The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 93
About This Presentation
Title:

The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Description:

The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective Avinash K. Dixit MIT Press, 1996 * * * * * Our approach to this question of where policy is ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:203
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 94
Provided by: CarlosP85
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective


1
The Making of Economic Policy A Transaction-Cost
Politics Perspective
  • Avinash K. Dixit
  • MIT Press, 1996

2
Motivation
  • The reality of most countries trade policies is
    so blatantly contrary to all the normative
    prescriptions of the economist that there is no
    way to understand it except by delving into the
    politics.

3
Transaction-Costs
  • In economics, it has come to mean a very general
    class of information, negotiation, and
    enforcement problems that affect the internal
    organization of firms and the outcome of market
    and nonmarket relations among firms, workers and
    so on.
  • A similar and even more severe class of
    transaction costs (which deals with
    principal-agent problems, commitment and
    credibility) pervades political relations and
    affect political outcomes.
  • The policy process can be better understood and
    related to each other by thinking of them as the
    result of various transaction costs and of the
    strategies of the participants to cope with these
    costs.

4
Common Agency
  • Within this general framework, a particularly
    important feature of the political process of
    making economic policy is the common agency,
    where several players in the political game try
    to influence the actions of one decision-maker.
  • It leads to a severe diminution of the power of
    the incentives that can be offered to this
    decision-maker.

5
Market versus Government
  • The tradition dichotomy of market versus
    government, and the question of which system
    perform better, largely lose its relevance.
  • Both of them are facts of the imperfect economic
    life, and they unavoidable interact in complex
    ways.
  • The most we can do is to understand how the
    combined economic-political system evolves
    mechanisms to cope with the variety of
    transaction costs it must face that precludes a
    fully ideal outcome.

6
Principal-Agent Model
7
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Regulatory agency
8
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Firms and Investors
Regulatory agencies
9
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Firms and Investors
Regulatory agency
Consumers
10
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Firms and investors
Regulatory agency
Executive
Consumers
Congress and Committees
11
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Firms and Investors
Regulatory agency
Executive
Consumers
Congress and Committees
12
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Firms and investors
Regulatory agency
Executive
Voters
Consumers
Congress and Committees
13
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Bureaucracy and other agencies
Firms and Investors
Regulatory agencies
Executive
Voters
Congress and Committees
Consumers
14
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Bureaucracy and other agencies
Courts
Firms and Investors
Regulatory Agency
Executive
Voters
Consumers
Congress and Committees
15
The players in the Regulatory Process and their
inter-relations
Bureaucracy and other agencies
Courts
Supreme Court
Firms and Investors
Regulatory agency
Executive
Voters
Consumers
Congress and Committees
16
Set of Principal Agent Models
Supreme Court
Court
Bureaucracy and other agencies
Regulatory Agencies
Executive
Firms and Investors
Voters
Consumers
Interest Groups
Congress and Committees
17
Principal-Agent model
  • It is relevant to analyze relationships with
    following conditions
  • Delegation
  • Asymmetric information
  • Imperfect relation between the effort and its
    results
  • High costs of monitoring
  • No alignment of preferences or objectives

18
Principal-Agent model
  • In general terms, there exist two solutions to
    the principal-agent relation
  • Involves a structure of remuneration aiming at
    approaching the incentives of both parts involved
    (paying a tip).
  • Rules and institutions capable of avoiding
    opportunistic behavior of the agent.

19
Positive versus Normative Political Theory
  • To what extent those theories are excluding,
    complementary, or competitors?
  • Both are based on the premise that agents are
    rational and look for the own interests.
  • Dixit suggests a synthesis, labeled
    transaction-cost politics that views
    policymaking as a process in real time.

20
Normative Political Theory
  • Market failure (i.e. natural monopoly)
  • Requires a criterion to fix with the best way
    this failure aiming at maximizing the social
    welfare.
  • Pareto-optimality (efficiency criterion)
  • First-best and second-best solutions (overcome
    the market imperfections)
  • Moral hazard (level of effort of the firm)
  • Adverse selection (the regulator has no complete
    information about the costs of the firm)
  • The regulator is obliged to pay informational
    rents.

