Title: Futures Valuation-A Second Look
1- PART-X
- Futures Valuation-A Second Look
2Assets That Pay a Known Income
- If a person receives income from an asset that is
in his possession, then such a cash inflow will
obviously reduce the carrying cost - The carrying cost can now be defined as
- rS I, where I is the future value of the
income as computed at the time of expiration of
the forward contract
3Known Income (Cont)
- Why use the future value of the income and not
just the income? - We need to calculate the future value of the
income, because the interest cost incurred for
financing the purchase of the asset is payable
only at the end - And due to the principle of Time Value of Money,
all cash flows must be measured at the same point
in time in order to be comparable
4Known Income (Cont)
- Consequently in order to rule out cash and carry
arbitrage we require that - F S ? rS I ? F ? S(1r) - I
- Similarly from a short sellers perspective, in
the case of such assets, the effective income
obtained by investing the proceeds from the short
sale will be reduced by the amount of income
received from the asset
5Known Income (Cont)
- This is because the short seller is required to
compensate the lender of the asset for the income
generate by the asset - Thus in order to preclude reverse cash and carry
arbitrage, we require that - F S ? rS I ? F ?S(1r) - I
- Consequently the no arbitrage condition is
- F S(1r) - I
6Illustration ofCash and Carry Arbitrage
- Consider the case of TISCO once again
- Assume that the share price is Rs 100, and that
the stock is expected to pay a dividend of Rs 5
after three months, and another Rs 5 after six
months - Forward contracts expiring after six months are
available at a price of Rs 96 per share
7Illustration (Cont)
- We will assume that the second dividend payment
will be made just an instant before the forward
contract matures - Take the case of an arbitrageur who can borrow at
10 per annum - He can borrow Rs 100 and buy a share of TISCO
8Illustration (Cont)
- He can simultaneously go short in a forward
contract to sell the share after six months for
Rs 96 - After three months he will receive the first
dividend of Rs 5 - This can be reinvested for the three months that
remain in the life of the contract at a rate of
10 per annum
9Illustration (Cont)
- Finally, just prior to the maturity of the
forward contract, he will receive the second
dividend of Rs 5 - Thus at the time of delivery of the share, the
investors cash inflow is - 96 5 x (1 0.10) 5 106.025
- -----
- 4
10Illustration (Cont)
- The rate of return on investment is
- (106.025 100) 0.0625 6.25
- -------------------
- 100
- Which is greater than the borrowing rate of 5
for six months
11Illustration (Cont)
- Cash and carry arbitrage was profitable in this
case since F gt S(1r) - I - That is, the contract was overpriced
12Illustration of Reverse Cash and Carry Arbitrage
- Assume that the price of the forward contract is
Rs 94 and not Rs 96 - An arbitrageur can short sell the stock and
receive Rs 100 - This can be invested at 10 per annum so as to
receive Rs 105 after six months - Simultaneously he can go long in a forward
contract in order to reacquire the asset after 6
months
13Illustration (Cont)
- After 3 months, the company will declare a
dividend of Rs 5 - Since the arbitrageur has short sold the share,
he must compensate the lender of the share - This Rs 5 can be borrowed at the rate of 10 per
annum - Similarly, at the end of 6 months, another Rs 5
will have to be paid when the second dividend is
declared
14Illustration (Cont)
- So the inflow at the end of six months is Rs 105
- The outflow at the end of six months is
- 94 5x (1.025) 5 Rs 104.125
- Thus there is clearly an arbitrage profit of
Rs 0.875 - Reverse cash and carry arbitrage was profitable
because - F lt S(1r) - I
15The No-Arbitrage Condition
- The no-arbitrage condition is
- F S(1r) I
- In our example the correct price of the forward
contract is - F 100(1.05) 10.125 Rs 94.875
16Physical Assets
- While financial assets like stocks and bonds
generate cash flows for investors who hold them,
physical assets entail the incurrence of
expenditure - Investors have to bear the costs of storage as
well as related expenses like insurance premiums
17Physical Assets (Cont)
- A cost is nothing but a negative income
- Hence if we denote the future value of all
storage related costs as Z, as calculated at the
time of expiration of the forward contract, then
Z -I - Thus the no-arbitrage condition may be expressed
as F S(1r) (-Z) S(1r) Z
18Physical Assets and Arbitrage
