What Drives Merger Waves? - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 26
About This Presentation
Title:

What Drives Merger Waves?

Description:

Recently, authors such as Shleifer and Vishny and Rhodes-Kropf and Vishwanathan ... While there is undoubtedly some merger activity driven by managers timing the ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:469
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 27
Provided by: landoras6
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: What Drives Merger Waves?


1
What Drives Merger Waves?
  • Jarrad Harford

2
Motivation
  • The question of what drives waves of merger
    activity is an old one.
  • Recently, authors such as Shleifer and Vishny and
    Rhodes-Kropf and Vishwanathan have developed
    behavioral models explaining the observed
    relation between stock market valuations and
    merger activity.
  • This has refocused the debate as one between
    neoclassical and behavioral explanations for
    waves

3
Research Question
  • Is a clustering of mergers at the aggregate level
    due to a combination of industry shocks for which
    mergers facilitate change to the new environment,
    or is it due to market timing?

4
Hypotheses
  • Neoclassical hypothesis
  • Based on the work of Coase (1937), Gort (1969),
    Maksimovic and Phillips (2001), Jovanovic and
    Rousseau (2001,2002)
  • Economic disturbance leads to industry
    reorganization
  • Modify to include a role for capital liquidity
  • Eisfeldt and Rampini (2003)
  • Shleifer and Vishny (1992)
  • Once a technological, regulatory or economic
    shock occurs, the collective reaction of firms
    inside and outside the industry reallocates
    industry assets through merger and partial-firm
    acquisitions.

5
Hypotheses
  • Behavioral Hypothesis
  • Shleifer and Vishny (2003)
  • Bull markets lead groups of bidders with
    overvalued stock to use it to buy real assets of
    undervalued targets.
  • Model relies on dispersion in valuations and time
    horizons.
  • Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2003)
  • Rational targets accept bids from overvalued
    bidders because they overestimate synergies
    during market peaks.
  • Both models rely on bidder managers timing market
    valuations.

6
Predictions
  • Neoclassical Hypothesis
  • Observable shocks will precede waves
  • MOP will be either stock or cash
  • Both mergers and partial-firm cash transactions
  • Credit constraints will be low and/or asset
    values will be high

7
Predictions
  • Behavioral Hypothesis
  • Merger waves occur following periods of
    abnormally high stock returns or M/B ratios,
    especially when dispersion in those metrics is
    high
  • Post-wave returns should be poor
  • Post-merger operating performance should be
    particularly poor in waves
  • MOP should be overwhelmingly stock
  • Partial-firm transactions for cash should not be
    common

8
Sample
  • I end-up with
  • 35 waves from 28 industries (7 of which have 2
    waves, one in the 1980s and one in the 1990s)
  • Average 24-month non-wave period has 7.8 bids
  • Average 24-month wave period has 34.3 bids
  • How I got there

9
Sample
  • Start with all merger transactions (gt50mil) on
    SDC from 1981 to 2000
  • Measure highest 24-month concentration in 1980s
    and 1990s for each industry (Fama-French 48
    industries)
  • For each industry, compare that concentration to
    the empirical distribution of concentrations from
    1000 simulations specific to that industry
  • If the actual concentration was greater than the
    95th percentile concentration in the
    distribution, categorize that period as a wave

10
Industry Characteristics and Waves
  • Operating Environment
  • Shocks to Profitability (cash flow/sales), Asset
    turnover (Sales/TA), Sales growth, ROA, Employee
    Growth,
  • RD, Capital Expenditures
  • Market valuations
  • 1- and 3-year returns and s of those returns
  • Market-to-book ratios
  • Measure all variables in year prior to start of
    an industry merger wave

11
Univariate Results
  • Summary of Table 2
  • Shocks to profitability, asset turnover, sales
    growth, ROA, employee growth, RD, Capital
    Expenditures are all abnormally high
  • M/B, change in M/B and s(M/B) are all abnormally
    high
  • 3-year return is abnormally high, but 1-year
    return, s(3-year return), s(1-year return) are
    all not

