Title: Microfinance
1Microfinance
2Overall motivation for microfinance
- Lack of access to financial instruments (savings,
credit) is a key obstacle to poor families
seeking to improve their own lives - Many investments that are good for households'
long-run prospects require large up-front costs - e.g., tuition for education, capitalization of
small enterprises - But it is often difficult to pay such up-front
costs - Savings mechanisms are inefficient or nonexistent
- Credit mechanisms poor
- Microfinance institutions seek to fill this gap,
by bringing financial services to the poor and
previously unserved
3Microfinance common elements
- Focus on providing financial services to those
excluded from the formal banking sector - Most common credit
- More recently savings
- New frontier insurance
- Credit mostly intended to finance self-employment
activities - Provide small loans (as small as 75), to be
repaid over several months to a year - Many dispense with collateral requirements
- Key for poor households with few assets
- How are microfinance lenders able to do this?
4Asymmetric information problems
- Adverse selection individuals who know they are
likely to default select into borrowing pool,
raising default rates and interest rates for
everyone - Hidden type, hidden information
- Moral hazard
- Individuals exert less effort than the lender
would desire, raising default rates and interest
rates for all - Ex-ante less effort is exerted to make the
project succeed - Ex-post even if project succeeds, may
voluntarily default - Hidden action
5Group liability lending
- Widely-publicized mechanism of Grameen Bank for
dispensing with collateral requirements - a.k.a. joint liability
- Idea make everyone in a group of 5 borrowers
jointly liable for repaying each of the loans to
group members - If group doesn't repay each loan, no-one in group
gets subsequent loans - Not the same as group lending
6Group liability in theory
- Why does it work?
- Helps solve asymmetric information problem that
usually exists between lenders and borrowers (and
that is costly for conventional lenders to deal
with) - Adverse selection
- Moral hazard
- Reduces adverse selection
- groups will only form if all have confidence in
individuals' repayment - people generally know each other beforehand,
members will be selected for their reliability
as borrowers - Reduces moral hazard
- creates incentives for within-group monitoring
and enforcement - In the end, key is to reduce transaction costs
for lenders, allowing them to serve borrowers
with very small loans
7Group liability drawbacks
- What drawbacks might group liability have?
- Increases tension among members
- Leads to voluntary dropouts
- Can harm social capital among members
- More costly for clients who are good risks,
because they are more likely to pay off loans of
their peers - Bad clients can free ride off good ones
- Makes it more difficult to attract and retain
good clients - As groups mature, loan sizes typically diverge
- Smaller clients may not want to guarantee larger
loans of other group members - Overall group liabilitys beneficial effect on
repayment may reduce client base (and poors
overall access to finance) - Also bank profitability may be lower
8Gine and Karlan (2006)
- Field experiment in the Philippines
- Microfinance bank where borrowers (all women)
organized into joint-liability groups of 20 - 169 pre-existing centers randomized into
- Treatment converted to individual-liability
centers - Control no change from joint liability
- Findings
- No impact on repayment rate
- Attracts new clients to individual-liability
centers - Caveats
- Groups were still formed under joint liability
(so still benefit from joint structures impact
on adverse selection) - Only moral hazard is affected by experiment
- Next step form groups under individual
liability, and test effects
9Karlan and Zinman (2007) Motivation
- Credit markets thought to be imperfect due to
asymmetric information problems - Adverse selection
- Moral hazard
- Policy responses
- Microlending resolve adverse selection, moral
hazard via joint liability, group lending - Subsidies for lenders if moral hazard, asymmetric
information problems make private sector lending
unprofitable for the poorest sectors - Appropriate policies depend on understanding
extent of these asymmetric information problems
10Karlan and Zinman (2007)
- Goal quantify importance of various information
asymmetries in a credit market - Adverse selection
- Repayment burden
- Moral hazard
- Typically assumed to be unobservable
- Experiment with a consumer lender to the working
poor in South Africa - Randomization used to separately identify these
effects - offer interest rate identifies adverse
selection - contract interest rate identifies repayment
burden - dynamic repayment incentive identifies moral
hazard
11Experimental design
12Findings
- Evidence of moral hazard
- Dynamic repayment incentive has significant
effects on default - No evidence of adverse selection or repayment
burden overall - But analysis by gender reveals
- adverse selection for females
- Repayment burden for males
- See Tables 4, 5
13Table 4
14Table 5
15Discussion items
- Why is it important for loan supply decision to
be blind to the experimental offer rates? - And was it, in fact?
