Title: EE10: Demand and welfare theory
1EE10 Demand and welfare theory
- What is so special about environmental goods?
- Theory of consumer demand for market goods
- Welfare effects of a price change Equivalent
variation versus compensating variation - Consumer demand for environmental goods
- Welfare effects of a quantity change Equivalent
surplus versus compensating surplus - Theory and practise
2Last two weeks
- International externalities
- Optimisation analysis
- Game-theory analysis
- Acid rain
- Depletion of the ozone layer
- Climate change
- Pollution control CCS
3Economic Value
- Neo-classical revolution Value is relative,
value measures demand versus supply, value is
based on consumption and production - Basis of valuation Peoples preferences, what
people want - Values depend on context
- Supply, demand
- Uncertainty Something that is uncertain is worth
less, an uncertain loss is worth more - Uniqueness Something that is unique is worth more
4What to value?
- Individuals can derive value from environmental
goods from more sources than direct consumption - Types of environmental services
- source of materials input fossil fuel, wood
products, fish, water etc. - life-support services liveable climatic regime,
breathable atmosphere - amenity services recreation, wildlife
observation, scenic view, passive use values - sink for the assimilation of wastes
5Why valuation?
- We must make choices about how to manage the
human impact on natural systems - Greater use of a particular environmental service
or greater protection of a specific natural
system results in less of something else
(trade-off) - To make the most of scarce resources we must
compare what is gained from an activity with what
is sacrificed by undertaking that activity - Why? To assess the net impact of changes
6What is so special about environmental goods and
services?
- In economics the criterion for assessing the net
impacts (benefits and costs ) is the
well-being of the members of society - Well-being is defined as the individuals
preferences for goods - Preferences are typically represented through
demand functions - Changes in well-being can be inferred by changes
in prices or quantity - Problem with environmental goods no markets
exist - Individuals have preferences nevertheless
- Changes in well-being are derived by individuals
- max. willingness to pay for gains or (WTP)
- min. willingness to accept compensation for
losses (WTA) - Prices and marginal WTP or WTA are equivalent
7Consumer demand theory Market goods
- Consider a consumer who has a utility function
- This consumer maximises the utility of a bundle
of goods x, with prices p, and income M - This solves to the ordinary or Marshallian demand
function - Substituting the expression for xi gives the
indirect utility function - this gives you the highest level of utility
attainable, given prices p and income Y
8Consumer demand theory -2
- Roys identity relates x and v
- That is, the derivative of indirect utility with
respect to the ith price yields the ith demand
function, after normalising by the marginal
utility of income
9Constructing an ordinary demand function
x2
p1
I3
I2
I1
x1(p1,p2,M), demand for x1
C
Budget constraint
C
A
A
B
B
x1
x1
10Consumer demand theory -3
- An alternative to generate a demand curve is to
keep utility constant instead of income - Here the consumer is assumed to minimize total
expenditure to achieve a given level of utility
at price level P - This solves to the compensated or Hicksian demand
function - This gives the quantity demanded as a function of
price and utility - Income is of no consequence as prices change,
expenditures are adjusted to maintain constant
utility.
