiency
- Net revenue stability
- Simplicity and understandability
- Resource conservation
7Additional Considerations in Tariff Design
- Public acceptability
- Political acceptability
- Ease of implementation
- Enhancement of credit rating
8Criteria versus Average Tariff
who can afford a private water connection
Water consumption by hhs with private water
connection
Economic benefits received by hhs with private
water connection
Low Medium
High Very High
Low Medium
High Very High
Low Medium
High Very High
US1.00/m3
US0.50/m3
US0.05/m3
0.00
9Criteria versus Average Tariff
Revenues received by water utility
Costs to water utility to deliver water supply
Economic costs paid by others (e.g., subsidies
needed by water utility)
Medium High
Low Zero
Low Medium
High Very High
Low (None?) Low (None?)
High Very High
US1.00/m3
US0.50/m3
US0.05/m3
0.00
10Hierarchy of Objectives
- Most restrictive
- Least restrictive
- Economic Efficiency
- Equity
- Simplicity, transparency
- Fairness
- Resource conservation
- Net revenue stability
- Revenue sufficiency
11Service Quality vs. Cost Recovery
Asian Water Utilities Handbook,1997 Good Service Poor Service
Costs Recovered Kuala Lumpur Seoul Singapore Taipei Colombo Hanoi Jakarta Lahore
Costs Not Recovered Beijing Hong Kong Shanghai Kathmandu Dhaka Manila
12Some Basic Tariff Options
- Single part tariff, consists of either
- Fixed charge (not based on measured water use)
- Volumetric charge (based on measured water use)
- Two part tariff, includes both fixed and
volumetric charges
13Volumetric Charges
- Uniform price - all units of water billed at same
price - Block-type structures - two or more prices, each
applies to use within a defined segment (block)
of monthly use - Decreasing block - block price falls as use rises
- Increasing block (IBT) - block price rises as use
rises Note first block price usually set below
cost
14Tariff Design - Uniform Price
- Periodic fixed (service) charge, e.g.,
US/month/connection - Single commodity price, e.g., /m3
- Example (in US)
- 5.00/month for residential connection, plus
- 1.00/m3 for all water use
15Tariff Design - Decreasing Block
- Periodic fixed (service) charge
- Two or more commodity prices (/m3), decreasing
with use - 5.00/month for residential connection, plus
- 1.50/m3 for all water used up to 15 m3/month
- 1.00/m3 for all water used in excess of 15
m3/month, up to 30 m3/month - 0.75/m3 for all water used in excess of 30
m3/month
16Tariff Design - Increasing Block (IBT)
- Periodic fixed (service) charge
- Two or more commodity prices (/m3), increasing
with use - 5.00/month for residential connection, plus
- 0.75/m3 for all water used up to 15 m3/month
- 1.00/m3 for all water used in excess of of 15
m3/month, up to 30 m3/month - 1.50/m3 for all water used in excess of 30
m3/month
17Tariff Design - Variants
- Increasing rate designs
- Combination block designs
- Free service allowances (form of increasing
block) - Seasonal water tariffs
- Seasonal sewer tariffs
- Lifeline rates
18U.S. Water/Sewer Agencies
- 50,000 water utilities
- 30,000 wastewater utilities
- Urban places with 100,000 population
- 300 water utilities
- 200 wastewater utilities
19U.S. Government-Owned Water Utilities
- 80 percent of total
- 85-90 percent of large systems
- Very few subject to tariff regulation by State
- Only 12 of 50 states with laws restricting
pricing practices
20U.S. Investor-Owned Water Utilities
- 10-15 percent of large systems
- Subject to tariff regulation by State agency,
based on rate-of-return
21U.S. Water Tariffs
22Commonly Overlooked Facts I
- Water and sewer services are bundled commodities
- Users respond to the sum of water and sewer
tariffs - Developing tariffs separately according to
different criteria is illogical
23Commonly Overlooked Facts II
- Prices determine water use, not tariff design
- Each user responds to his/her last block price
regardless of what other prices may be, or what
other users may do. - Block type rates permit price discrimination,
individual users respond to the price in specific
block(s)
24Increasing Block Tariffs (IBTs)
- Still actively promoted in developing countries
- Water pricing is an important instrument for
stimulating efficient use of water. A basic
amount could be used at a relatively low rate,
while water consumption beyond that amount could
be charged with progressively higher rates.