- Why present results for the standardized index of
three default measures? (Kling, Liebman, and Katz
2007) - Ditto the seemingly unrelated regression (SUR)
- How to interpret results by gender?
16Savings
17The role of savings
- Transform a series of small payments into a
usably large lump sum (Rutherford 1999) - For investment
- As buffer stock (self-insurance)
- Less costly than credit no need to pay for
lenders risk
18Barriers to savings
- Problems with self-discipline
- While understanding the need to save for the
future, individuals cant resist the temptation
to spend now -
- Strong social pressures to share accumulated
assets with others who have immediate needs - Reflective of informal insurance/risk-sharing
arrangements - High transactional or informational costs
- Distance to branches, unfamiliarity with formal
financial institutions, difficulty filling out
forms, etc. - A barrier to formal savings
19Informal savings
- In the absence of formal savings mechanisms,
households in poor countries have developed a
variety of informal means to save - Cash savings at home
- But vulnerable to temptation, theft, and pressure
to share with others - Asset accumulation and decumulation
- E.g., livestock
- Czukas, Fafchamps and Udry (1998)
- Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1993)
- But this comes at an efficiency cost
- ROSCAs
- but some innovative MFIs are starting to offer
formal savings
20SafeSave
- Helping overcome transactional cost barriers to
savings - New program in Dhaka, Bangladesh
- Deposit collectors visit people in their homes
- Clients may deposit as little as one taka
(0.015) when the collector calls at their house
each day - Accounts with balances above 1,000 taka (15)
earn 6 interest. - Clients may withdraw up to 500 taka per
day (7.50) at their doorstep, or up to 5,000
taka per day (75) at the branch office - 22,000 clients, with average savings balance of
22
Source http//www.safesave.org/
21Commitment savings
- Do people need help with self-control, with
committing to savings? - Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin (2006), Tying Odysseus
to the Mast - Randomized offer of commitment savings product to
customers of a rural bank in Philippines - Customers pre-commit to save a certain amount or
for a certain time period before withdrawal - Withdrawals not allowed before pre-committed
amount or time period, except for emergencies
22Table 1
23Table 2
24Table 3
25Table 5
26Table 6
27Comments on Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin
- Effects may be due to helping overcome
- Self-discipline problems
- But also helps resist pressure to share with
others - More research needed on whether this is
substitution from other forms of saving (other
banks, or physical asset holdings) - A follow-up paper indicates that savings do not
seem to be sustained in longer term
28Risk and insurance
29Agenda
- Risk-coping mechanisms
- Townsend (1994), Udry (1994), and related
literature - A field experiment in Malawi insurance, credit,
and technology adoption
30Micro-level responses to risk
- How do households cope with risk?