21
Normative Political Theory
  • As a consequence of asymmetric information
    Laffont and Tirole offer as a solution a menu of
    contract
  • Price-caps
  • Repartition of profits
  • Thus, the firm would have incentives to revel its
    true effort

22
Normative Political Theory
  • The normative solution is rarely observed in the
    real life
  • The normative solution requires a high level of
    discretion of the regulator. This generates
    incentives for opportunistic behavior
  • Dixit (1996) observes that the normative theory
    understand the formulation and implementation of
    policies as a technical or organizational
    problems. As if political failures could be
    avoided through good management, namely, giving
    power to make and implement economic policy to an
    economist
  • In other words, it does not take into account
    political and economic institutions.
  • The benevolent, omnipotent, and omniscient
    dictator would maximize the social welfare.

23
Positive and Normative Political theory
  • Dixit 1996
  • Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-best literature
24
Positive and Normative Political theory
  • Dixit 1996
  • Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-best literature
Informational Economics literature
25
Positive and Normative Political theory
  • Dixit 1996
  • Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-best literature
Informational Economics literature
PPTR tries to relax this unrealistic premises
26
Positive and Normative Political theory
  • Dixit 1996
  • Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-best literature
Informational Economics literature
Economic relations Usually involves Multiple
principals
27
Positive and Normative Political theory
  • Dixit 1996
  • Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-best literature
Informational Economics literature
Economic agents, Including regulatory
agencies, Bureaucracy, and government are made by
people that try to Maximize their own interests
28
Positive Theory
  • Also starts from a market failure
  • Regulation necessarily leads to a redistribution.
    Rarely there are Pareto-optimum corrections or
    ways of implementing compensations
    (side-payments)
  • Given the behavioral premises, individuals and
    groups would try to influence this
    redistribution.
  • Their capacity to do so would depend on the
    institutions (i.e. property rights)

29
Positive Theory
  • Many situations apparently inefficient could be
    understood as a consequence of restrictions
    imposed by transaction costs among agents. The
    great majority of the PPTR tries to explain why
    such inefficient situations are observed even
    when there are obvious and better ways to deal
    with that. This involves to identify the source
    of restriction which are generating transaction
    costs and to show how it affects the agent
    choices. Almost always it requires to take into
    account the political institutions.

30
Why does the regulation (government intervention)
tend to be inefficient?
  • Economic reasons
  • Asymmetric information
  • Uncertainty about effects, costs, and benefits
  • It does not mean that the regulation is not
    necessary however, those problems should be
    taken into account

31
Why does the regulation (government intervention)
tend to be inefficient?
  • Political reasons
  • Regulation necessarily means income
    redistribution
  • Quotas, licenses, subsides, establish a price,
    etc. transfer rents and incomes
  • Interest-groups will demand this redistributions
    and politicians offer
  • Generally, the regulation tends to be inefficient
  • Rent-seeking
  • Few beneficiaries and lots of opponents

32
A Synthesis A Policy Process in Real Time
  • Constitutions are incomplete contracts
  • The constitution never lays down the clear, firm,
    and comprehensive set of rules that the
    contractarian approach depicts so there is room
    for maneuver in individual acts.
  • Inability to foresee all the possible
    contingencies and to adjust to them
  • Last longer than most business relationships
  • Constitutions are not made behind a veil of
    ignorance

33
Coases Theorem
  • Once the property rights over a disputed resource
    (ex. Rents of a monopoly) have been established,
    and given that the transaction costs are equal to
    zero, the private negotiations between agents
    approaches to the efficient level of allocation.
    (Coase, Ronald, (1960) The problem of social
    cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1-44).

34
Example
  • A firm pollutes a river which provides a cost of
    500 to a farmer along the river.

35
Example
  • A firm pollutes a river which provides a cost of
    500 to a farmer along the river.
  • It costs 300 to the farmer to build a station to
    purify the water.

