Title: The HeckscherOhlinSamuelson Model
1The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson Model
- Factor Proportions Theory
2Problems with the Generic Neoclassical Model
- What is the source of a countrys comparative
advantage? Generic neoclassical theory doesnt
really say - Factors other than labor (especially capital) are
not explicitly included
3H-O-S In General
- Heckscher, and his student Ohlin, worked in the
early part of the 20th century - Samuelson refined their work after WWII
- Closer attention is paid in this model to each
countrys resource endowment
4H-O-S Assumptions
- 2 countries
- 2 commodities
- 2 factors (labor and capital)
- Perfect competition exists in all markets
- Each countrys endowment of factors is fixed
- Factors are mobile internally, but immobile
internationally
5H-O-S Assumptions (contd)
- Each producer has a wide range of options as to
how to produce X or Y - if K is cheap relative to labor, a relatively
capital-intensive method will be adopted - if K is expensive relative to labor, a relatively
labor-intensive method will be adopted - Each country has the same CRTS technology
6H-O-S Assumptions (contd)
- Tastes and preferences are the same for both
countries
7Concepts and Terminology
- The capital-labor ratio for good X is simply
KX/LX, and for Y is KY/LY - If KX/LX gt KY/LY, production of good X is capital
intensive relative to production of good Y - For example, the amount of capital per worker in
the U.S. petroleum and coal industry is 468,000 - The similar figure for apparel products is 8,274
- Therefore, petroleum and coal is produced in a
relatively capital-intensive manner
8Concepts and Terminology
- Also, production of Y must be relatively labor
intensive (If KX/LX gt KY/LY, then LY/KY gt LX/KX) - That is, apparel products are produced in a
labor-intensive manner (as compared to petroleum
and coal)
9Relative Factor Intensities, Selected U.S.
Industries (1992)
10Concepts and Terminology
- Country A is said to be capital abundant relative
to Country B if (K/L)A gt (K/L)B - For example, if the U.S. has a capital stock of
4.3 trillion and a labor force of 121 million,
then K/L is about 36,000. - K/L for India works out to 607 billion/304
million 2,000. - Therefore, the U.S. is capital abundant relative
to India India is relatively labor abundant.
11Relative Factor Endowments, Selected Countries
(1992)
12Concepts and Terminology
- To summarize
- goods are produced relatively K or L intensively
- countries are relatively K or L abundant
13Concepts and Terminology
- The factor price of labor (the wage) is denoted w
- The factor price of capital is denoted r
- If labor is relatively expensive, w/r will be a
relatively big number - If labor is relatively cheap, w/r will be a
relatively small number
14More on Factor Prices
- What makes labor relatively expensive?
- If it is relatively scarce
- What makes labor relatively cheap?
- If it is relatively abundant
- So If (K/L)A is a relatively big number (that
is, capital is relatively abundant), w/r will be
a relatively big number, reflecting the relative
scarcity of L and abundance of K
15A Review of Trade in the Neoclassical Model
- Suppose the U.S. is capital abundant relative to
Mexico - This, of course, means that Mexico is relatively
labor abundant - These differences affect the shape of each
countrys PPF - Suppose that cars are produced rel.
K-intensively, and textiles labor intensively
16Autarky in Mexico and the U.S.
U.S.
Mexico
Cars
Cars
(PT/PC)Mex
E
e
Y1
Y4
(PT/PC)US
X1
Textiles
Textiles
X4
17Autarky in Mexico and the U.S.
- The relative price of textiles in autarky is
greater in the U.S. than in Mexico - That is, the U.S.s autarky price line is steeper
than Mexicos - In symbols, (PT/PC)U.S. gt (PT/PC)Mex.
- This means that Mexico has the comparative
advantage in textiles
18Autarky in Mexico and the U.S.
U.S.
Mexico
Cars
Cars
(PT/PC)Mex
E
e
Y1
Y4
(PT/PC)US
X1
Textiles
Textiles
X4
19Autarky in Mexico and the U.S.
- This also means that the relative price of cars
in autarky is lower in the U.S. than in Mexico - That is, (PC/PT)U.S. lt (PC/PT)Mex.