11Consumer demand theory -4
- Demand for the ith commodity is the derivative of
the expenditure function to the price of i
12Constructing a compensated demand function
p1
x2
I1
hx1(p1,p2,U1), demand for x1
C
C
A
A
B
B
Budget constraint
x1
x1
13Ordinary and compensated demand
- We derived ordinary and compensated demand
functions - Ordinary demand functions bundle income and price
effects together - Compensated demand function do not have this
problem, but look at price effects alone - To evaluate the effect of a governmental policy
that changes relative prices we want to examine
the price effect only - Typically, economists estimate ordinary demand
functions, as utility cannot be observed
14Income and price effects
x2
e/p21
A
Price effect
e/p22
B
Income effect
C
I1
I0
D
M
x1
15Surplus from ordinary and compensated demand
p1
If AB is an ordinary demand function like
x1(p1,p2,M) Consumer Surplus ABCD-BCDEABE
A
If AB is a compensated demand function like
hx1(p1,p2,U1) the area under the curve correspond
to changes in constant utility expenditures
E
B
p1
C
D
x1
x1
16Ordinary and compensated demand - 3
p1
hx1(p1,p2,U0)
Compensated demand
hx1(p1,p2,U1)
A
B
x1(p1,p2,M)
Ordinary demand
x1
17Ordinary and compensated demand - 4
- Properties of both demand functions are related
- We observe ordinary demand functions, but we are
interested in compensated demand functions the
latter can be derived from the former if agents
are rational, and even then it involves many
steps including integration
18Welfare effects of price changes
- Consider price fall P ? P
- Willingness to pay (WTP) to secure price fall is
known as compensating variation (CV) - Willingness to accept compensation (WTAC) to
forego price fall is known as equivalent
variation - There are gains and loss, so four measures (EV)
- Price decreases
- WTP to secure a gain (CV)
- WTAC to forego a gain (EV)
- Price increases
- WTP to prevent a loss (EV)
- WTAC to tolerate a loss (CV)
19Welfare measures
- Compensating variation is the quantity of income
that compensates consumers for a price change,
that is, returns them to their original welfare - Equivalent variation is an income change that
yields the same utility change as the price
change - Both terms can be defined using the expenditure
function
20Ordinary and compensated demand Welfare effects
p1
Compensated variation ABEG Consumer Surplus
AEFB Equivilent variation ADFB gt If p decreases
CVltDCSltEV
hx1(p1,p2,U0)
Compensated demand
hx1(p1,p2,U1)
E
A
D
p01
F
x1(p1,p2,M)
p11
B
G
Ordinary demand
x1
x01
x11
21Consumer demand theory Environmental goods
- Often demand for environmental commodities is
only indirectly observed - People change their behaviour in response to
changes in the environment, but do not purchase
environmental quality directly - Well repeat the analysis above, but now assume
that only n-1 goods are directly traded the nth
good (named q) is the environmental commodity of
interest
22Restricted demand
- The environmental good q affects individuals
utility - This consumer maximises the utility of a bundle
of goods X, with prices P, and income M - This leads to restricted ordinary demand
functions - and a restricted indirect utility
- Again, Roys identity relates x and v
23Restricted demand - 2
- The dual of the problem Minimising expenditure
- This leads to the expenditure function function
- The Hicks-compensated demand function for changes
in prices is - The Hicks-compensated inverse demand (marginal
WTP) for changes in q is - Rearranging the equation yields the compensating
demand for q
24Restricted demand - 3
- But...
- we can determine how expenditures change with q
for some price of good x and implicitly defining
a demand function for q only if we assume weak
complementarity - That is, if the demand for good x drops to zero,
then demand for good q goes to zero as well and
marginal changes in q no longer affect
expenditure - Example if swimming is too expensive, water
quality is irrelevant
25Restricted compensated demand
p1
A
Choke price
The income equivalent or marginal WTP for a
change in q ABC
B
C
p1
hx1(p1,q0,U1), initial demand for x1
hx1(p1,q0 Dq ,U1), demand for x1 after increase
in q
D
x1
26Welfare effects of quantity changes
- Measures of surplus instead of variation when
consumers are not free to vary the quantity of q - In case of quantity changes, compensating and
equivalent surplus are defined as - U0 results from (P,q0,M)
27Measures of changes in welfare for an
environmental good
Expenditure on private good x, M
D
ES/px
If q0 increases to q1, income has to be reduced
by CS/p to keep the same utility
B
M
Mpxx
A
U2
CS/px
U1
C
U0
q0
q1
Quantity/quality of environmental good q
28WTP and WTAC
- If the good is relatively unimportant ES and CS
are roughly the same - If environmental goods are relatively scarcer
than market commodities, one may expect the
compensating variation/surplus (WTP) to be
smaller than the equivalent variation/surplus
(WTAC) for improvements - Differences between WTP and WTAC are mainly due
to income effects - People view gains and losses differently
- WTP is limited to an individuals income, WTAC is
unbounded - Confirmed by empirical studies, but not
uncontested - Implies that surveys, policies need to be
carefully designed - Income effects are small only if the good is of
little value relative to your overall wealth
29Theory and practice
- Horowitz and McConnell collect 208 observations
of WTP and WTAC from 45 studies - For all studies, the average ratio WTAC/WTP is
7.2 (0.9) - However, for public or non-market goods, the
ratio is 10.4 (2.5) - For ordinary goods, it is 2.9 (0.3)
- For money, it is 2.1 (0.2)