- If this relationship is violated, then arbitrage
profits can be made - We will first consider an overpriced forward
contract on gold - Obviously if the contract is overpriced, then
Cash and Carry Arbitrage will be profitable
19Illustration (Cont)
- Let the spot price of gold be 500 per ounce
- Let storage costs be 5 per ounce for a period
- of six months, payable at the end of six
- months
- Let the price of a forward contract for delivery
of an - ounce of gold six months hence be 535
20Illustration (Cont)
- Consider the case of an investor who can borrow
at 10 per annum - He can borrow 500 and buy an ounce of gold and
simultaneously go short in a forward contract - Six months hence he can deliver the gold for
535
21Illustration (Cont)
- His interest cost for six months will be 25 and
the storage cost will be 5 - Thus the effective carrying cost will be
30 - The rate of return on investment is
- (535 500) 0.07 7
- --------------
- 500
22Illustration (Cont)
- The effective carrying cost is
- (530 500) 0.06 6
- --------------
- 500
- Hence the cash and carry strategy is profitable
- It is so because F gt S(1r) Z
23No-Arbitrage
- In order to rule out both cash and carry as well
as reverse cash and carry arbitrage, it must be
the case that - F S(1r) Z
24The Importance of Short Sales
- In order to carry out reverse cash and carry
arbitrage, the freedom to short sell is critical - Thus, if the market is to be free of arbitrage
opportunities, there must be unfettered freedom
to short sell - In practice, short sales need not always be
feasible
25Pure versus Convenience Assets
- A Pure asset, also known as an Investment asset,
is one that is held by the investor as an
investment - That is, the investor is holding it purely
because it is expected to provide some income
during the holding period, and some capital gain
at the time of sale - Of course there could be assets which are
expected to provide no income, but are being held
mainly in anticipation of a capital gain
26Pure Assets (Cont)
- Hence, as long as an investor is assured that
such an asset will be returned to him intact, at
the end of the period during which he would
otherwise have held it as an investment, and that
he will be suitably compensated for any payments
that he would have received in the interim, then
he will not mind parting with it
27Pure Assets (Cont)
- In other words, such an investor will be willing
to lend the asset, to facilitate short selling on
the part of another - All financial assets tend to be investment
assets. - Precious metals like gold also tend to be
investment assets
28Convenience Assets
- Consider an agricultural commodity like wheat
- It is often held for reasons other than potential
returns - Let us consider the situation from the
perspective of a person who chooses to hoard it
before a harvest
29Convenience Assets (Cont)
- Normally prices of commodities rise before
harvesting is complete and fall thereafter - Thus a person who hoards wheat during a harvest,
not only has to incur storage costs, but also
faces the spectre of a capital loss - Thus, seen from an investment angle, it makes
little sense to hold wheat prior to a harvest
30Convenience Assets (Cont)
- However in practice there are investors who
choose to hold commodities like wheat under such
circumstances - Such people are obviously getting some intangible
benefits from holding the commodity
31Convenience Assets (Cont)
- For instance a wheat mill owner may wish to
ensure that the mill does not have to be closed
during an unanticipated shortage due to a cyclone
or a monsoon failure - The value of such intangible benefits is called
the Convenience Value - If an investor is getting a convenience value
from an asset he will not part with it to
facilitate short sales
32Convenience Values
- We can think of the convenience value as an
implicit dividend - However, unlike in the case of an explicit
dividend, a potential short seller cannot
compensate the owner of such an asset, and induce
him to part with it - This is true, firstly because convenience values
cannot be quantified
33Convenience values (Cont)
- Secondly the perception of such value will differ
from holder to holder
34Convenience Assets andNo-Arbitrage
- Thus for assets which are being held for
consumption purposes, we can only state that - F S(1r) Z
- The possibility of cash and carry arbitrage will
ensure that - F ?S(1r) Z
35Convenience Assets andNo Arbitrage
- However F may be less than S(1r) Z, without
giving rise to reverse cash and carry arbitrage,
because facilities for short selling may not exist
36The Mechanics of Reverse Cash and Carry Arbitrage