- In rich countries, people have insurance
- Fire insurance, home insurance, auto insurance,
life insurance, medical insurance - These insulate people from the potentially
ruinous effects of catastrophic shocks - In poor countries, formal insurance markets tend
not to exist or to be very limited - The poor have to rely on informal insurance
- A vast literature in development economics
illustrates the ingenious ways poor households
insure themselves from adverse shocks - A theme idiosyncratic risk is easier to cope
with than aggregate risk
31Poverty and vulnerability a vicious circle
Poverty
Vulnerability
32Ways to cope with risk
- Ex ante smooth income
- Ex post smooth consumption
33Smoothing income
- Choose a safe production technology farm a food
crop like cassava rather than a cash crop like
coffee - Avoid risky new investments, transitions to
different technologies (Malawi example) - Diversify income sources
- Diversify farming plots spatially
- References Morduch (1992, 1995, 1999)
- Note all of these are costly (reduce average
income, even while making income more stable)
34Smoothing consumption
- Reciprocal transfers (informal insurance)
- Coate and Ravallion (1993), Townsend (1994), Udry
(1994), Ligon (1998), Banerjee and Newman (1993) - Credit Udry (1994)
- Asset sales Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1993)
- Savings Paxson (1992)
- Labor supply Kochar (1999)
- Migration by family members Rosenzweig and Stark
(1989) - Remittances Yang (2008), Yang and Choi (2007)
35Theory risk-sharing between households
- Basic result if there is a Pareto-efficient
allocation of risk across households, one
householdss consumption should not depend on
idiosyncratic shocks - 2 households, indexed by i1,2
- Uncertain income, separable utility
- Pareto efficient allocation of risk between
households 1 and 2 implies - Any two households marginal utilities are
proportional - consumption moves in tandem
- If utility is CARA
36Empirical implication
- Consumption depends only on mean village income
(and households weight in the Pareto program),
and not on idiosyncratic shocks - Consumption should comove within villages
- Empirical test regress household consumption on
idiosyncratic shocks, controlling for village
income (or village fixed effects in panel
setting), and idiosyncratic shocks should not
have effect - Townsend (1994), Ravallion and Chaudhuri (1997)
find high degree of comovement in consumption
across Indian ICRISAT households, even with
substantial idiosyncratic income variation - But can reject full risk-sharing (idiosyncratic
shocks do have some effect)
37Insurance, Credit and Technology Adoption Field
Experimental Evidence from Malawi
Xavier Gine World Bank Dean Yang University of
Michigan
38A technology adoption puzzle
- Green Revolution high-yield crop varieties have
led to significant increases in agricultural
productivity worldwide - But there is enormous variation in the extent to
which households have adopted these new
technologies - In Malawi, hybrid maize adoption has lagged
behind Kenya, Zambia, and Zimbabwe - Need to look beyond credit constraints even when
credit offered, only 33 of farmers took up a
loan for improved seeds
39Credit or insurance as the key barrier?
- In observational data, the relative importance of
credit constraints and imperfect insurance may be
confounded - Example widely-observed correlation between
wealth and adoption of new technology - May be because wealthier farmers have better
access to credit - But wealthier households may also have better
access to (formal and informal) insurance
mechanisms - Disentangling the two explanations is crucial to
good policymaking - Needed exogenous variation in insurance
40Technology adoption, risk, and credit
- Key question Does risk inhibit adoption of new
technologies? - High-yielding varieties have higher yields but
may also be riskier - So households unwilling to bear fluctuations in
their consumption may decide not to adopt - Downside risk of adoption may be exacerbated when
adoption requires credit - Failure of crop is compounded by the consequences
of default - Problem absent or imperfect insurance markets
41This paper
- A field experiment where insurance was allocated
randomly - Question of interest
- Does providing insurance against a major source
of risk increase farmers willingness to take out
a loan to adopt a new technology? - Adoption decision whether or not to take out a
loan for improved groundnut and maize seeds
42Harvesting groundnuts
43Weather insurance and loan take-up in theory
- Risk-averse farmers choose between traditional
seeds, and taking out loan for improved seeds - Improved seeds have higher mean yield, but are
riskier - Consider attractiveness of bundling loan with
weather insurance (at actuarially fair rate) - Loans subject to limited liability in case of
default, lender can only seize the value of
production - Under certain conditions, farmers might take the
uninsured loan if offered, but prefer the status
quo (traditional seeds) to the insured loan - Basic idea limited liability provides implicit
insurance - Insurance premium may exceed benefit from
insurance - Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1993) welfare gain from
actuarially-fair weather insurance is minimal
44Simple model
- Output from traditional seeds YT
- Output from improved seeds YH, YL with
probabilities p, 1-p - Output positively covaries with rainfall
- Farmers are offered loans to purchase improved
seeds (repayment R) lender can only confiscate
production, but cannot seize assets (so there is
a consumption floor) - CRRA utility u(c) c1-s/(1-s)
- Farmers are heterogeneous in risk aversion (si)
and low-state income from improved seeds (YL,i) - Some farmers offered loan bundled with
actuarially fair rainfall insurance policy (loan
forgiven if low state occurs) - Does rainfall insurance raise loan take-up?
