Title: CHAPTER 16: CAPITAL STRUCTURE
1CHAPTER 16 CAPITAL STRUCTURE BASIC CONCEPTS
- Topics
- 16.1-16.2 The Basics
- 16.3-16.4 Capital Structure in Perfect Markets
- Modigliani and Miller Proposition I (No Taxes)
- Modigliani and Miller Proposition II (No Taxes)
2Nobel Price Winners in your Textbook
- Harry Markowitz (1990)
- William Sharpe (1990)
- CAPM
- Merton Miller (1990)
- Franco Modigliani (1985)
- Capital structure
- To come
- Myron Scholes (1997)
- Robert Merton (1997)
- Option pricing
316.1 The Definition
- What is capital structure?
- The pie
- Two Questions in Capital Structure
- What happens to the cost of various sources of
funds when the capital structure is changed? - Is there an optimal capital structure?
Firm value V B (market value of debt) S
(market value of equity) A capital structure
ratio Debt-equity ratio B/S
4Cost of Equity Capital Review
- CAPM Cost of equity rS rf ß E(rM) - rf
- ß Cov(rs,, rM) / Var(rM)
- Other sources of funds what if there is
leverage? - Cost of debt rB expected return on firms
debt, i.e., the rate of interest paid - The weighted average cost of capital (WACC) is
given by - Note that for now we ignore the tax deductibility
of interest payments - Read over chapters 11 and 13 to review these
concepts
516.2 Management objective revisited
- Objective of management Maximizing S
- However, as long as there is no costs of
bankruptcy, maximizing S is equivalent to
maximizing V - An example Firm has 10,000 shares. Share price
25. Debt has a market value of 100,000. - V B S 100,000 10,000 25 350,000
- Now suppose firm borrows another 50,000 and pays
it immediately as a special dividend. - B 100,000 50,000 150,000
- What would be shareholder gain/loss if firm value
changes?
6Example contd
Consider Three Possibilities
V increases to 380,000 V stays constant at 350,000 V decreases to 320,000
S 170,000
Shareholder gain from dividend 50,000 50,000 50,000
Capital loss -80,000
Net gain/loss to shareholders -30,000
- Changes in capital structure benefit the
stockholders if and only if the value of the firm
increases. - Managers should choose the capital structure that
they believe will have the highest firm value (to
make the pie as big as possible).
7What is the optimal capital structure, if any,
that maximizes firm value?
- Assume Perfect Capital Markets (PCM)
- Information is free and available to everyone on
an equal basis. - No transaction costs
- No taxes
- No costs of bankruptcy
- Firms and investors can borrow / lend at the same
rate - MM Proposition I (no taxes) The market value of
any firm is independent of its capital structure.
- Let VU be the value of an unlevered firm (i.e.,
all equity financing), and VL be the value of an
otherwise identical levered firm (i.e. some
debt financing) VL VU.
816.3 Proof of MM Proposition I (No taxes) VL
VU
- Assume that all cash flows are perpetuities (just
to make the calculations easier). Let X be the
identical cash flow stream generated by each firm
(i.e. U and L) VU SU be the value of the
unlevered firm, and VL SL BL be the value of
the levered firm. - Consider an investor who owns some fraction a
(e.g. 5) of the shares of U - This investor can get the same return by
investing in L - If Vu gt VL the investor would not buy any shares
in U since the same return is available on a
similar investment in L
9Proof contd
- Consider an investor who owns a of Ls equity
- This investor can get the same return by
investing in U and borrowing on personal account - If VL gt VU the investor would not buy any shares
in L since the same return is available on a
smaller investment in U
10Proof contd
- We have shown that no one would buy shares in U
if VU gt VL and that no one would buy shares if VL
gt VU - Therefore VU VL is the only solution consistent
with market equilibrium - The same arguments apply to more complicated
capital structures - The same arguments apply if cash flows are not
perpetuities and/or not constant.
11Some observations
- MMs result is based on a no-arbitrage argument
if two investments give the same future returns,
they must cost the same today - A key (implicit) assumption is that individuals
can borrow as cheaply as corporations - One way to do this is through buying stock on
margin - With a margin purchase, the broker lends the
investor a portion of the cost (e.g., to buy
10,000 of stock on 40 margin, put up 6,000 of
your own money and borrow 4,000 from the broker) - Since the broker holds the stock as collateral,
brokers generally charge relatively low rates of
interest - Firms, on the other hand, often borrow using
illiquid assets as collateral (and get charged
higher rates)
12Example 1
- Given VU 100m, X 10m, r 5, BL 50m,
then MM Proposition I implies SL 50M - Suppose SL 40m
- Suppose SL 60M
13Example 2 Uncertain cash flows
Consider an all-equity firm, Trans Can, that is
considering going into debt. (Maybe some of the
original shareholders want to cash out.)
