Title: Econ 522 Economics of Law
1Econ 522Economics of Law
Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 12
2Logistics
- Midterm will be returned at end of lecture
- HW2 is online, due in two weeks (Wed Mar 17)
- Second midterm Wed Mar 24
- Cumulative, through end of contract law
3Last time
- Default rules
- Why are gaps left in contracts?
- What rules should be applied to fill those gaps?
- CU use terms most parties would have chosen
(efficient terms) - Ayres and Gertner under some conditions, use
default rules which penalize one or both parties
for concealing information - Regulations
- Example derogation of public policy
- Ways to get out of a contract
- Formation defenses (no contract exists)
- Performance excuses (circumstances have
changed) - One formation defense incompetence (but not
drunkenness)
4Another formation defensedire constraints
5Dire constraints
- Necessity
- Im about to starve, someone offers me a sandwich
for 10,000 - My boats about to sink, someone offers me a ride
to shore for 1,000,000 - Contract would not be upheld I signed it out of
necessity - Duress
- Other party is responsible for situation Im in
- Someone makes me an offer I cant refuse
6Friedman on duress
- Example
- Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him
100 - You write him a check
- Do you have to honor the agreement?
- Efficiency requires enforcing a contract if both
parties wanted it to be enforceable - He did he wants your 100
- You did youd rather pay 100 than be killed
- So why not enforce it?
- Makes muggings more profitable ? leads to more
muggings - Tradeoff dont enforce Pareto-improving trade,
in order to avoid incentive for bad behavior
7Friedman on duress
- Example
- Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him
100 - You write him a check
- Do you have to honor the agreement?
- Efficiency requires enforcing a contract if both
parties wanted it to be enforceable - He did he wants your 100
- You did youd rather pay 100 than be killed
- So why not enforce it?
- Makes muggings more profitable ? leads to more
muggings - Tradeoff dont enforce Pareto-improving trade,
in order to avoid incentive for bad behavior
8What about necessity?
- Same logic doesnt work for necessity
- You get caught in a storm on your 10,000,000
sailboat - Tugboat offers to tow you to shore for 9,000,000
- (Otherwise hell save your life but let your boat
sink) - Duress if we enforce contract, incentive for
more crimes - Here if we enforce contract, incentive for more
tugboats to be available for rescues how is
that bad? - Social benefit of rescue value of boat, minus
cost of tow - Say, 10,000,000 10,000 9,990,000
- If tugboat gets entire value, his private gain
social gain - So tugboat captain would invest the efficient
amount in being available to rescue you - So whats the problem?
9What about necessity?
- What about your decision whether to sail that
day - 1 in 1000 chance of being caught in a storm
- If so, 1 in 2 that a tugboat will rescue you
- Private cost of sailing 1 in 2000 you lose boat,
1 in 2000 you pay tugboat captain value of boat - 10,000,000/2000 10,000,000/2000 10,000
- So youll choose to sail if your value is above
10,000 - Social cost 1 in 2000 boat is lost, 1 in 2000
boat is rescued - 10,000,000/2000 10,000/2000 5,005
- Efficient to sail when your value is above 5,005
- When your value from sailing is between 5,005
and 10,000, you undersail - If the price of being towed was just the marginal
cost, you would sail the efficient amount
10Friedmans point
- Same transaction sets incentives on both parties
- Price that would be efficient for one decision,
is inefficient for other - Put the incentive where it would do the most
good - Least inefficient price is somewhere in the
middle - And probably not the price that would be
negotiated in the middle of a storm!
11Friedmans point
- Same transaction sets incentives on both parties
- Price that would be efficient for one decision,
is inefficient for other - Put the incentive where it would do the most
good - Least inefficient price is somewhere in the
middle - And probably not the price that would be
negotiated in the middle of a storm! - So makes sense for courts to overturn contracts
signed under necessity, replace them with ex-ante
optimal terms
12More general point
- Single price can create multiple incentives
- Often impossible to set them all efficiently
- Already saw this with remedy for breach
- Expectation damages efficient breach, but
inefficient signing - Include gains from reliance overreliance
- Exclude gains from reliance inefficient breach
13Real duress versus fake duress
- Court wont enforce contracts signed under threat
of harm - Give me 100 or Ill shoot you
- But many negotiations contain threats
- Give me a raise, or Ill quit
- 3,000 is my final offer for the car, take it or
I walk - The difference?