45What farmers take up the loan?
- Find coefficient of relative risk aversion
sTU(YL) such that farmer whose si sTU is
indifferent between traditional seeds and
uninsured loan for hybrid seeds - Farmer takes up the uninsured loan if si lt sTU
- Find analogous cutoff for insured loan, sTI(YL)
- Cutoffs will be function of income from improved
seeds in low state, YL - See Figure 1
46Figure 1
47Key partners in project
- Rural lenders
- Malawi Rural Finance Company (MRFC)
- Opportunity International Bank of Malawi (OIBM)
- National Smallholder Farmers Association of
Malawi (NASFAM) - Contact with farmers
- Insurance Association of Malawi
- Underwrites insurance
- World Bank / University of Michigan
- Technical advice on design of insurance policy
- Design of randomized evaluation
48Experimental design
- Joint liability loans for clubs of 10-15
farmers - Participation is individual farmer decision
- Randomization across 32 localities
- Treatment farmers offered hybrid seed loan with
insurance against poor rainfall - 393 farmers
- Control farmers offered hybrid seed loan only
(no insurance) - 394 farmers
49Loan details
- Farmers given option to purchase either groundnut
package only, or both groundnut and maize - Seeds and fertilizer for planting 1 acre
(groundnut) or ½ acre (maize) - Initial deposit of 12.5 of principal
- Repayment due in 10 months
- 27.5 interest rate (33 annual interest rate x
10/12) - Maize repayment
- Uninsured 36
- Insured 40-43
- Groundnut repayment
- Uninsured 34
- Insured 36-38
50Weather insurance policy
- Farmers insured against poor rainfall as measured
at nearest weather station - Paid continuous amount depending on shortfall
below 1st trigger, up to maximum amount for
rainfall at or below 2nd trigger - Insurance premium actuarially fair price
17.5 surtax
51Insurance payout structure
payout
2nd trigger (corresponds to crop failure)
1st trigger
rainfall during phase
52Project locations
53Orientation meeting, October 2006
54Simple treatment-control comparison
- Take-up rate for uninsured loan 33.0
- Take-up rate for insured loan 17.6
55Regression specification
- For farmer i in group j
- Yij a bIj fXij eij
- Yij takeup indicator
- Ij treatment indicator
- Xij vector of control variables (collected at
baseline) - Standard errors reported
- clustered at locality level
- bootstrapped
56Impact of insurance on take-up
Table 3 Impact of insurance on take-up of loan for hybrid seeds Table 3 Impact of insurance on take-up of loan for hybrid seeds Table 3 Impact of insurance on take-up of loan for hybrid seeds Table 3 Impact of insurance on take-up of loan for hybrid seeds
(Ordinary least-squares estimates)
Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Treatment indicator -0.154 -0.141 -0.132 -0.128
0.109 0.082 0.082 0.074
Clustered s.e. p-value 0.155 0.085 0.107 0.082
Bootstrapped p-value 0.198 0.116 0.140 0.120
Region fixed effects Y Y Y
Linear control variables Y
Indicators for 5-year age categories Y
Land quintile indicators Y
Income quintile indicators Y
Education quintile indicators Y
Mean dependent variable 0.253 0.253 0.253 0.253
Observations 787 787 787 787
R-squared 0.03 0.13 0.15 0.17
significant at 10 significant at 5 significant at 1 significant at 10 significant at 5 significant at 1 significant at 10 significant at 5 significant at 1
57Implied interest rate elasticity
- For a farmer placing zero value on insurance,
effective annual interest rates for groundnut
loan were - 27.5 for uninsured loan
- 37.8 to 44.4 for insured loan (varied according
to location) - The 13-percentage-point decline in take-up (from
baseline 33.0) ? a 39.4 decline - Increase in effective interest rate due to
insurance 37.5 to 61.3 - Implied interest rate elasticity of credit demand
ranging from 0.64 to 1.05
58Additional testable predictions from theory
- Take-up rates for insured vs. uninsured loan
suggest that sample tends to have lower levels of
YL - In this range of YL, there is another theoretical
implication to test - YL should be positively correlated with take-up
of insured loan - But not correlated with take-up of uninsured
loan - But how to measure YL?
