Title: 4 Lectures on the
14 Lectures on the uropean crisis
- Lecture 4 The philosophy of the EMU economic
polices fiscal policies of the monetary union
fiscal governance the debate on the fiscal
multipliers
2The philosophy of the EMU economic policies
- Independent CB ? monetary policy is ineffective
in the long run price stability is the
predominant target - Budget deficit crowds out private investment. So
balanced budget rules ? Maastricht Treaty and
Stability and Growth Pact reinforced by most
recent measures (six and two packs fiscal
compact) - Full employment pursued at national level through
market and (mainly) labour market flexibility. - A full anti-Keynesian program no ex-ante
coordination of budget and monetary policies. - Otmar Issing ? no need for ex ante coordination.
If countries follow the rules there will be an ex
post coordination by he market.
3Alternative view
- Monetary policy is effective of course,
expansionary policies raise inflation, but a
natural unemployment rate defined at a zero (or
very low) inflation rate is a fiction useful to
keep wages under control. Income policy should be
used to keep inflation under control. - Fiscal policy does not crowd out private
investment which are, in general, not at full
employment level - Coordination between fiscal and monetary policy
at an international level is necessary in order
to permit fiscal expansions, when necessary, at
low interest rates. - Full employment is an international question, not
a national one! International coordination is
necessary. - There is not a potential output at which, with
price and wages flexibility, the economy tends
to potential output depends on long term
aggregate demand and if AD is depressed,
productive capacity is lost.
4The European economic governancehttp//europa.eu/
rapid/press-release_MEMO-13-979_en.htm
- Crisis prevention Fiscal policy regulated by the
GSP (Amsterdam 1997) and by a baroque number of
new regulations approved in the last years. - The Stability and Growth Pact was established at
the same time as the single currency in order to
ensure sound public finances. However, the way it
was enforced before the crisis did not prevent
the emergence of serious fiscal imbalances in
some Member States. - It has been reformed through the Six Pack (which
became law in December 2011) and the Two Pack
(which entered into force in May 2013), and
reinforced by the Treaty on Stability,
Coordination and Governance (which entered into
force in January 2013 in its 25 signatory
countries). - The new rules (introduced through the Six Pack,
the Two Pack and the Treaty on Stability,
Coordination and Governance) are grounded in the
European Semester, the EU's policy-making
calendar. - Crisis management
- EFSF and ESM
5The European economic governance Growth and
stability pact
- The SGP contains two arms the preventive arm
and the corrective arm. The preventive arm seeks
to ensure that fiscal policy is conducted in a
sustainable manner over the cycle. The corrective
arm sets out the framework for countries to take
corrective action in the case of an excessive
deficit. - The cornerstone of the preventive arm is the
country-specific medium-term budgetary objective
(MTO), defined in structural terms (i.e. in
cyclically adjusted terms and net of one-off and
other temporary measures). Member States outline
their medium-term budgetary plans in stability
and convergence programmes (SCP), which are
submitted and assessed annually in the context of
multilateral fiscal surveillance under the
European Semester. - The corrective arm is made operational by the
Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP), a step-by-step
procedure for correcting excessive deficits that
occur when one or both of the rules that the
deficit must not exceed 3 of GDP and public debt
must not exceed 60 of GDP (or at least diminish
sufficiently towards the 60) defined in the
Treaty on the Functioning of the EU (TFEU or
Treaty) are breached. - Non-compliance with either the preventive or
corrective arms of the Pact can lead to the
imposition of sanctions for euro area countries.
In the case of the corrective arm, this can
involve annual fines for euro area Member States
and, for all countries, possible suspension of
Cohesion Fund financing until the excessive
deficit is corrected.
6The European economic governance the European
semester
- The European Semester represents a yearly cycle
of EU economic policy guidance and
country-specific surveillance. Each year the
European Commission undertakes a detailed
analysis of EU Member States' programmes of
economic and structural reforms and provides them
with recommendations for the next 12-18 months. - Within the European semester the European
authorities intervene in the formulation of
national fiscal policies (ex ante coordination) - (e.g. the Commission in November had reservations
about the Italian budget )
7The European semester some relevant dates
- October Euro area Member States submit draft
budget plans for the following year to the
Commission (by 15 October). If a plan is out of
line with a Member State's medium-term targets,
the Commission can ask it to be redrafted. - November The Commission publishes its opinions
on draft budget plans. The Alert Mechanism Report
(AMR) screens Member States for economic
imbalances. - December Euro area Member States adopt final
annual budgets, taking into account the
Commission's advice and finance ministers'
opinions. - February/March It is around this time that the
Commission publishes in-depth reviews of Member
States with potential imbalances (those
identified in the AMR). - April Member States submit their
Stability/Convergence Programmes (medium-term
budget plans) and their National Reform
Programmes (economic plans), which should be in
line with all previous EU recommendations.
