Title: Introduction to Valuation Bond Valuation
1Introduction to ValuationBond Valuation
- Financial Management
- P.V. Viswanath
- For a First course in Finance
2Lesson Objectives
- To look at the difference between economics and
finance - To introduce the notion of future dollars as
traded goods. - To introduce the price of future dollars
- To relate the price of money to interest rates.
- To use these rates to price Treasury securities
- To introduce the notion of arbitrage
3Absolute and Relative Pricing
- In economics, we tend to price goods and assets
by considering the factors affecting the supply
and demand for them. - The number of goods and assets are very many.
Each of them is different in some way or another
from the other. - Computing the price of one good does not allow us
to price another good, except to the extent that
other goods are substitutes or complements for
the first good. - In finance, the number of assets can be
reasonably characterized in terms of a smaller
number of basic characteristics. - Hence most assets can, to a first approximation
be priced by considering them as combinations of
more fundamental assets.
4The Fundamentals of Economics
- One of the issues that economics analyzes is the
determination of prices of goods. - For example, what determines the price of eggs?
- We have a supply curve that is, a schedule of
quantities of eggs that their current possessors
would be willing to sell and the prices at which
they would be willing to sell them. - The higher the price, the more theyd be willing
to sell.
5The Supply Curve
Price ( per unit)
Quantity of Eggs
6The Demand Curve
- We can also imagine the different amounts of eggs
that people would be willing to buy and the
prices at which they would buy those quantities. - The lower the price, the more would be demanded.
7The Demand Curve
Price ( per unit)
Quantity of Eggs
8The Determination of the Price of Eggs
Price ( per unit)
Quantity of Eggs
9Economics and Finance
- Finance, like Economics, is interested in the
prices of goods. - But the goods that financial analysts are
interested in, are quite different. - As you might imagine, financial economists are
interested in money (or purchasing power) and in
the price of money. - But what does it mean to talk about the price of
money? In what currency would you pay to acquire
money?
10Money and Time
- The answer is that access to resources today is
not the same as access to resources tomorrow
that is, money available today is not the same as
money available tomorrow. - You can buy something today only if you have the
money to buy it with today. Having access to
money, which will be available tomorrow wont
allow you to necessarily buy things today! - This means that we can talk of different kinds of
money. - And, denoting time by the subscript t, we can
talk of the price of time 1 (tomorrow) money in
terms of time 0 (today) money.
11More on the price of money
- Lets assume that all prices are denominated in
t0 dollars (todays money). - Then, just as we might say that the price of a
book is 10, the price of a subway token is 2
and the price of a cup of Starbucks coffee is
3.50, we could also say - The price of a t1 dollar is 0.90, the price of
a t2 dollar is 0.7831 and the price of a t3
dollar is 0.675.
12The price of coffee, said differently
- This might sound a little strange to you, but
lets put it slightly differently. - Going back to a cup of coffee, we said its price
was 3.50, but if we know that 3.50 1, we
could equally well say that the price of a book
is 1. - Then even if we were all in the US and Starbucks
only accepted US dollars, there would be no
problem if Starbucks had its price list
denominated in euros.
13More ways to price coffee
- Lets take this further.
- Suppose Starbucks required everybody to play the
following game in order to figure out the price
of its offering. - Suppose they took the actual dollar price of a
coffee multiplied it by 2 and added 3 to it and
called it java units (J). - A cup of coffee that normally cost 3.5 would be
listed as costing 10J. - Then if we saw a cappuccino listed at 13J, we
would simply subtract 3 to get 10, then divide by
2 to get a price of 5. - It would be a little weird, but nothing
substantive would change.
14Rates
- So now, lets go back to the price of money we
said that the price of a t1 dollar was 0.90,
and that the price of a t2 dollar was 0.7831. - Now clearly the price of a t1 dollar, which is
0.90 today, will rise to 1 at t1. - Hence providing todays price of a t1 dollar is
equivalent to providing the rate of change of the
price over the coming period. - I have exactly the same information in each case.