- Threat of destruction of value versus failure to
create value - A promise is enforceable if extracted as price of
cooperating in creating value not if it was
extracted by threat to destroy value
14Example
- Alaska Packers Association v Domenico (US Ct App
1902) - Captain hires crew in Seattle for fishing
expedition to Alaska - In Alaska, crew demands higher wages or theyll
quit - Captain agrees
- Back in Seattle, refuses higher wages, claiming
duress
15A performance excuseimpossibility
16Next doctrine for voiding a contract
impossibility
- When performance becomes impossible, should
promisor owe damages, or be excused from
performing? - A perfect contract would explicitly state who
bears each risk - Contract may give clues as to how gaps should be
filled - Industry custom might be clear
- But in some cases, court must fill gap
17Next doctrine for voiding a contract
impossibility
- In most situations, when neither contract nor
industry norm offers guidance, promisor is held
liable for breach - But there are exceptions
- Change destroyed a basic assumption on which the
contract was made
18Next doctrine for voiding a contract
impossibility
- In most situations, when neither contract nor
industry norm offers guidance, promisor is held
liable for breach - But there are exceptions
- Change destroyed a basic assumption on which the
contract was made - Efficiency requires assigning liability to the
party that can bear the risk at least cost - Party that can take precautions to minimize the
risk - Or can best spread the risk over many transactions
19Important general concept
- Who is the efficient bearer of a particular risk?
- Also called low-cost avoider
- Who is in best position to mitigate/reduce a
risk, or hedge it, or endure it? - We already saw this question with efficient
default rules - When a contract leaves a gap, an efficient
contract would have allocated each risk to
low-cost avoider - Construction company building a house, completion
is delayed - Family might be efficient risk-bearer, because
its cheaper for them to stay with friends than
for construction company to pay for hotel - Cost of raw materials goes up, increasing cost of
construction - Construction company might be efficient
risk-bearer, because they can buy materials early
or change design plans
20Contracts based onbad information
21Misinformation
- Four doctrines for invalidating a contract based
on faulty information - Fraud
- Failure to disclose
- Frustration of purpose
- Mutual mistake
22Fraud and Failure to Disclose
- Fraud violates negative duty not to misinform
- In some circumstances, positive duty to disclose
certain information - Civil law contract may be voided if you did not
supply information you should have (failure to
disclose) - Common law seller is not forced to disclose
everything he knows - Must warn about hidden dangers
- Need not share information that makes product
less valuable but not dangerous - But, new products come with implied warranty of
fitness
23Frustration of Purpose
- Both parties based a contract on the same bad
information ? contract may be voided due to
frustration of purpose - Coronation Cases
- Rooms rented out with view of new kings
coronation parade - Parade was postponed, owners still tried to
collect rent - Courts ruled change in circumstance had
frustrated the purpose of the original contracts,
which were therefore void - When a contingency makes performance pointless,
assign liability to the party who can bear the
risk at least cost
24Mutual Mistake
- Frustration of purpose circumstances changed
after the contract was signed - Mutual mistake circumstances changed before the
contract was signed, but the parties didnt know
about it - Enforcing the contract would be like forcing
involuntary exchange - Coase we expect voluntary exchange to be
efficient - But involuntary exchange may not be
25Another principle knowledge and control
- Hadley v Baxendale (miller and shipper)
- Hadley knew shipment was time-critical
- But Baxendale was deciding how to ship crankshaft
(boat or train) - A general principle about information efficiency
generally requires uniting knowledge and control - Contracts that unite knowledge and control are
generally efficient, should be upheld - Contracts that separate knowledge and control may
be inefficient, should more often be set aside
26Unilateral mistake
- Mutual mistake neither party had correct
information - Contract neither united nor separated knowledge
and control - Unilateral mistake one party has mistaken
information - I know your car is a valuable antique, you think
its worthless - You sell it to me at a low price
- Contracts based on unilateral mistake are
generally upheld
27Unilateral mistake
- Mutual mistake neither party had correct
information - Contract neither united nor separated knowledge
and control - Unilateral mistake one party has mistaken
information - I know your car is a valuable antique, you think
its worthless - You sell it to me at a low price
- Contracts based on unilateral mistake are