Eurostat publishes verified debt and deficit data
from the previous year, which is important to
check if Member States are meeting their fiscal
targets. - June/July The European Council endorses the
CSRs, and EU ministers meeting in the Council
discuss them. EU finance ministers ultimately
adopt them in July.
8Six pack
- Entered into force on 13 December 2011
- Five Regulations and one Directive (that is why
it is called six-pack) - Applies to 27 MS with some specific rules for
euro-area Member States, especially regarding
financial sanctions - The six-pack does not only cover fiscal
surveillance, but also macroeconomic surveillance
under the new Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure. - In the fiscal field, the six-pack strengthens the
Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). According to the
SGP Member States' budgetary balance shall
converge towards the country-specific medium-term
objective (MTO) - so-called preventive arm - and
the general government deficit must not exceed 3
of GDP and public debt must not exceed 60 of GDP
(or at least diminish sufficiently towards the
60 threshold). The six-pack reinforces both the
preventive and the corrective arm of the Pact,
i.e. the Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP), which
applies to Member States that have breached
either the deficit or the debt criterion.
9Six Pack
- The six-pack ensures stricter application of the
fiscal rules by defining quantitatively what a
"significant deviation" from the MTO or the
adjustment path towards it means in the context
of the preventive arm. - Moreover, the six-pack operationalizes the debt
criterion, so that an EDP may also be launched on
the basis of a debt ratio above 60 of GDP which
would not diminish towards the Treaty reference
value at a satisfactory pace (and not only on the
basis of a deficit above 3 of GDP, which has
been the case so far). - Financial sanctions for euro-area Member States
are imposed in a gradual way, from the preventive
arm to the latest stages of the EDP, and may
eventually reach 0.5 of GDP. The six-pack
introduces reverse qualified majority voting
(RQMV) for most sanctions, therefore increasing
their likelihood for euro-area Member States.
(RQMV implies that a recommendation or a proposal
of the Commission is considered adopted in the
Council unless a qualified majority of Member
States votes against it.)
10Treaty on Stability, Coordination and
Governance (TSCG)
- Entered into force on 1 January 2013.
- The fiscal part of the TSCG is referred to as
"Fiscal Compact". Requires contracting parties to
respect/ensure convergence towards the
country-specific medium-term objective (MTO), as
defined in the SGP and Six Pack (e.g. convergence
to 60 at the pace of 1/20 per year). - Lower limit of a structural deficit (cyclical
effects and one-off measures are not taken into
account) of 0.5 of GDP (1.0 of GDP for Member
States with a debt ratio significantly below 60
of GDP). - These budget rules shall be implemented in
national law through provisions of "binding force
and permanent character, preferably
constitutional". (? this is the real novelty of
the TSCG). Compliance with the rule should be
monitored by independent institutions - European Court of Justice (CoJ) may impose
financial sanction (0.1 of GDP) if a country
does not properly implement the new budget rules
in national law and fails to comply with a CoJ
ruling that requires it to do so.
11Two Packs
- Approved 13 May 2013. Reinforces the role of the
Commission in the evaluation of national budgets - As part of a common budgetary timeline, euro-area
Member States shall submit their draft budgetary
plan for the following year to the Commission and
the Eurogroup before 15 October, along with the
independent macro-economic forecast on which they
are based. - This builds on the Stability and Growth Pact
(SGP), under which Member States present the main
characteristics of their medium-term public
finance plans to the Commission and the Council
in spring (in Stability or Convergence
Programmes). The exercise in autumn introduced by
the two-pack allows monitoring and sharing
information on MS budgetary policies closer to
their adoption. The Commission analyses if the
draft budget is in line with the SGP and the
recommendations from the European Semester (which
the country has received in May/June). - If the Commission assesses that the draft
budgetary plan shows serious non-compliance with
the SGP, the Commission can require a revised
draft budgetary plan.
12Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure (MIP) (Included
in the Six Pack)
- The Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure (MIP) is a
surveillance mechanism that aims to identify
potential risks early on, prevent the emergence
of harmful macroeconomic imbalances and correct
the imbalances that are already in place. - The alert mechanism consists of an
indicator-based scoreboard complemented by an
economic reading thereof presented in an annual
Alert Mechanism Report (AMR). - On this basis, the Commission decides for which
countries it will prepare country-specific
in-depth reviews. - In the preventive arm this is part of the
integrated package of recommendations under the
European semester. If the Commission instead
considers that there are severe or excessive
imbalances that may jeopardise the proper
functioning of the Economic and Monetary
Union, it may recommend to the Council to open an
Excessive Imbalance Procedure (EIP) which falls
under the corrective arm of the new procedure. - In case the in-depth review points to severe or
excessive imbalances in a Member State that may
jeopardise the proper functioning of the Economic
and Monetary Union, the Council may declare the
existence of an excessive imbalance and adopt a
recommendation asking the Member State to present
corrective actions within a specified deadline.
13Scoreboard indicators a boring and expected list
with few (limited) exceptions
- 3 year backward moving average of the current
account balance as percent of GDP, with
thresholds of 6 and -4 - net international investment position as percent
of GDP, with a threshold of -35 - 5 years percentage change of export market shares
measured in values, with a threshold of -6 - 3 years percentage change in nominal unit labour
cost, with thresholds of 9 for euroarea
countries and 12 for non-euroarea countries - 3 years percentage change of the real effective
exchange rates based on HICP/CPI deflators,
relative to 41 other industrial countries, with
thresholds of -/5 for euroarea countries and
-/11 for non-euroarea countries - private sector debt (consolidated) in of GDP
with a threshold of 133 - private sector credit flow in of GDP with a
threshold of 15 - year-on-year changes in house prices relative to
a Eurostat consumption deflator, with a threshold
of 6 - general government sector debt in of GDP with a
threshold of 60 - 3-year backward moving average of unemployment
rate, with a threshold of 10 - year-on-year changes in total financial sector
liabilities, with a threshold of 16.5.
14Limits bad Economics and morality play
- Why the asymmetry 6/-4 CA surpluses? ? CA
surpluses are a vice from the international
economy point of view. Stop the morality play in
Economics. - Why only a negative NIP is sanctioned? Huge
positive NIP must as well. - Why in case of imbalances action must be taken at
national level only? This is again a morality
play (YOU are guilty) and bad Economics - In case the in-depth review points to severe or
excessive imbalances in a Member State that may
jeopardise the proper functioning of the Economic
and Monetary Union, the Council may declare the
existence of an excessive imbalance and adopt a
recommendation asking the Member State to present
corrective actions within a specified deadline.
Then, , the Member State is obliged to present a
corrective action plan (CAP) setting up a roadmap
to implement corrective policy actions. The CAP
should be a detailed plan for corrective actions
with specific policy measures and implementation
timetable. As regards the content of the CAP it
is clear that the policy response to
macroeconomic imbalances has to be tailored to
the circumstances of the Member State concerned
and where needed will cover the main policy
areas, including fiscal and wage policies, labour
markets, product and services markets and the
financial sector. Moreover, efficiency and
credibility derive from consistent approaches
across policy strands.
15Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure for Germany
much ado about nothing
- Daniel Gros argues that the 13 November
announcement of the European Commission that
Germany is running an excessive current account
surplus appears to be much ado about little. All
the Commission can, and will, do is to start an
in depth analysis. This might lead to strong
political reactions and an enormous echo in the
media. But nothing of concrete substance is
likely to follow. (http//www.ceps.eu/book/macroec
onomic-imbalance-procedure-and-germany-when-surplu
s-E2809CimbalanceE2809D)
16The mysterious Golden rule Let us (Lettas) have
a dream
- In principles well behaved countries, those not
under a EDP, will be able to exclude the
following year some public investment from the
deficit. Spain and France decided not to well
behave, and are in principle subject to the EDP.
But they grew (or better, they declined less)
than Italy. In spite of huge austerity Oli Rehn
(I refrain from defining its intelligence) said
no. We do not trust Italys efforts. They asked
more austerity! They are right not to trust the
Italian government. The question is that all the
European policy framework is mad.
17European acronymia EFSF and ESM
- The European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF)
was created by the euro area Member States
following the decisions taken on 9 May 2010
within the framework of the Ecofin Council. The
EFSFs mandate is to safeguard financial
stability in Europe by providing financial
assistance to euro area Member States within the
framework of a macro-economic adjustment
programme. - To fulfill its mission, EFSF issues bonds or
other debt instruments on the capital markets.
The proceeds of these issues are then lent to
countries under a programme. The EFSF may also
intervene in the primary and secondary bond
markets, act on the basis of a precautionary
programme and finance recapitalisations of
financial institutions through loans to
governments. - EFSF was created as a temporary rescue mechanism.