for Convenience Assets
- We have provided a detailed illustration of how
cash and carry arbitrage will take place in the
case of physical commodities - The corresponding arguments are valid
irrespective of whether the asset is a pure asset
or a convenience asset - However we have not yet discussed reverse cash
and carry arbitrage in detail, even for those
physical commodities which are investment assets
and not convenience assets
37Reverse Cash and Carry andConvenience Assets
- It must be remembered that all physical assets
need not be convenience assets - However even for those commodities which tend to
be held for investment purposes, there are some
finer issues when it comes to reverse cash and
carry arbitrage
38Reverse Cash and Carry (Cont)
- In the case of financial assets, whenever reverse
cash and carry arbitrage is undertaken, the
arbitrageur who is also the short seller, has to
compensate the lender for any income that he is
forgoing by parting with the asset
39Reverse Cash and Carry (Cont)
- However, in the case of physical assets, the
lender is not foregoing any income - On the contrary he would have incurred storage
costs had he chosen to hold on to the asset,
rather than lend it for a short sale - In this case therefore, reverse cash and carry
arbitrage will be profitable only if the cost
savings experienced by the lender are passed on
to the arbitrageur (short seller)
40Illustration
- Assume that the spot price of gold is 500 per
ounce - Let the price of a six month forward contract be
525 - The storage cost is 5 per ounce for six months,
payable at the end of the period. - The borrowing/lending rate is 10 per annum
41Illustration (Cont)
- F 525 lt S(1r)Z 500(10.05)5 530
- Take the case of an arbitrageur who short sells
the asset - He will receive 500 which he will lend at 10
per annum - Simultaneously he will go long in a forward
contract to acquire the gold after six months at
525
42Illustration (Cont)
- At the end of six months his cash inflow will be
525 which will be the same as his cash outflow - Thus in order for the arbitrage strategy to be
profitable, he ought to be compensated by the
lender of the asset with 5, which is the amount
of the storage cost saved by him, or at least
with a fraction of the amount
43Illustration (Cont)
- In practice such an arrangement may not be
feasible - Does this mean that an under priced forward
contract cannot be exploited even if the
commodity is being held for investment purposes? - The answer is no
44Quasi-Arbitrage
- Consider the situation from the perspective of a
person who owns one ounce of gold - He can sell the gold in the spot market and lend
the proceeds for six months - Simultaneously he can go long in a forward
contract to reacquire the gold at 525 - Six months hence his inflow will be 525.
45Quasi-Arbitrage (Cont)
- This amount will be just adequate to repurchase
the gold. - In addition he will have 5 in his possession
which represents the storage costs saved.
46Quasi-Arbitrage (Cont)
- Such an investor is not an arbitrageur in the
conventional sense, although he has clearly
exploited an arbitrage opportunity - Such a strategy is called Quasi-Arbitrage
- In derivatives parlance, we say that he has
replaced a natural spot position with a synthetic
spot position
47Synthetic Spot
- What do we mean by a synthetic spot position?
- Notice that this investor gets back his gold at
the end - Thus although he has sold the gold, it is
effectively as if he has not parted with it - Thus he has sold something without really selling
it
48Synthetic Spot (Cont)
- Or put differently, he continues to own the gold
during the period of six months, without actually
owning it - We know that Spot Futures Synthetic T-bill
- Therefore Futures T-bill Synthetic Spot
- Thus in the case of physical commodities that are
held as investment assets, the possibility of
cash and carry arbitrage and reverse cash and
carry quasi-arbitrage, will help ensure that - F S(1r) Z
49The Value of a Forward Contract
- When a forward contract is entered into, its
value to both the parties is zero - That is, neither the long nor the short has to
pay any money to get into a forward contract - Of course both of them have to post margins.
- But a margin is a performance guarantee and not a
cost
50Forward Price versus Delivery Price
- The delivery price is the price specified in the
forward contract - It is the price at which the short agrees to
deliver and the long agrees to accept delivery as
per the contract
51Forward Price versusDelivery Price (Cont)
- What then is a Forward Price?