generally upheld - Contracts based on unilateral mistake generally
unite knowledge and control - And this creates an incentive to gather
information
28Unilateral mistake Laidlaw v Organ (U.S. Supreme
Court, 1815)
- War of 1812 British blockaded port of New
Orleans - Price of tobacco fell, since it couldnt be
exported - Organ (tobacco buyer) learned the war was over
- Immediately negotiated with Laidlaw firm to buy a
bunch of tobacco at the depressed wartime price - Next day, news broke the war had ended, price of
tobacco went up, Laidlaw sued - Supreme Court ruled that Organ was not required
to communicate his information
29Unilateral mistake productive versus
redistributive information
- Productive information information that can be
used to produce more wealth - Redistributive information information that can
be used to redistribute wealth in favor of
informed party - Cooter and Ulen
- Contracts based on one partys knowledge of
productive information especially if that
knowledge was the result of active investment
should be enforced - Contracts based on one partys knowledge of
purely redistributive information or fortuitously
acquired information should not be enforced
30More on duty to disclose
- Sellers must inform buyers about hidden safety
risks - Common law does not generally require disclosure
of other types of information - But
- Obde v Schlemeyer (1960)
- Seller knew building was infested with termites,
did not tell buyer - Termites should have been exterminated
immediately to prevent further damage - Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose
- Sale did not unite knowledge and control
31More on duty to disclose
- Sellers must inform buyers about hidden safety
risks - Common law does not generally require disclosure
of other types of information - But
- Obde v Schlemeyer (1960)
- Seller knew building was infested with termites,
did not tell buyer - Termites should have been exterminated
immediately to prevent further damage - Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose
- Sale did not unite knowledge and control
- Many states require used car dealers to reveal
major repairs done, sellers of homes to reveal
certain types of defects
32Other reasons a contract may not be enforced
33Vague contract terms
- Courts will generally not enforce contract terms
that are overly vague - Can be thought of as a penalty default
- But some exceptions
- Parties may commit to renegotiating the contract
in good faith under certain contingencies
34Fairness
- Bargain theory courts ask only whether a
contract was part of a bargain, not whether that
bargain was fair - Hamer v Sidway (drinking and smoking)
- But two common law doctrines to get out of
extremely one-sided contracts - Adhesion
- Unconscionability
35Adhesion and unconscionability
- Adhesion standardized take-it-or-leave-it
contracts - Friedman calls it bogus duress
36Adhesion and unconscionability
- Adhesion standardized take-it-or-leave-it
contracts - Friedman calls it bogus duress
- Unconscionability
- Overly one-sided contract may not be enforced
- Terms such that no man in his senses and not
under delusion would make on the one hand, and as
no honest and fair man would accept on the other - When the sum total of its provisions drives too
hard a bargain for a court of conscience to
assist - Terms which would shock the conscience of the
court - Similar concept in civil law lesion
37Unconscionability Williams v Walker-Thomas
Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)
- Unconscionability has generally been recognized
to include an absence of meaningful choice on the
part of one of the parties together with contract
terms which are unreasonably favorable to the
other party. - In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice
is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining
power.
38Unconscionability Williams v Walker-Thomas
Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)
- Unconscionability has generally been recognized
to include an absence of meaningful choice on the
part of one of the parties together with contract
terms which are unreasonably favorable to the
other party. - In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice
is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining
power.
39Unconscionability Williams v Walker-Thomas
Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)
- Unconscionability has generally been recognized
to include an absence of meaningful choice on the
part of one of the parties together with contract
terms which are unreasonably favorable to the
other party. - In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice
is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining
power. - Not normal monopoly cases but situational
monopolies - Think of Ploof v Putnam (sailboat in a storm)
40Midterms
41Midterm
- Overall pretty good
- Mean 82, median 84, std dev 14
- Not actually assigning letter grades till after
final - But to have an approximate idea of where you
stand - 90s roughly AB or A
- 80s roughly B
- 70s roughly BC
- high 50s/60s roughly C
A-H
Q-Z
I-P