- Assume farmers with higher socio-economic status
have higher YL - Regress take-up on education, income, and wealth
- Separately for farmers offered insured and
uninsured loans
59Figure 1
60Other determinants of take-up
Table 5 Determinants of take-up in treatment and control groups Table 5 Determinants of take-up in treatment and control groups Table 5 Determinants of take-up in treatment and control groups Table 5 Determinants of take-up in treatment and control groups Table 5 Determinants of take-up in treatment and control groups
(Ordinary least-squares estimates) (Ordinary least-squares estimates)
Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season Dependent variable Respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season
Treatment group (insured loan) Treatment group (insured loan) Treatment group (insured loan) Treatment group (insured loan) Treatment group (insured loan) Treatment group (insured loan) Control group (uninsured loan) Control group (uninsured loan) Control group (uninsured loan) Control group (uninsured loan) Control group (uninsured loan) Control group (uninsured loan)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
Years of schooling 0.014 0.011 -0.001 -0.002
0.005 0.005 0.008 0.009
Net income (MK 100,000) 0.098 0.075 0.004 0.003
0.059 0.053 0.010 0.010
House quality 0.041 0.027 0.011 0.011
0.027 0.030 0.022 0.022
Land owned 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001
0.003 0.003 0.002 0.002
Risk aversion (self-reported) -0.008 -0.008 -0.015 -0.015
0.006 0.006 0.004 0.004
Region fixed effects Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y
Mean dependent variable 0.176 0.176 0.176 0.176 0.176 1.176 0.330 0.330 0.330 0.330 0.330 0.330
Observations 393 393 393 393 393 393 394 394 394 394 394 394
R-squared 0.074 0.078 0.073 0.058 0.061 0.101 0.274 0.274 0.274 0.274 0.286 0.287
F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables 3.446 F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables F-stat Joint signif. of first 4 indep. variables 0.113
P-value 0.03 P-value 0.98
significant at 10 significant at 5 significant at 1 significant at 10 significant at 5 significant at 1 significant at 10 significant at 5 significant at 1 significant at 10 significant at 5 significant at 1
Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions. Notes -- Standard errors clustered by localities in square brackets. Dependent variable equal to 1 if respondent took up loan for November 2006 planting season, and 0 otherwise. Omitted region indicator is for Kasungu. See Appendix for variable definitions.
61Other potential explanations
- Complexity
- Risk priming
- Differential default cost perceptions
62In sum
- Take-up is lower for loans bundled with insurance
against poor rainfall (priced actuarially fairly) - Compared with identical loans that are uninsured
- Potential explanation
- Farmers already implicitly insured by limited
liability inherent in loan contract - Reduces value of the formal, explicit insurance
- Among farmers offered the insured loan, take-up
is higher among farmers with higher education,
income, and wealth - But not among farmers offered the uninsured loan
- Perhaps because higher-status farmers have higher
default costs
63Ongoing related research
- Current projects continue to examine the nature
of constraints that Malawian farmers face in
financial markets - Credit
- How important are difficulties in enforcement in
limiting credit supply in rural areas? - In particular, can improvements in identification
technology raise loan repayment rates? - Savings
- How important are imperfect savings mechanisms in
explaining low input use on farms? - How important are transactions costs in
explaining low utilization of formal savings
mechanisms?