36
Example
  • A firm pollutes a river which provides a cost of
    500 to a farmer along the river.
  • If costs 300 to the farmer to build a station to
    purify the water.
  • The firm can eliminate the harmful effect of
    pollution changing its production process at the
    cost of 100.

37
Questions
  • Should be allowed the firm to pollute the river?
  • Should the firm be obliged to change its
    production process?
  • Who should pay for that?
  • What are the economic implications if the firm
    would have the property rights of polluting and
    the farmer would have to compensate him in order
    to not pollute?

38
Example
  • And, if the property rights belong to the farmer?

39
The Coases Theorem
  • Coase argues that, for the economic efficiency
    point of view, the result would be the same
    regardless the of the property rights given that
    the transaction costs are null.

40
Numeric Example I
  • Cost of pollution over the farmer 500
  • Cost of cleaning from the farmer 300
  • Cost of cleaning from the firm 100
  • Case I
  • The farmer has the property rights.
  • The firm will pay for the right to pollute, It
    pays 100 at maximum
  • The farmer would accept more than 300 only since
    he/she would have to clean the water in order to
    avoid the cost of 500
  • Thus, the is no agreement and the firm purifies
    the water itself.

41
Numeric Example I
  • Cost of pollution over the farmer 500
  • Cost of cleaning from the farmer 300
  • Cost of cleaning from the firm 100
  • Case II
  • The firm has the property rights.
  • The farmer will pay for the firm to not pollute.
    It pays 300 at maximum
  • The farmer would accept to pay no more than 100
    since he/she could clean the water at this price.
  • Thus, the farmer pays between 100 and 300 and
    the firm purifies the water itself.

42
The solution is the same in both cases
  • The solution is economically efficient

43
Efficiency vs. Equity
  • Although the reached solution are not affected by
    the property rights the distribution between the
    parts involved would be.

44
Efficiency vs. Equity
  • When the property rights belong to the farmer,
    the firm has a cost of 100.

45
Efficiency vs. Equity
  • However, when the property rights belong to the
    firm, the farmer pays at least 100 and part of
    the exceeding of 200. This rent of 200 will
    be allocated by negotiations between the parts.

46
What is the fairest solution?
  • Coase recommends that we should not conclude too
    fast.
  • He calls our attention to the reciprocal nature
    of the problem.

47
Graphic Example.
MB for the firm to pollute
MC of the pollution over the farmer
c
a
d
b
?3
?
?1
?2
48
If the firm has PR it pollutes until ?3. The
farmer can convince the firm to pollute until ?2
offering more of d. The farmer would thus win
cd.
MB for the firm to pollute
MC of the pollution over the farmer
c
a
d
b
?3
?
?1
?2
49
If the farmer has the PR he/she prefers ?1 (if
there is no negotiation). The firm can compensate
the farmer to pollute at ?2 offering more of
b.
MB for the firm to pollute
MC of the pollution over the farmer
c
a
d
b
?3
?
?1
?2
50
Necessary conditions to reach the negotiated
result
  • Well defined property rights. It implies
    political and judicial institutions that work
    well.
  • Low transaction costs
  • Information about all costs of each possible
    result for each part involved.

51
Polemic Implications of the Coases Theorem
  • In many cases there are no necessity of
    governmental interventions in order to solve
    problems of externalities since the private
    negotiations reach the economically efficient
    solution.

52
Limitations of the Coases Theorem
  • The transactional costs usually are not small,
    especially when several players are involved.
  • There exist public and private externalities. In
    the public ones there are the free-ridding
    problem.
  • There exist the problem of inter-temporal
    transactions with future generations.
  • The initial distribution of the property rights
    can affect the capacity of negotiation of each
    part.
  • Even when the theorem fits there are room for
    government role.