- This rate of change is also my rate of return
over the next year if I buy a t1 dollar, today,
and is also known as the interest rate. - In our example, this works out to (1-0.90)/0.90
or 11.11
15Rates
- What about the price of a t2 dollar, which we
said was 0.7831? - Once again, the price of this t2 dollar would be
1 at t2 (in t2 dollars, of course). - We could compute the gross return on this
investment, in the same way, as 1/0.7831 1.277
or a return of 27.70. - But this is a return over two periods, and we
cannot compare it directly to the 11.11 that we
computed earlier. - The solution to this problem is to annualize the
two-period return
16Computing Annualized Rates
- We computed the return on buying a t2 dollar at
27.70. - Suppose the one-period return on this is r that
is, the return from holding this t2 dollar from
now until t1 is r. Then, every dollar invested
in this specialized investment could be sold at
(1r) at t1. - Now, if we assume the return on this t2 dollar
if held from t1 to t2 is also r, then the
(1r) value of our outlay of one t0 dollar in
this investment would be (1r)(1r) or (1r)2. - But we already know from our return computation,
that this is exactly 1.277 (that is 1 plus the
27.7). - Hence we equate (1r)2 to 1.277 and solve for r.
17Annualized Rates
- This involves simply taking the square-root of
1.277, which is 13. - Of course, we wont get exactly 13 in each of
the two periods. - The 13 rate is, rather, a sort of average return
over the two periods, that results in a 27.7
over the two years. - We can now take 0.675, the price of a t3 dollar
and also convert it to a rate of return. - In this case, we take the cube root of (1/0.675),
which works out 14
18Yield to maturity
- So now we have the current prices of t1, t2,
and t3 dollars, or 0.90, 0.7831 and 0.675
respectively. - Alternatively, the information in these prices
could also be presented as rates of return, which
in our case are 11.11, 13 and 14 respectively. - These rates are also called yields-to-maturity.
- Yields-to-maturity, in general, are the
annualized total returns that you would get if
you held a particular financial instrument to
maturity. - In this case, the returns each year are only from
price appreciation, while in other cases, there
may be annual cash payments received by the
investor, as well.
19Using the rates
- We have assumed, up to this point, that
purchasing a t1 dollar is riskless. That is, the
person who sold us the t1 dollar today, in
return for the 0.90, would, in fact, pay us 1
at time t1. - We will continue with this assumption, for now.
- Note, as well that buying a t1 dollar is
equivalent to lending money for one period, while
selling a t1 dollar is equivalent to borrowing
money for 1 period. - A bond is precisely a promise to pay its holder
some combination of future dollars. - Corporations, governments and other entities who
need funds for the continuing operations issue,
that is sell, such bonds.
20Treasury Bonds
- Consider now a bond issued by the Treasury
Department, which essentially acts as banker for
the Federal Government. - These bonds, or promises to pay are considered
default-free, i.e. we fully expect the Treasury
to live up to its promises. - We can, therefore, evaluate and price these
Treasury or T-bonds using the risk-free yields
that we established before. - This need not be true of other governmental
institutions, such as municipalities, such as the
City of New York or Federal agencies such as PATH
the Port Authority of New York and New Jersey.
21Treasury Bonds
- On Feb. 29th 2008, the Treasury issued a 2 note
with a maturity date of February 28, 2010 with a
face value of 1000, which was sold at auction. - The price paid by the lowest bidder was
99.912254 of face value. - This means that the buyer of this bond would get
every six months 1 (half of 2) of the face
value, which in this case works out to 10. - In addition, on Feb. 28, 2010, the buyer would
get 1000.
22Terminology
- The maturity of this bond is 2 years.
- The coupon rate on this bond is 2
- The face value of this bond is 1000
- The price paid for this bond is 999.123
- The yield-to-maturity obtained by this buyer is
2.045, i.e. the average rate of return for this
buyer if s/he held it to maturity.
23Pricing this bond
- Lets assume for now, that we do not know the
price of this bond. How can we price this bond? - What we do know is that a holder of this bond
would receive 10 in 6 months, another 10 in 1
year, 10 again in 1.5 years and 1010 in 2
years. - We also know that a 6-month T-bill issued on Feb.
21, 2008 sold for 98.968667. - A T-bill is a promise to pay money 6 months in
the future. With the given price then, a buyer
would get a 1.042 return for those 6 months. - This is often annualized by multiplying by 2 to
get a bond-equivalent yield of 2.084. - We also know that yields of bonds generally are
higher for higher maturities.