12
Univariate Results
  • Deregulation and Capital Liquidity
  • Index of deregulatory events
  • 4-quarter moving average of the Commercial
    Industrial rate spread
  • Federal reserves SLO survey
  • Highly correlated with the question of tightening
    or easing credit

13
Figure 1 Capital Liquidity, Industry Merger
Waves and Aggregate Merger Activity
14
Predicting an Industry Merger Wave
  • Logit models
  • All 48 industries for the 20-year sample period
  • Problem operating shocks are too highly
    correlated
  • Solution 1st principal component from 7 shock
    variables
  • Include on its own and with an interaction for
    capital liquidity
  • Low capital liquidity high CI rate spread or
    low M/B

15
Table 4 Predicting Merger Waves
16
Summary of Logit Models
  • On their own, behavioral variables have some
    predictive power for merger waves.
  • However,
  • Commonly cited association between stock price
    performance and merger waves disappears after
    controlling for capital liquidity
  • Once nested within a neoclassical model of merger
    waves, the behavioral variables add little
    explanatory power

17
Partial-firm (divisional) Acquisitions
  • Neoclassical hypothesis predicts that
    transactions will occur both at the firm and
    divisional level and that the MOP will be both
    cash and stock
  • Mulherin and Boone (2000), Maksimovic and
    Phillips (2001), Schlingemann, Stulz and Walkling
    (2002),
  • Behavioral hypothesis cannot explain divisional
    transactions for cash, especially when executed
    by stock-swap bidders

18
(No Transcript)
19
 
Table 5 The Relation between Merger Activity and
Partial-Firm Acquisitions
20
Table 5, Panel B
21
Summarizing Partial-firm acq. results
  • Total firm-level and partial-firm level activity
    are highly correlated
  • Stock-swap only merger activity is correlated
    with cash partial-firm level activity
  • Being a bidder strongly predicts being a buyer in
    a partial-firm transaction
  • Even being a stock bidder strongly predicts being
    a cash buyer in a partial-firm transaction

22
Long-run returns
  • Behavioral hypothesis predicts poor long-run
    returns following merger waves.
  • Extant evidence is mixed (e.g. Loughran and Vijh,
    1997 Mitchell and Stafford, 2000)
  • Use Fama (1998)s calendar time approach
  • Create monthly portfolios of treatment firms
  • Regress vector of monthly returns on FF 3-factor
    realizations

23
Table 6 Long-run Returns
24
Table 6, Panel B
25
Summary of Long-run Return Results
  • There is little evidence of abnormally low
    returns following merger waves
  • There is some evidence of poor post-merger
    returns for stock bidders in merger waves. This
    evidence is not robust to equal-weighted returns.

26
Operating Performance
  • Inherently noisy tests during merger waves
  • Idea is to compare with-merger performance to
    performance that would have occurred without the
    merger
  • Pre-merger performance and industry performance
    are probably both noisy proxies for performance
    without the merger
  • Consequently, neoclassical hypothesis makes no
    prediction about the observed post-merger
    performance in a wave
  • Under the null of the behavioral hypothesis,
    post-merger performance in waves should be
    particularly poor

27
Table 7 Operating Performance Changes following
Mergers
28
Summary of Operating Performance Tests
  • No evidence that post-merger operating
    performance is worse for mergers during waves
  • Only evidence of a difference for wave vs.
    non-wave mergers is better post-merger asset
    turnover and M/B

29
Summary of Predictions and Findings
30
Conclusions
  • Comparing the behavioral and neoclassical (with
    capital liquidity) hypotheses, the results
    consistently support the neoclassical hypothesis
  • The role of capital liquidity causes industry
    merger waves to cluster in time even if industry
    shocks do not
  • The relation between asset values and merger
    activity reflects capital liquidity rather than
    misvaluation

31
Conclusions
  • While there is undoubtedly some merger activity
    driven by managers timing the market, such
    mergers do not cause merger waves.
  • Aggregate merger waves are caused by the
    clustering of shock-driven industry merger waves,
    not by attempts to time the market.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com