53
Role of the government is to help greasing the
private negotiation
  • Property rights have to be well defined and
    allocated clearly.
  • The government has to monitor the environment
    aiming at identifying who are the polluters and
    who are victims of the pollution. This
    information has to be publicized for all parts
    that have been affected.
  • The government must establish, quantify, and
    publicize the legal rules that regulates the
    environment in order to make it easier the
    private negotiations.
  • Access to the judicial system has to be
    facilitated and cheap

54
Regulation and the Coases Theorem
  • As in practical terms those conditions are rarely
    found, the coases solution is not viable (this
    is exactly what Coase claims!)
  • Therefore, the regulation becomes necessary.
  • The transactions costs are the key. Whose are the
    political property rights? What are the political
    transaction costs?
  • The results usually are not efficient

55
Regulation and the Coasee Theorem
  • Reasons why it is difficult to make side
    payments
  • Informational problems, uncertainty, difficulties
    of measuring costs and benefits
  • Collective action problems
  • Inexistence of a market of political property
    rights (political risks)

56
Delegating Powers
  • A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policy
    making under Separate Powers

David Epstein Sharyn OHalloran
57
(No Transcript)
58
Puzzle
  • Why does Congress delegate broad authority to the
    executive in some policy areas but not in others?
  • Can Congress perfectly control delegated
    authority through administrative procedures,
    oversight, and administrative law?

59
Question
  • When does Congress specify the details of policy
    in legislation, and when does it leave these
    details to regulatory agencies?
  • What are the implications of this institutional
    choice for policy outcomes?
  • Basic question of policy making in a
    separation of powers system.

60
Transaction Cost Politics
  • Policy can be made (i) in Congress, (ii) through
    delegation authority to the executive agencies,
    or a (iii) mixture of these two.
  • When deciding where policy will be made, Congress
    trades off the internal policy production costs
    of the committee system against the external
    costs of delegation
  • (make-or-buy decision).

61
Theory
  • A policy will be made in the politically most
    efficient manner that is, maximizing
    legislators political goal reelection.
  • Legislators will prefer to make policy themselves
    as long as the political benefits they derive
    from doing so outweighs the political costs
    otherwise, they will delegate to the executive

62
Abdication versus delegation?
  • Implications
  • To what extent can Congress control unelected
    regulatory agencies when delegating authority?
  • Lowi (1969)
  • Congress has surrendered their legislative
    authority to bureaucrats
  • MCNOLGAST (1987, 1989)
  • Legislators can control bureaucrats through
    oversight, administrative procedures and
    enfranchising third parties into the
    decision-making process.

63
Authors Claim
  • A theory of oversight divorced from a theory of
    delegation will overlook the fact that those
    issue areas in which the executive makes policy
    differ from those in which Congress makes policy
    itself.

64
Legislative organization and delegation
  • Distributive versus informational theories
  • This is a false dichotomy (whether committee
    serves pork barrel projects or legislators
    desire to avoid the consequences of ill-informed
    policies)
  • Some policy areas are more characterized by
    informational concerns and other by distributive.
    The first ones tend to be delegated and the
    second tend to be made in Congress

65
Divided Government and Delegation
  • To what extend will an opposing Congress delegate
    more powers to the executive?
  • Mayhew (1991) the same number of legislation get
    passed under unified and divided government. It
    doesn't lead to gridlock.
  • However, the authors call our attention to the
    quality of bills passed
  • Congress delegate less and constrains more under
    divided government procedural gridlock, that is,
    producing executive branch agencies with less
    authority to make policy and increase oversight
    from congressional committees.

66
What does Transaction Cost mean?
  • Anything that makes reality deviate from this
    Coasian world
  • anything that impedes the specification,
    monitoring, or enforcement of an economic
    transaction is a transaction cost (Dixit 1966).

67
Common elements of the Transaction Costs analysis
  • The contract is the unit of analysis
  • The contracts are enforceable by some neutral
    third-party
  • Assumes the existence of multiple governance
    structures
  • Economic actors are assumed to be boundedly
    rational (agents cannot eliminate transaction
    costs by simply contracting)
  • Holdup problems
  • Contracts are incomplete and ambiguous

68
Theory of Transaction Cost politics
  • Delegation to a bureaucracy is subjected to the
    political equivalent of a holdup problem so
    Congress will delegate to the executive when the
    external transaction costs of doing so are less
    than the internal transaction costs of making
    policy through the normal legislative process of
    the committees.