(Urban Water Resources Management, UN, 1993, p
19). - Widely used in OECD countries
25IBT Example La Paz, Bolivia
26Examples of IBTs
27What is Rationale for IBTs?
- Claimed to transfer income from rich to poor
- Claimed to transfer income from firms to poor HHs
- Very high prices in top blocks claimed to
discourage extravagant and wasteful use - IBTs are said to implement marginal cost pricing
principles - IBTs are said to reflect assumed rising marginal
cost curves
28IBT Rationale Revisited I
- Rich subsidize the poor
- Average price rises with HH use. Therefore, to
the extent that water use is correlated with
income, subsidy occurs. - Maximum possible subsidy is small (typically US1
to US3 per month) - Subsidy is regressive within the lower blocks
29IBT Rationale Revisited II
- Firms subsidize poor households
- IBTS produce such a subsidy
- Subsidy is regressive within the lower blocks
- If subsidy were desirable, it could be achieved
more easily by sectorally differentiated prices - Subsidy may not be desirable large users may
exit system, increasing average costs for
residential users
30IBT Rationale Revisited III
- IBTs discourage extravagant or wasteful use
- No clear what extravagant means
- If wasteful means uses that do not justify the
resource cost of the water, then - Setting price equal to marginal cost means that
every customer pays to replace every unit of
water taken, regardless of the type of use - No further incentive is necessary or desirable
31IBT Rationale Revisited IV
- IBTs are consistent with marginal cost pricing
- There is only one marginal cost for a given class
of customers at a given time - IBTs result in different customers within the
class paying different prices at any given time,
based on their total monthly use - At most one of these prices can equal marginal
cost all others represent a divergence from
marginal cost pricing principles
32IBT Rationale Revisited V
- IBTs track rising marginal costs
- Marginal cost is not necessarily rising, even in
developing countries - If marginal cost is rising, it rises as a
function of aggregate water use it does not
change perceptibly with changes in water use by a
single HH - Prices are meant to reflect the costs imposed by
additional water use by the HH. These are the
same for all HHs in a given class at any given
time. - Marginal cost may rise over time then prices
should also rise over time, but for all uses
33Limitations of IBTs in Practice
- Difficulty in limiting size of the first block
- Difficult to provide proper economic incentives
to most customers - Difficult to meet revenue target without large
departures from marginal cost - Lack of transparency and difficulty of
administration - In the case of shared connections, or where
connected HHs resell water to vendors, IBTs
increase cost to the very poor
34An Alternative to Increasing Block Tariffs
- Use lump-sum transfers for income redistribution
and other fairness objectives - This allows the choice of a uniform price design,
preferable according to all other criteria - Lump-sum transfers can lead to negative fixed
charges for some users
35A Practical Alternative to IBTs Uniform Price
with Rebate (UPR)
36Household Water Bill UPR vs. IBT
Households Monthly Water Use (m3) Uniform Price with Rebate Increasing Block Tariff
5 US2.50 US2.50
10 US3.31 US5.00
15 US8.31 US7.50
20 US13.31 US12.50
25 US18.31 US17.50
37Two-Part Tariff Evaluation
- Both tariffs produce the same revenue
- Two-part tariff provides improved incentives
- More HHs face full marginal cost with a UPR than
with a IBT. Only the smallest, most price
inelastic HHs face a zero incremental price - Two-part tariff more effective in transferring
income - Per-HH transfer is larger
- Transfer is not regressive
38Two-Part Tariff Evaluation
- Two-part tariff is simple and transparent
- Two-part tariff is more equitable
- Advantages of two-part tariff even greater when
compared to a multi-step IBT
39Conclusions
- Usual rationales for employing IBTs are either
incomplete or incorrect - There are significant practical difficulties with
the application of IBTs in developing countries - If the purpose of an IBT is to redistribute
revenue, alternative tariff designs can do so
more effectively - IBTs, on the other hand, introduce inefficiency,
inequity, complexity, lack of transparency,
revenue instability, and forecasting difficulties
40Conclusions (cont.)
- Properly designed tariffs are powerful management
tools - Comparisons of alternative designs can be complex
- No single design fits all circumstances
- Increasing block designs, though widely used,
have many disadvantages - Better tariff design is possible