Title: Economics 100B
1Economics 100B
- Instructor Ted Bergstrom
- T.A. Oddgeir Ottesen
- Syllabus online at www.econ.ucsb.edu (Class
pages) - Or at www.econ.ucsb.edu\tedb
- (Econ 100B)
2Dont forget to register with Aplia
- First homework assignment due Sunday night.
- Instructions for signing up on class website.
3Lets get registered
4Have you ever bid for anything on eBay?
- Yes, frequently
- Yes, but not frequently
- No
5An Oil Auction
- This illustrates a common value auction in
which different bidders have partial information
about the value of object being auctioned. - Two bidders. Each has explored half of the oil
field. - Whole oil field is up for bids.
6Auction Details
- Coin flips determine value of each side 3 m if
head, 0 if tails. - Bidder A sees result only for side A
- Bidder B sees result only for side B
- Bidders submit sealed bid for the whole oil field
(both sides)
7Is this oilfield auction a common value auction
or a private values auction?
- Common Value
- Private Values
8Answer
- This is a common values auction. The oilfield is
worth the same amount to whoever gets it. - The only difference between the bidders is that
they have different bits of information. - This would be a private values auction if e.g.
one firm could use the oilfield more effectively
than the other.
9In this auction, if you are Player A and you see
that your side of the field is worth 0, could
you make a profit by bidding 3 million or more?
- Yes, this would be a good strategy.
- Yes, but chances are low, so this is not a good
strategy. - No, I could never make money and I may lose money
with such a bid.
10In this auction, if you are Player A and your
side of the oilfield is worth zero, what is your
expected value for the whole field?
- 3,000,000
- 6,000,000
- 4,500,000
- 1,500,000
- 0
11Expected Value is sum of possible values times
probabilities of each value.
- Two possible outcomes
- Other side has value 0.
- Other side has value 3,000,000.
- Each outcome has probability 1/2
- My side of the field is worth 0.
- So expected value of whole field is
- 0x1/23,000,000x1/21,500,000
12In this auction, if you are Player A and your
side of the oilfield is worth 3,000,000 what is
your expected value for the whole field?
- 3,000,000
- 6,000,000
- 4,500,000
- 1,500,000
- 9,000,000
13Expected Value or whole field if my side is worth
3,000,000
- Two possible outcomes
- Other side has value 0.
- Other side has value 3,000,000.
- Each outcome has probability 1/2
- So expected value of whole field is
- 3,000,000 (0x1/23,000,000x1/2)4,500,000
14What happens if bidders bid expected values?
- They would bid 1.5 mil if their own side worth
0 and 4.5 mil if their own side is worth 3
mil. - Suppose you see 0 and bid 1.5 mil.
- If other guy sees 3 mil, he will bid 4.5
- And you dont get field. If other guy sees 0, he
bids 1.5 and you flip coin for who gets the
field.
15How did you do?
- If you saw 0 and bid 1.5 million, you will not
get the field if it is valuable, but you have a
50-50 chance of paying 1.5 million for a
worthless field. - Not a good outcome for you.
16Similar problem if you see 3 mil and bid 4.5
mil.
- If other guy saw 0, he bids 1.5 mil and you get
3 mil worth of oil field for 4.5 mil. This
happens with probability ½. - If other guy sees 3 mil, he bids 4.5 mil. Coin
is flipped. You might win coin toss and get 6
mil worth of oil for 4.5 mil. But this happens
only with probability 1/2x1/21/4. - Prob lose 1.5 mil is ½, prob win 1.5 mil is ¼.
Not a good deal.
17Conclusion
- In this auction, you would on average lose money
if you bid as high as your expected value.
18The winners curse
- In this auction, you would on average lose money
if you bid as high as your expected value. - The expected value conditional on winning the
auction is lower than the expected value. - This effect is called the winners curse.
19Buying Montana
- I will sell a contract in which I promise to pay
.01 for every 1000 people who live in Montana.
Thats 1 for every 100,000 people in Montana. - The sale will be by an English auction.