69
Reasons not to delegate
  • With transaction costs equal to zero Congress
    might like to delegate broad discretionary
    authorities and agencies might like to receive
    such authority (please everyone). However,
  • Difficult to control and monitoring
  • Incomplete contracts
  • Uncertainty of future opportunistic behavior
  • Impossibility of binding the actions of agency
    successors

70
Reasons to delegate
  • Save time/Reduce congress workload
  • Take advantage of agency expertise
  • Protect special interests
  • Blame-shifting (avoiding the inefficiencies of
    committee system)
  • Delays, logrolling, informational inefficiencies,
    etc.
  • These do not explain why delegate in some
    policy areas rather than others.

71
Neither alternative is perfect
  • However, in some specific cases delegate or not
    (how mach delegate) would be relatively more
    attractive than from the median legislators
    preference.

72
Basic Assumptions
  • Two alternative modes of policy making
  • Congress
  • Committee System
  • Regulatory Agencies
  • Delegation to Executive
  • Legislators decide where policy is made.
  • Legislators primary goal is reelection
  • Authority will be allocated across the branches
    in a politically efficient manner

73
Division of Labor
  • Each alternative mode of policy making has its
    own set of inefficiencies
  • Legislative Policy Making (Committees)
  • Logrolling, delay, informational problems
  • Agency Policy Making (Delegation)
  • Principal-agent problems of oversight
  • So when deciding where policy will be made,
    legislators trade off these internal and external
    inefficiencies.

74
Make-or-Buy
  • Congresss decision to delegate is like a firms
    make-or-buy decision.
  • Legislators can either produce policy internally,
  • OR
  • Legislators can subcontract out (delegate) to the
    executive.

75
Discretion Continuum
D
Legislative Policymaking
Agency Policymaking
High Discretion
Low Discretion
76
Discretion Continuum
D
Legislative Policymaking
Agency Policymaking
High Discretion
Low Discretion
Trade Off
77
Discretion Continuum
D
Legislative Policymaking
Agency Policymaking
High Discretion
Low Discretion
Trade Off
  • Amount of discretion delegated to the executive
    balances these costs at the margin.

78
The formal decision to delegate
  1. The legislation (bill) is the unit of analysis
  2. There exist enforceable mechanisms for
    inter-branch contracts
  3. Multiple possible governance structures
  4. Bounded-rationality
  5. Holdup problem
  6. Internal transaction cost of production
  7. A decision mechanisms predicting which governance
    structure will be chosen

79
Model Elements
  • Actors Floor, Comm., Pres., Agency
  • Policy space X ?1, status quo x00
  • Preferences (x-xi)2 xF0, xPgt0
  • Implies that all actors will be risk averse
  • Outcomes x p ? , ? U-R,R
  • Agencies have perfect information of ?
  • Committees only know sign of ?
  • Floor knows ex ante distribution of ?

80
Model
  • Players
  • Median floor voter in Congress (F)
  • Congressional Committee (C)
  • President (P)
  • Agency (A)
  • One-dimension policy single-pick preferences,
    median voter (pivotal)
  • Each player has a most-preferable policy or ideal
    point and are risk-averse (dislike uncertainty)
  • Policy outcomes are not necessarily the same as
    the policies that emerged from the policymaking
    process.
  • That is, X p ?

81
Model
  • The players start the game with probabilistic
    beliefs about the value of ?.
  • These beliefs are uniform in some interval -R,
    R.
  • During the game, players will try to gather more
    information (expertise) about the exact value of ?