In October 2010, it was decided to create a
permanent rescue mechanism, the European
Stability Mechanism (ESM). The ESM entered into
force on 8 October 2012. - From this date onwards, the ESM will be the main
instrument to finance new programmes. In parallel
to the ESM, the EFSF will continue with the
ongoing programmes for Greece, Portugal and
Ireland.
18EFSF
- The Facility act after a support request is made
by a euro area Member State and a country
programme has been negotiated with the European
Commission and the IMF and after such a programme
has been accepted by the euro area finance
ministers and a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU)
is signed. This would only occur when the country
is unable to borrow on markets at acceptable
rates. - any financial assistance to a country in need is
linked to strict policy conditions which are set
out in a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU)
between the country in need and the European
Commission. - Following the increase of guarantee commitments
to 780 billion, EFSFs effective lending
capacity is intended to be 440 billion. This is
explained by the credit enhancement structure
which includes an overguarantee of up to 165 - On 28 November 2010, the ECOFIN Ministers
concurred with the European Commission and the
ECB that providing a loan to Ireland was
warranted to safeguard the financial stability in
the euro area and the EU as a whole. The total
lending programme for Ireland is 85 billion. - Following the formal request for financial
assistance made by the Portuguese authorities on
7 April 2011, the Eurogroup and ECOFIN Ministers
agreed to grant financial assistance on 17 May.
The financial package of the programme will cover
financing needs up to 78 billion. - At the euro zone summit held on 26 October 2011,
euro zone Heads of State or Government agreed to
a second financial assistance programme for
Greece. The details of this programme were agreed
by the Eurogroup on 21 February 2012. As part of
the second bailout for Greece, the loan is
shifted to the EFSF, amounting to 164 billion
19ESM
- The European Stability Mechanism is the permanent
crisis resolution mechanism for the countries of
the euro area. The ESM issues debt instruments in
order to finance loans and other forms of
financial assistance to euro area Members States. - The decision leading to the creation of the ESM
was taken by the European Council in December
2010. The euro area Member States signed an
intergovernmental treaty establishing the ESM on
2 February 2012. The ESM was inaugurated on 8
October 2012. - For this purpose, the ESM is entitled to raise
funds by issuing financial instruments or by
entering into financial or other agreements with
ESM Members, financial institutions or other
third parties. - All financial assistance to Member States is
linked to appropriate conditionality. - The ESM may provide stability support by
- -providing loans to countries in financial
difficulties, - purchasing bonds of an ESM Member State in
primary and secondary debt markets, - providing precautionary financial assistance in
the form of a credit line, - ? financing recapitalisations of financial
institutions through loans to governments
including in non-programme countries. - The ESMs maximum lending capacity is 500
billion. During the Eurogroup meeting held on 30
March 2012, it was decided that the EFSF would
continue to fund the existing Facility Agreements
for Portugal, Ireland and Greece.
20ESM
- Stability support loans within a macro-economic
adjustment programme. The objective is to assist
ESM Members that have significant financing needs
but have to a large extent lost access to market
financing, whether because they cannot find
lenders or because lenders will provide financing
only at excessive prices that would adversely
impact the sustainability of public finances. - Precautionary financial assistance The objective
of ESM precautionary financial assistance in the
form of credit lines is to support sound policies
and prevent crisis situations by allowing ESM
Members to secure ESM assistance before they face
major difficulties raising funds in the capital
markets. Precautionary financial assistance aims
at helping ESM Members whose economic conditions
are still sound to maintain continuous access to
market financing by reinforcing the credibility
of their macroeconomic performance while ensuring
an adequate safety-net. - Primary Market support facility The ESM may
engage in primary market purchases of bonds or
other debt securities issued by ESM Members to
allow them to maintain or restore their
relationship with the dealer/investment community
and therefore reduce the risk of a failed
auction. It would also serve to increase
efficiency of ESM lending. - Conditions would be those of the macroeconomic
adjustment programme or precautionary programme. - As announced by ECB President Mario Draghi on 6
September 2012, Outright Monetary Transactions,
i.e. is the purchase of euro area sovereign bonds
on the secondary market by the ECB, will be
considered for future cases of EFSF/ESM
macroeoconomic adjustment programmes or
precautionary programmes, provided that they
include the possibility of EFSF/ESM primary
market purchases.