- Current
- Assets 8,000
- Debt 0
- Equity 8,000
- Debt/Equity ratio 0
- Interest rate n/a
- Shares outstanding 400
- Share price 20
Proposed (50 debt) 8,000 4,
000 4,000 1 10 200 20
14Example 2 contd Unlevered ROE
- Current Shares Outstanding 400 shares
- Recession Expansion Expected
- Probability 0.5 0.5
- EBI 400 2,000 1,200
- Interest 0 0 0
- Net income 400 2,000 1,200
- EPS 1.00 5.00
- ROE 5 25
15Example 2 contd Levered ROE
- Proposed Shares Outstanding 200 shares
- Recession Expansion Expected
- Probability 0.5 0.5
- EBI 400 2,000 1,200
- Interest (400) (400) (400)
- Net income 0 1,600 800
- EPS 0 8 4
- ROE 0 40 20
16Example 2 contd
- Since the expected ROE is higher under 50 debt,
should the firm switch to this capital structure? - Not only have expected returns increased, but so
has risk - The MM argument is that it doesnt matter,
because investors can effectively create the
payoffs from the alternative capital structure
themselves (homemade leverage)
17Example 2 contd Replicate the higher EPS with
only an unlevered firm and borrowing homemade
leverage
- Assume that you buy 200 shares of unlevered firm
using 2,000 of your own money and borrowing the
rest 2,000 at 10 on margin from your broker. - Recession Expansion Expected
- EPS of Unlevered Firm 1 5 3
- Earnings for 200 shares 600
- Less interest on 2000 (200)
- Net Profits 400
- ROE (Net Profits / 2,000) 20
- Same ROE as if we bought into a levered firm!
Whats the trick? - Our personal debt equity ratio (personal
leverage) is the same as the levered equity - Personal Debt contribution/equity contribution
18Example 2 contd Law of One Price
- Lets call the portfolio in previous slide
Strategy A. Suppose the investor engages in the
following alternate investment strategy
(Strategy A) with levered firm only - Buy 100 shares of levered firm. Also 50 of
equity ownership. Initial cost 20100 2,000. - Recession Expansion Expected
- EPS of Levered Firm 0 8 4
- Earnings for 100 shares 0 800 400
- ROE (Net Profits / 2,000) 0 40 20
- Same initial investment same ROE in every
scenario - Value of strategy A must equal value of strategy
B (Law of one price). - Or
19How is no-arbitrage principle used in proving MM?
- Arbitrage opportunity, in principle, allows you
to - have non-negative profit in every state of the
world with an initial investment of 0. - Well show that if VL ? VU there exists an
arbitrage opportunity. - By Law of One Price the arbitrage opportunity
will disappear instantaneously. - Suppose instead PL21, so that SL 4,200 and VL
8,200 gt VU
20No arbitrage contd
- What to do?
- Buy low and sell high
- We consider a simple occasion where buy and sell
involve same percentage of equity - Borrow or lend to make initial investment be zero
- Synthetic strategy
- (1) Buy low buy 50 of Us equity, costs 200
shares 20 4,000 - (2) Sell high (short) sell 50 of Ls equity,
proceeds 100 shares 21 2,100 - (3) Zero initial investment borrow 1,900 at
10. - Whats my payoff?
21No arbitrage contd
- Cashflow (dividend income)
- Recession Expansion Expected
- Buy 50 of U (200 sh.) 200 1000 600
- Short 50 of L (100 sh.) (400)
- Borrow 1,900 at 10 (190)
- Net Profits 10
- ROE (Net Profits /0) 8
- At time T, you clear your position by reversing
(1) (2) (3) in the previous slide and receive 0
back. - I will make in every scenario with zero
initial investment. - But everyone else can do it
22How does leverage affect shareholder returns?
- Note that from previous example that leverage
increases the expected return and risk of equity,
even if there is no chance of bankruptcy - Recall the weighted average cost of capital
formula - MM proposition I implies that the WACC is
constant (i.e., independent of capital structure) - In the previous example
2316.4 MM Proposition II Cost of equity
- Define
- Since r0 rWACC , we have
- This can be re-arranged to yield MM Proposition
II - Leverage increases the risk and return to
stockholders
24The Cost of Equity, the Cost of Debt, and the
Weighted Average Cost of Capital MM Proposition
II with No Corporate Taxes
Cost of capital r ()
r0
rB
rB
Debt-to-equity Ratio
25Example 2 contd
- Cost of equity of unlevered firm
- r0 expected earnings to unlevered
firm/unlevered equity - 1200/8000 15
- rs
- Is this right
26- Assigned Problems 16.2, 3, 4, 6, 8, 10, 11