- This means that the U.S. has the comparative
advantage in cars
20Autarky to Trade
U.S.
Mexico
Cars
Cars
(PX/PY)trade
E
e
Y1
Y4
X1
Textiles
Textiles
X4
21Production in Trade
U.S.
Mexico
Cars
Cars
(PX/PY)T
e'
Y5
E
e
Y1
Y4
E'
Y2
X1
X2
Textiles
Textiles
X4
X5
22Consumption in Trade
U.S.
Mexico
Cars
Cars
e'
Y5
C'
Y3
E
e
Y1
Y4
c'
Y6
E'
Y2
X1
X2
Textiles
Textiles
X5
X6
X3
X4
23The Result
- The relatively capital abundant country (U.S.)
exports the relatively capital intensive good
(cars) - The relatively labor abundant country (Mexico)
exports the relatively labor intensive good
(textiles)
24The Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem
- A country will export the commodity that uses
relatively intensively the factor that country
has in relative abundance - A country will import the commodity that uses
relatively intensively the factor that is
relatively scarce in that country
25The Source of Comparative Advantage
- If a country has a lot of labor relative to K,
its wage rates will be relatively low, so - the product that uses a lot of labor in its
production (relatively speaking) will be produced
at a relatively low cost, so - the country should export the labor intensive good
26The Source of Comparative Advantage
- If a country has a lot of capital relative to L,
its capital price will be relatively low, so - the product that uses a lot of K in its
production (relatively speaking) will be produced
at a relatively low cost, so - the country should export the capital intensive
good
27The Source of Comparative Advantage
- So it is a countrys relative factor endowment
that determines its comparative advantage - This is why the H-O-S model is also called the
factor proportions theory
28Changes in Relative Commodity Prices
- As we learned before,
- (PT/PC)US falls as the U.S. moves to trade. That
is, the international relative textile price is
lower than the U.S.s autarky price. - (PT/PC)Mex rises as Mexico moves to trade. That
is, the international relative textile price is
higher than Mexicos autarky price.
29Changes in Factor Prices
- In autarky, the K-intensive product (cars) is
less expensive to produce in the U.S. as compared
to Mexico - this is because K is relatively abundant in the
U.S., which makes the price of capital
relatively low - As trade commences, r will rise since demand for
capital will rise
30Changes in the Price of Capital in the U.S.
r
SK
D1K
QK
31Changes in the Price of Capital in the U.S.
r
SK
In autarky, the price of capital (r1) is
determined by supply of and demand for capital
in the U.S
r1
D1K
QK
32Changes in the Price of Capital in the U.S.
r
SK
When trade starts, the U.S. increases its
production of the capital intensive product, and
therefore demand for capital increases in the U.S.
r2
r1
D2K
D1K
QK
33Changes in Factor Prices
- In autarky, the L-intensive product (textiles) is
more expensive to produce in the U.S. as compared
to Mexico - this is because L is relatively scarce in the
U.S., which makes the price of labor relatively
high. - As trade commences, w will fall since demand for
labor will fall
34Changes in the Price of Labor in the U.S.
w
SL
D1L
QL
35Changes in the Price of Labor in the U.S.
w
SL
In autarky, the price of labor (w1) is determined
by supply of and demand for labor in the U.S
w1
D1L
QL
36Changes in the Price of Labor in the U.S.
w
SL
When trade starts, the U.S. decreases its
production of the labor intensive product, and
therefore demand for labor decreases in the U.S.
w1
w2
D1L
QL
37Commodity and Factor Prices In Trade A Summary
- When trade begins, the relative price of the good
intensive in the abundant factor rises (e.g.,
(PC/PT)US rises) - The relative price of the good intensive in the
scarce factor falls (e.g., (PT/PC)US falls) - Also, the price of the abundant factor rises, and
the price of the scarce factor falls (i.e., w
falls, r rises in the U.S.)