21ESM
- Secondary Market Support Facility The Secondary
Market Support Facility aims to support the good
functioning of the government debt markets of ESM
Members in exceptional circumstances where the
lack of market liquidity threatens financial
stability, with a risk of pushing sovereign
interest rates towards unsustainable levels and
creating refinancing problems for the banking
system of the ESM Member concerned. An ESM
secondary market intervention is intended to
enable market-making that would ensure some debt
market liquidity and incentivise investors to
further participate in the financing of ESM
Members. - Bank recapitalisations The aim of a loan for
recapitalising financial institutions is to
preserve financial stability of the euro area as
a whole and of its Member States by addressing
those specific cases in which the roots of a
crisis situation are primarily located in the
financial sector and not directly related to
fiscal or structural policies. - Will the ESM make loans directly to financial
institutions? - Currently, the ESM may only lend to euro area
Member States. However, at the euro area summit
on 29 June 2012, it was proposed that once an
effective supervisory mechanism is established
for banks in the euro area, involving the ECB,
following a regular decision the ESM could have
the possibility to recapitalise banks directly.
22ESM
- On 25 June 2012, the Spanish government made an
official request for financial assistance for its
banking system to the Eurogroup for a loan of up
to 100 billion.The results of the diagnostic
exercise, commissioned by the Spanish authorities
to external evaluators, indicated that the
additional capitalisation needs of the Spanish
banking sector as a whole could be estimated to
be in a range of 51-62 billion. Including an
additional safety margin, these capital needs
would remain within the envelope approved by the
Eurogroup of up to 100 billion in total. - The programme will address the exceptional
financial, budgetary and structural challenges
that Cyprus is facing. The total amount of
financial assistance, agreed by the Eurogroup, is
up to 10 billion. Out of this amount, the ESM
will provide approximately 9 billion, and the
IMF will contribute around 1 billion.
23Comments
- Funds collected by the ESM are guaranteed by the
same troubled states, a vicious circle. Only the
ECB can guarantee the ESM. - The ESM plays the role of the ECB without the
printing press! - Proposals that the ESM functions as a bank, that
is uses its capital as leverage to borrow from
the ECB (this is a way to circumvent the
prohibition to the ECB to buy sovereign debt). - Prohibition to the ESM to lend directly to
troubled banks - Small size in the case of a default risk of a
major country. Indeed the ECB is the only
institution that can avoid big defaults. It has
always been so, it cannot be otherwise CBs have
been invented with that purpose!
24The debate on the fiscal multiplier
- When G falls or t rises, Y will fall. The
question is the dimension of the fall. Strong
debate over 2011-13 on the size of the
multipliers, that is on the effects of fiscal
austerity (or of the opposite fiscal expansion). - A multiplier of 1.5, for instance, means that 1
in government-spending cuts reduces GDP by 1.50
a multiplier of 0.5 means a 1 cut in spending
only reduces GDP by 50 cents. - Keynesians ? the multipliers are large
- supporters of expansionary fiscal retrenchment or
of Ricardo-Barro effect ? multipliers are low
25The conservatives viewpoint
- Ricardo-Barro effect if t falls, Y will remain
constant since people expect more future taxes,
so they will save they save all the extra-income
they receive via tax-reductions. Likewise, in
case of fiscal austerity if t rises, people will
save less expecting to pay less taxes in the
future, so non effects on Y. - On Ricardo-Barro ? during a crisis people consume
less than they like to so if they get
extra-income (through lower taxes or by getting a
subsidy or a job), they will spend more.
Conversely ? if during a crisis taxes are
increased, people will might save less but just
because they feel impoverished! Or, if they can,
they save the same being afraid of the future. - Expansionary fiscal retrenchment (Alberto
Alesina and Bocconi boys) ? austerity and leads
to higher credibility of long-run budget
sustainability and to lower interest rates that
help the adjustment in a virtuos circle
26In Europe conservatives have lost in theory but
(unfortunately) prevail in practice (they have
not won in Germany)
- Further and further empirical estimates of the
fiscal multipliers have shown that they are
larger than 1, often much larger they are large
in depressions, when capacity and labour are
under-utilised they are larger if monetary
policy is cooperative keeping interest payments
low.
27This is from Krugman
28References
- http//ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/articles/gover
nance/2012-03-14_six_pack_en.htm - http//ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/economic_gover
nance/ - http//ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/economic_gover
nance/macroeconomic_imbalance_procedure/index_en.h
tm - http//www.efsf.europa.eu/attachments/EFSF20FAQ2
001072013.pdf - http//www.esm.europa.eu/pdf/FAQ20ESM2022102013.
pdf - Gerhard Illing, Sebastian Watzka, Fiscal
Multipliers and Their Relevance in a Currency
Union A Survey, German Economic Review, 2013.