- The forward price at a given point in time is the
delivery price that is applicable for a contract
being negotiated at that particular instant - Once a contract is sealed, its delivery price
will not change
52Forward Price versusDelivery Price (Cont)
- However, as each new trade is negotiated, the
forward price will keep changing - To put things in perspective, if one were to come
and say that he had entered into a forward
contract a week ago, we would ask what was the
delivery price? and not what was the forward
price then?, although both would mean the same
53Forward Price versusDelivery Price
- However, if we were to negotiate a contract at a
particular point in time, we would ask what is
the forward price? - And if the negotiation were to be successful and
the contract were to be sealed, then the
prevailing forward price would become the
delivery price of the contract being entered into
54Evolution of Value
- When a contract is first entered into, its value
to both parties will be zero - However, as time passes, a pre-existing contract
will acquire value - Consider a long forward position that was entered
into in the past at a time when the forward price
was K - Consequently its delivery price as of today will
be K
55Evolution of Value (Cont)
- In order to offset this position, the investor
will have to take a short position, which will
obviously be executed at the prevailing forward
price F - Thus if a counter-position is taken, the investor
will have a payoff of (F-K) awaiting him at the
time of expiration of the contract
56Evolution of value (Cont)
- The value of the original contract is nothing but
the present value of this payoff
57Illustration
- Assume that a forward contract exists that
expires at time T - Let the delivery price be K
- Let F be the current forward price for a contract
expiring at time T - Let r be the risk-less rate of interest for a
loan between now and time T
58Illustration (Cont)
- The value of a long forward position is therefore
- F K
- ---------
- (1r)
59Illustration (Cont)
- The value of a short position will be the
negative of this, that is - -(F K) K - F
- ----------- --------
- (1r) (1r)
60Numerical Illustration
- A long position in a 9 month forward contract was
entered into 3 months ago - The delivery price is 100
- Today the forward price for a 6 month contract is
120 - The risk-less rate of interest for six months is
10
61Numerical Illustration (Cont)
- The value of a long forward position with a
delivery price of 100 is therefore - 120 100
- ------------ 18.18
- 1.10
- The value of a short forward position with a
delivery price of 100 will be 18.18
62Value
- As you can see, once a contract is sealed, a
subsequent increase in the forward price will
lead to an increase in value for the holder of a
long position - A subsequent decline in the forward price will
lead to an increase in value for the holder of a
short position
63Value of a Futures Contract
- The value of a futures contract is zero when the
contract is initiated - That is, no money is required to take either a
long or a short position in futures - Assume that a futures contract is entered into at
a price F0 - Let the settlement price at the end of the day be
F1
64Value of a Futures Contract (Cont)
- Using the same logic as for forward contracts, if
this contract were to be offset, the profit for
the long would be F1 F0 - This is precisely the amount that will be paid
to/received from the long when the contract is
marked to market at the end of the day
65Value of a Futures Contract (Cont)
- Thus the process of marking to market ensures
that the value of a futures position, whether
long or short, is reset to zero at the end of the
day - Thus between the end of one trading day and the
next, a futures contract will build up value - However at the end of the next day, the value
will revert to zero
66Forward Price versus Futures Price
- One logical question is, will the price fixed per
unit of the asset in the case of a forward
contract be the same as in the case of a futures
contract on the same asset, if the contracts are
similar in all other respects? - It can be shown that under certain conditions,
this will indeed be the case
67Pricing
- More specifically, if the risk-less rate of
interest is a constant, and is the same for all
the maturities, then forward and futures prices
will be identical for contracts on the same asset
and with the same expiration date - Thus all the no-arbitrage conditions derived
earlier are valid for futures contracts too
68Random Interest Rates
- In real life however, interest rates are
constantly fluctuating and are not constant - This will therefore have an impact on the
relationship between the forward price and the
futures price - The difference arises because while futures
contracts are marked to market on a daily basis,
forward contracts are not
69Impact of Random Interest Rates
- Let us first consider a situation where interest
rates and futures prices are positively
correlated - That is, when interest rates are high, so are the
futures prices and vice versa - Now rising futures prices will lead to cash
inflows for investors with long positions
70Impact of Random Rates (Cont)
- Thus the longs will be able to reinvest their
profits at relatively high rates of interest - At the same time rising futures prices will lead