38Commodity and Factor Prices In Trade A Summary
- In our example, (PT/PC)US falls as trade
commences - (w/r)US also falls
- In Mexico, the opposite is happening
- (PT/PC)Mex rises
- (w/r)Mex also rises
- Therefore relative commodity and factor prices
move together as trade commences
39The Relative Cost Curve
- Since relative factor and commodity prices move
together as countries move from autarky to trade,
we can look at a picture of these two sorts of
prices - We also know that in autarky (PT/PC)Mex is lower
than (PT/PC)US - (w/r)Mex is also lower in autarky than (w/r)US
since Mexico is relatively labor abundant
40The Relative Cost Curve
PT/PC
(PT/PC)US
(PT/PC)Mex
(w/r)Mex
w/r
(w/r)US
41The Relative Cost Curve
PT/PC
(PT/PC)US
(PT/PC)Mex
(w/r)Mex
w/r
(w/r)US
42The Relative Cost Curve
PT/PC
(PT/PC)US
As trade commences, (PT/PC)US falls, and
(PT/PC)Mex rises
(PT/PC)Mex
(w/r)Mex
w/r
(w/r)US
43The Relative Cost Curve
PT/PC
(PT/PC)US
In addition, as trade commences (w/r)US falls,
and (w/r)Mex rises
(PT/PC)Mex
(w/r)Mex
w/r
(w/r)US
44Factor Price Equalization
- In fact, each country moves along the relative
cost curve to a common point - We know this because there is only one
international price - If the countries wind up with a common
international price, they must also wind up with
a common set of relative factor prices
45The Relative Cost Curve
PT/PC
(PT/PC)US
(PT/PC)Int
Both relative commodity and factor prices
equalize in trade
(PT/PC)Mex
(w/r)Mex
(w/r)US
w/r
(w/r)Int
46The Factor Price Equalization Theorem
- In equilibrium, with both countries facing the
same relative product prices, relative costs will
be equalized. This can only happen if relative
factor prices are equalized between countries.
47H-O-S and the Distribution of Income
- The H-O theorem, together with the FPE theorem,
also tell us about how the incomes of different
groups within a country change as trade starts - This provides insight into the politics of free
trade
48The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem
- As trade commences, the owners of the relatively
abundant factor will find their real incomes
rising the owners of the relatively scarce
factor will find their real incomes falling.
49H-O-S and the Distribution of Income
- According to the S-S theorem, if the U.S. is a
relatively K-abundant country, who in America
should favor free trade? - Who in America should favor protectionism?
50Theoretical Qualifications to H-O-S
- Suppose we relax some of the many assumptions.
Will the implications of the H-O-S model still be
the same?
51Qualification 1 Demand Reversal
- Normally, the relative price of the commodity
that uses intensively the abundant factor will be
lower - In our example, (PC/PT)US lt (PC/PT)Mex
- Or, (PT/PC)US gt (PT/PC)Mex
- What causes this difference in autarky prices?
Differences in supply conditions
52Qualification 1 Demand Reversal
- Suppose we let demand conditions differ
- Suppose domestic demand for the good that uses
relatively intensively the relatively abundant
factor is very strong in each country - That is, suppose demand for cars is very strong
in the U.S., and that demand for textiles is very
strong in Mexico
53Qualification 1 Demand Reversal
- Such strong demand makes the autarky car price in
the U.S. higher, and the textile price in Mexico
higher - In the extreme, demand reversal could occur
(PC/PT)US gt (PC/PT)Mex, and - (PT/PC)US lt (PT/PC)Mex
- So what?