24Yield Curves for Feb. 1-12, 2008
Date 1mo 3mo 6mo 1yr 2yr 3yr 5yr 7yr 10yr 20yr 30yr
02/01/08 1.75 2.10 2.15 2.13 2.09 2.22 2.75 3.13 3.62 4.31 4.32
02/04/08 2.15 2.27 2.22 2.17 2.08 2.23 2.78 3.18 3.68 4.37 4.37
02/05/08 2.22 2.19 2.13 2.06 1.93 2.08 2.66 3.08 3.61 4.32 4.33
02/06/08 2.12 2.10 2.10 2.05 1.96 2.11 2.67 3.08 3.61 4.36 4.37
02/07/08 2.19 2.17 2.13 2.08 1.99 2.21 2.79 3.21 3.74 4.50 4.51
02/08/08 2.24 2.23 2.12 2.05 1.93 2.10 2.69 3.11 3.64 4.41 4.43
02/11/08 2.35 2.31 2.13 2.06 1.93 2.10 2.67 3.09 3.62 4.38 4.41
02/12/08 2.55 2.31 2.12 2.06 1.94 2.13 2.71 3.13 3.66 4.43 4.46
25Yield Curves for Feb. 1-12, 2008
26Pricing a Treasury bond
- Suppose we believe that the current environment
of uncertainty will continue. - We might believe that investors will be even more
unwilling to invest in securities that have any
default risk. - In that case, they will be willing to buy
Treasury securities at lower yields. - We use this to estimate current bond-equivalent
yields. - Suppose we estimate the current bond-equivalent
yields for 6-month money, 1 year money, 18-month
money and 2 year money as 2.07, 2.1, 2.11 and
2.14.
27Discounting
- Keeping in mind that what we have are
bond-equivalent yields, i.e. yields computed on a
six-monthly basis and then doubling to get the
annual yield, we will compute the current prices
of future dollars. - To do this, we need to employ a procedure called
discounting. - Suppose the required risk-free rate of return on
future dollars is 4 per period. - Now, if I have a certain, default-free promise of
200 in 3 periods, what is the value of this
promise today?
28Discounting
- We know the value at t3 of this promise would be
exactly 200. - The value at t2of the promise would have to be
such that would yield a return of exactly 4 over
the last period, i.e. from t2 to t4. - Suppose the required value is S. Then, we would
need (200-S)/S 1.04. - Solving this equation, we find S 200/1.04.
- What would the value at t1 be?
- Applying the same principle, we see that it must
be S/1.04 or 200/1.042. - Analogously, we can see that the value at t0 of
a promise to pay 200 in n periods is 200/(1.04)n.
29Pricing the 2-yr T-bond
- Coming back to our T-bond, the annualized yield
on 6-month money is 2.07 hence the six-month
yield is 2.07/2 or 1.035. - Hence a promised dollar-payment at t 0.5 would
sell today for 1/1.01035 or 0.989756 today. - The annualized yield on 1-year money is 2.1
hence the six-month yield is 2.10/2 1.05. - Hence a promised dollar-payment at t1 would sell
today for 1/1.01052 0.979326.
30Pricing the 2-yr T-bond
- The annualized yield on 1.5 year money is 2.11
hence the six-month yield is 2.11/2 1.055. - Hence the price today of a promised
dollar-payment at t1.5 is 1/1.010553 0.96901,
using the discounting method. - The annualized bond-equivalent yield on 2-year
money is 2.14. - The price today of a promised dollar-payment at
t2 is 1/1.01074 0.95832
31Pricing the 2-yr T-bond
- So now we know that our bond pays 10 in 6
months, another 10 in 1 year, 10 again in 1.5
years and 1010 in 2 years. - We also know that one dollar promised for each of
those dates is worth, today, 0.989756,
0.979326, 0.96901 and 0.95832 respectively. - Our bond, therefore, must sell for 10(0.989756)
10(0.979326) 10(0.96901) 1010(0.95832)
997.28.
32Arbitrage
- What we have done is to treat our 2 year 2
coupon bond as a portfolio of four other
zero-coupon bonds and then priced it as the sum
of the values of those zero-coupon bonds. - But what will guarantee that this price equality
will hold? - Heres where the efficient functioning of markets
comes into play. - A process called arbitrage ensures that the price
of a combination of other financial securities
does not deviate too much from the price implied
the prices of those other securities.