- Top bidder pays me his bid. I pay top bidder .01
for every thousand people who live in Montana.
20Auction Design
- Possible Goals
- Pareto efficiency
- maximization of the sellers profit.
21Auction Design
- Pareto efficiency
- the item must sell to the buyer with the highest
valuation of the item. - Which auctions are Pareto efficient?
22Auctions and Efficiency
- English auction with no reserve price must be
efficient since, if a buyer with a low valuation
was about to buy, the highest valuation buyer
would bid higher.
23Auctions and Efficiency
- English auction with a reserve price need not be
efficient since if the reserve price is set above
the (unknown to the seller) highest buyer
valuation, then there will be no sale and so no
gains-to-trade.
24Auctions and Efficiency
- Dutch auction need not be efficient. No buyer
knows other buyers valuations, so the highest
valuation buyer may delay too long and lose to
another bidder.
25Auctions and Efficiency
- Sealed-bid first-price auction need not be
efficient. No buyer knows other buyers
valuations, so the highest valuation buyer may
bid too low and lose to another bidder.
26Auctions and Efficiency
- Sealed-bid second-price auction is Pareto
efficient even though no buyer knows the other
buyers valuations (more on this later).
27Why Use a Reserve Price?
- Suppose there are 2 buyers.
- The seller believes each buyers valuation is 20
with chance 1/2 and 50 with chance 1/2. - I.e. with chance 1/4 each, the seller believes
she faces buyer valuations (20,20), (20,50),
(50,20) and (50,50).
28Why Use a Reserve Price?
- I.e. with chance 1/4 each, the seller believes
she faces buyer valuations (20,20), (20,50),
(50,20) and (50,50). - Use an English auction.
- Bids must be raised by at least 1.
- With chance 1/4 each, winning bids will be 20,
21, 21 and 50 if there is no reserve price.
29Why Use a Reserve Price?
- With chance 1/4 each, winning bids will be 20,
21, 21 and 50 if there is no reserve price. - Sellers expected revenue is(20 21 21
50)/4 28with no reserve price.
30Why Use a Reserve Price?
- With chance 1/4 each, the seller believes she
faces buyer valuations (20,20), (20,50),
(50,20) and (50,50). - Set a reserve price of 50.
- With chance 1/4 there will be no sale.
- With chance 3/4 the winning bid will be 50.
31Why Use a Reserve Price?
- Set a reserve price of 50.
- With chance 1/4 there will be no sale.
- With chance 3/4 the winning bid will be 50.
- Sellers expected revenue is
32Reserve Price and Efficiency
- The reserve price causes an efficiency loss
since, with chance 1/4, there is no trade.
33Second-Price, Sealed-Bid Auction
- bids are private information
- bids are made simultaneously
- highest bidder wins
- winner pays second-highest bid
- also known as a Vickrey auction.
34Second-Price, Sealed-Bid Auction
- No bidder knows any other bidders true
valuation of the item for sale. - Yet, it is individually rational for each bidder
to state truthfully his own valuation. Why? - E.g. two bidders with true valuations v1 and v2.
35Second-Price, Sealed-Bid Auction
- Suppose object is worth 100 to me.
- Can I do better than to bid 100.
- Two cases
- Highest bid by anyone else gt100
- Highest bid by anyone else lt100
36Case A) Highest bid by anyone else is Greater
than 100.
- Would I gain by bidding more than 100?
- No, because second highest bid would still exceed
100 and object is only worth 100 to me. - Would I gain by bidding less than 100?
- No, because I still wouldnt get the object.
37Case B) Highest bid by anyone else less than
100.
- Would I gain by bidding more than 100?
- No, because I get the object either way at the
second bidders price. - Would I gain by bidding less than 100?
- No. If my bid is between the second highest bid
and 100, I still get object at second bid. If
my changed bid is less than second highest bid, I
dont get the object and miss the profit I would
get from bidding 100
38See you next week
Dont forget to do your homework.