54Qualification 1 Demand Reversal
- When trade begins, as usual the intl price will
lie between the two countries APRs - Therefore (PC/PT) for Mexico will rise as it
moves to trade - Mexico, then, would export cars
- Meanwhile, (PT/PC) for the U.S. will rise as it
moves to trade - The U.S., then, would export textiles
55Bottom Line on Demand Reversals
- If demand reversals occur, the H-O theorem no
longer holds the K-abundant country is exporting
the L-intensive good, and the L-abundant country
is exporting the K-intensive good - If demand reversals are common in the real world,
wed better find a new theory
56Qualification 2 Factor Intensity Reversal
- Implicitly, weve assumed that if good X is
K-intensive relative to good Y at one factor
price ratio, it will be K-intensive at all factor
prices - A FIR is when a good is relatively K-intensive at
one set of factor prices, but relatively labor
intensive at another
57Qualification 2 Factor Intensity Reversal
- FIRs occur when capital and labor can be
substituted more easily in the production of one
good than another - Example
- Suppose butane production is very inflexible 1K
1L 1 butane, and if you want more butane you
must add more of both K and L - Suppose apple production is much more flexible
58Qualification 2 Factor Intensity Reversal
- If w/r is very high, apple producers will choose
a relatively K-intensive method (as compared with
butane makers) - If w/r starts to fall, apple producers will start
substituting L for K - Eventually, its possible that apples might be
produced in a relatively L-intensive manner (as
compared with butane)
59Factor Intensity Reversal Implications for Trade
- Suppose France is K-abundant relative to Germany
(that is (K/L)F gt (K/L)G) - This means that (w/r)F gt (w/r)G
- Suppose further that there is a FIR in France,
at (w/r)F apples are produced relatively
K-intensively but in Germany at (w/r)G apples are
produced in a relatively L-intensive way
60Factor Intensity Reversal Implications for Trade
- If trade begins, according to the H-O theorem the
relatively K-abundant country (France) will
export the rel. K-intensive good (apples) and the
rel. L-abundant country will export the rel.
L-intensive good (also apples) - This cant work
61Factor Intensity Reversal The Bottom Line
- If FIRs are present, the H-O theorem breaks down
- If FIRs are common, wed better find a new theory
62Qualification 3 Transportation Costs
- In the real world, it is costly to transport
goods internationally - How do the implications of our model change if we
allow for transportation costs? - Consider the supply and demand curves for
textiles in Mexico and the U.S.
63Basic Set-Up
U.S.
SText
PT
PT
Mexico
SText
PAUS
PAMex
DText
DText
QT
QT
64Basic Set-Up
U.S.
SText
PT
PT
Mexico
SText
PAUS
PIntl
PIntl
PAMex
DText
DText
q1
q2
QT
QT
q1
q2
65Basic Set-Up
U.S.
SText
PT
PT
Mexico
SText
PAUS
Exp.
PIntl
PIntl
Imp.
PAMex
DText
DText
q1
q2
QT
QT
q1
q2
66Adding Transportation Costs
- Suppose Mexico tries to pass along 100 of the
transportation costs to the U.S. consumers - In this case, the U.S. textile price will rise,
and the quantity of imports demanded will fall - Mexico will have a surplus, and will eventually
lower their domestic price
67Adding Transportation Costs
U.S.
SText
PT
PT
Mexico
SText
Exp.
t-costs
PIntl
PIntl
Imp.
DText
DText
q1
q2
q1
q2
QT
QT
68Adding Transportation Costs
- Therefore, unless Mexico is the only seller in
the world, transportation costs will be borne by
both the consumer (the U.S.) and the seller
(Mexico). - How does this look on the graph?
69Adding Transportation Costs
U.S.
SText
PT
PT
Mexico
SText
Exp.
PIntl
PIntl
Imp.
DText
DText
q1
q2
q1
q2
QT
QT
70Adding Transportation Costs
U.S.
SText
PT
PT
Mexico
SText
Exp.
PIntl
PIntl
t-costs
Imp.
DText
DText
q1
q2
q1
q2
QT
QT
71Adding Transportation Costs
- Notice there is no longer a single international
textile price, but rather two different ones - That is, transportation costs drive a wedge
between the two countries prices
72Adding Transportation Costs the Bottom Line
- In general, the H-O theorem will still hold
- The FPE theorem breaks down, since factor prices
only equalize if the commodity prices do - Therefore, in the presence of transportation
costs, factor prices have a tendency to move
towards each other, but we should not expect
equalization
73Relaxing Other Assumptions
- One can relax many other assumptions and examine
how the implications of the model change - perfect competition
- CRTS
- identical production technologies
- lack of policy obstacles
- factors being perfectly transferable
74Relaxing Other Assumptions
- These issues have involved many researchers for
many years - You can read a bit about this research in your
text, but we have other fish to fry - Suffice it to say that relaxing these assumptions
can modify the basic H-O-S model, but doesnt
lead us to scrap the model