82
Game Tree
F
l
o
o
r

s
e
t
s

p
o
l
i
c
y

p
F
x

p

?
F
F
D
o
n
'
t

D
e
l
e
g
a
t
e
C
o
m
m
i
t
t
e
e

l
e
a
r
n
s

?
gt
0

o
r

?
lt
0
,

?
r
e
p
o
r
t
s

b
i
l
l

(
b
)
N
F
C
D
e
l
e
g
a
t
e
x

S
Q

p

?
A
F
A
g
e
n
c
y

l
e
a
r
n
s

F
l
o
o
r

s
e
t
s

P
r
e
s
i
d
e
n
t

s
e
t
s

e
x
a
c
t

v
a
l
u
e

o
f

?
?


d
i
s
c
r
e
t
i
o
n

(
d
)
,


A
g
e
n
c
y

i
d
e
a
l

s
t
a
t
u
s

q
u
o

(
S
Q
)
p
o
i
n
t

x

s
e
t
s

p
o
l
i
c
y

p
A
s
.
t
.

A


F
i
n
a
l

I
n
s
t
i
t
u
t
i
o
n
a
l

C
h
o
i
c
e
P
o
l
i
c
y

M
a
k
i
n
g

P
r
o
c
e
s
s
O
u
t
c
o
m
e
s
83
Sequential Signaling game
  • Institutional choice
  • While the agency observes the exact value of ?,
    the committee observes only whether ? lies in the
    interval range -R, 0 or the range 0. R that
    is, the committee sees only the sign of ?.
  • Policy-making Process
  • Choice of buying or making the policy.
  • Final outcome
  • Committee X p ?
  • Agency X SQ pa ?

84
Solving the Game
  • Agency sets policy as close to its ideal point as
    possible, given limits on discretion.
  • President sets Agencys ideal point to equal her
    own xAxP.
  • Congress sets status quo and discretion
  • Set SQ to get its ideal point in expectation,
    given beliefs about ?
  • Set discretion dR-xP.

85
Theoretical Propositions
  • In equilibrium, Congress will delegate more
    discretionary authority to the executive
  • 1. The lower the level of congressional-
    executive conflict
  • 2. The higher the level of committee-floor
    conflict
  • 3. The higher the level of uncertainty in the
    policy environment.

86
Deliberate Discretion?
  • The Institutional Foundation of Bureaucratic
    Autonomy

John Huber Charles Shipan
87
What this book is about?
  • How elected officials use the statutes to
    establish policy details in effort to achieve
    desired outcomes.
  • Develop and test a theory of delegation that
    explains the choice of how to delegate aiming at
    understanding how institutional context affects
    delegation strategies.

88
Two types of designing statutes
  1. To write long statutes with extremely detailed
    languages in a effort to micromanage the
    policymaking process.
  2. To write vague statutes that have many details
    unspecified, thereby delegating policymaking
    authority to other actors, usually bureaucrats.

89
Vague (Germany) versus specific (Ireland)
statutes about sexual harassment
  • Why has the same policy issue been treated
    differently by politicians in distinct political
    systems?
  • Why these choice matter?
  • Is the transferred discretion a deliberate
    choice?

90
Delegation as double-edge sword
  • the central reason for granting policymaking
    autonomy to bureaucrats their technical
    expertise also creates a big problem, as
    bureaucrats can use their knowledge against
    politicians. Bureaucratic expertise is thus a
    double-edge sword, creating both the incentive
    for legislatures to give policymaking power to
    bureaucrats and the opportunity for these
    bureaucrats to act counter to legislative
    preferences (Peters 1981)

91
Two prevalent views
  • Bureaucratic discretion (bureaucratic dominance)
  • versus
  • Deliberate discretion (politicians dominance.
    That is, politicians would have capacity to
    control bureaucrats and achieve their goals by
    delegating)

92
Alternative view
  • Rather than asking to what extent politicians
    control bureaucrats, the authors assume that in
    any political context there typically exists a
    politician who has greater opportunities than
    other political actors to influence bureaucratic
    behavior.
  • In parliamentary democracy Cabinet
  • In presidential system president or governors

93
4 factors that affect politicians incentives to
micromanage policymaking
  1. Level of political conflict between politicians
    who adopt the statute and bureaucrats who
    implement them
  2. The capacity of politicians to write detailed
    statutes
  3. The bargaining environment (e.g. the existence of
    vetoes or bicameral conflicts) in which the
    statutes are adopted
  4. The politicians expectation about non-statutory
    factors such as the role of courts or legislative
    oversight.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com