to cash outflows for investors with short futures
positions - These investors will have to finance such losses
at relatively high rates of interest
71Impact of Random Rates (Cont)
- On the contrary, if futures prices were to
decline, the corresponding interest rates would
also be lower - Declining prices will lead to losses for the
longs and profits for the shorts - Thus the longs can finance their losses at low
rates of interest while the shorts will have to
invest their profits at low rates
72Impact of Random Rates (Cont)
- An investor with a long position in a forward
contract on the same asset, will not be affected
by such interest movements in the interim, since
he will have no intermediate cash flows - Thus compared to such an investor, a person with
a long futures position will be better off
73Impact of Random Rates (Cont)
- By the same logic, a person with a short futures
position will be worse off as compared to an
investor with a short forward position - Thus a person taking a long futures position
should be required to pay more for this advantage
74Impact of Random Rates (Cont)
- Viewed from a shorts angle, a person with a
short futures position should receive more for
this disadvantage - Hence if interest rates and futures prices are
positively correlated, futures prices will exceed
forward prices
75Impact of Random Rates (Cont)
- By a similar argument, if interest rates and
futures prices are negatively correlated, then
futures prices will be less than the
corresponding forward prices
76The Case of Gold
- Assume that interest rates rise because of higher
expected inflation - Gold is widely perceived as a hedge against
inflation - So gold prices will be expected to rise if
inflation is expected to rise - Hence hold prices and interest rates should be
positively correlated
77The Case of T-bonds
- Interest rates are negatively related to bond
prices - So T-bond futures prices should be negatively
correlated with interest rates
78Conclusion
- We would expect a gold futures contract to be
priced higher than a comparable gold forward
contract - And a T-bond futures contract to be priced lower
than a comparable T-bond forward contract
79Conclusive Evidence?
- If we observe a difference between the futures
price and the price of a comparable forward
contract, for an asset, can we conclude that it
is due to a relationship between futures prices
and interest rates? - The answer is no
- Firstly the transactions costs could be different
in the two markets
80Conclusive ?
- Secondly forward markets are usually much less
liquid than futures markets - Thirdly futures contracts carry a lower risk of
default due to the role of the Clearinghouse and
the Marking to Market mechanism - To test the interest rate correlation hypothesis
we need to look at an asset for which these other
factors are insignificant - It has been argued that FOREX markets offer an
appropriate testing ground
81Net Carry
- The term Net Carry refers to the net carrying
cost of the underlying asset, expressed as a
fraction of the current spot price - If the risk-less rate is r, and the future value
of income from the asset is I, then - Net Carry rS I r I
- ------- --
- S S
82Net Carry (Cont)
- For physical assets which entail the payment of
storage costs - Net Carry r Z
- ---
- S
83Net Carry (Cont)
- For financial assets
- F S(1r) I S Net Carry x S
- For physical assets which are held for investment
purposes - F S(1r) Z S Net Carry x S
- However in the case of convenience assets
- F S(1r) Z ? F S(1r) Z - Y
84Net Carry (Cont)
- The variable Y which equates the two sides of the
relationship, is the marginal convenience value - If Y 0, then we say that the market is at full
carry - Thus investment assets, which includes all
financial assets and certain physical assets,
will always be at full carry
85Net Carry (Cont)
- However, futures markets for convenience assets
will not be at full carry - If the futures price of an asset exceeds the spot
market price, or if the price of a near month
contract is less than the price of a far month
contract, then we say that the market is in
Contango
86Net Carry (Cont)
- However if the futures price is less than the
spot price, or if the price of the near month
contract is more than the price of a far month
contract, then we say that the market is in
Backwardation
87Illustration of a Contango Market
Contract Price
Spot 500
March Futures 510
June Futures 520
September Futures 525
December Futures 540
88Illustration of a Backwardation Market
Contract Price
Spot 500
March Futures 485
June Futures 470
September Futures 450
December Futures 440
89Net Carry
- For financial assets, the net carry can either be
positive or negative, depending on the
relationship between the financing cost, rS, and
the future value of the income from the asset, I - A positive net carry will manifest itself as a
Contango market, whereas a negative net carry
will reveal itself as a market in Backwardation
90Net Carry (Cont)
- In the case of physical commodities, if the
market is at full carry, then we will have a
Contango market - However if the market is not at full carry, then
we may have either a Backwardation or a Contango
market, depending on the relative magnitudes of
the net carry and the convenience yield