33Arbitrage
- Suppose, for example that our two-year bond sold
for 996. - Then a bond trader could buy a bond at this
price, then, himself, issue the corresponding
four zero-coupon bonds and sell them at their
market prices. - He would then end up with a profit of 1.28 per
bond. - If the bond sold for, say, 998, he could buy the
zero-coupon bonds and then create a synthetic
coupon bond and sell it at the higher price and
make a profit of 998-997.28 or 72 cents per bond.
34Relative pricing of financial assets
- Consider first riskless financial assets, i.e,
assets that are claims on riskless cashflows over
time. - Consider a fundamental asset, i, defined by a
claim to 1 at time t i. - There can be T such fundamental assets,
corresponding to the t 1,..,T time units. - Then, any arbitrary riskless financial asset that
is a claim to ci at time i, i 1,..,T can be
considered a portfolio of these T fundamental
assets. - Hence, the price, P of any such asset is related
to the prices of these first T fundamental
assets. - In fact, the price of this asset would simply be
35Relative pricing of risky financial assets
- What about risky financial assets?
- We can equivalently imagine, for every level of
risk, a set of T fundamental risky assets. Then,
for any arbitrary risky asset of this level of
risk, we can equivalently write
- Of course, this is not entirely satisfactory,
because wed have TxM fundamental assets
corresponding to each of M levels of risk. We
will come back to this when we talk about the
CAPM. - In any case, we need to examine how this pricing
is established in the market-place.
36Arbitrage and the Law of One Price
- Law of One Price In a competitive market, if two
assets generate the same cash (utility) flows,
they will be priced the same. - How is this enforced?
- If the law is violated if asset 1 sells for
more than asset 2, then investors can make a
riskless profit by buying asset 2 and selling it
as asset 1! - In practice we need to take transactions costs
into account. - Also, it may be difficult to execute the two
transactions at the same time prices might
change in that interval this introduces some
risk.
37Exchange Rates and Triangular Arbitrage
- Consider the exchange rates reigning at closing
on January 30. - The yen/euro rate was 157.87 yen per euro
- The euro/ rate was 1.4835 per euro.
- The yen/ rate was 106.4 yen per dollar.
- If we start with a dollar, we can buy 106.4 yen
these can then be used to buy 106.4/157.87 or
0.674 euros, which can, in turn, be used to
acquire 0.9998, which is very close to a dollar.
38Triangular Currency Arbitrage
- Suppose the euro/ rate had been 1.50 per euro.
- Then, it would have been possible to start with
one dollar, acquire 0.674 euros, as above, and
then get (0.674)(1.5) or 1.011, or a gain of
1.1 on the initial investment of a dollar. - This would imply that the dollar was too cheap,
relative to the euro and the yen. - Many traders would attempt to perform the
arbitrage discussed above, leading to excess
supply of dollars and excess demand for the other
currencies. - The net result would be a drop a rise in the
price of the dollar vis-à-vis the other
currencies, so that the arbitrage trades would no
longer be profitable.
39Risk Arbitrage
- In this case, trading will continue until there
are no more riskfree profit opportunities. - Thus, arbitrage can ensure that the sorts of
pricing relationships referred to above can be
supported in the marketplace, viz
- What if there are still opportunities that will,
on average, lead to profit, but the investors
intending to benefit from this profit will have
to take on some risk? - Presumably investors will trade off the risk
against the expected profit so that there will be
few of these expected profit opportunities, as
well this brings us to the notion of the
informational efficiency of financial markets.
40Efficient Markets Hypothesis EMH
- An assets current price reflects all available
information this is the EMH. - If it didnt, there would be an incentive for
investors to act on that information. - Suppose, for example, that investors noticed that
good news led to stock prices rising slowly over
two consecutive days. - This would mean that at the end of the first day,
the good news was not all incorporated in the
stock price.
41Efficient Markets Hypothesis
- In this situation, it would be optimal for
traders to buy even more of a stock that was
noted to be rising on a given day, since the
stock would rise more the next day, giving the
trader an unusually good chance of making money
on the trade. - But if many traders pursue this strategy, the
stock price would rise on the first day, itself,
and the informational inefficiency would be
eliminated. - Empirically, financial markets seem to be
reasonably close to being efficient. - This allows us to price financial assets with
respect to fundamentals without worrying about
deviations from these fundamental prices.
42Stock Price Fundamentals
- What determines the price of a stock? Or, in
other words, why would an investor hold stocks? - The answer is that s/he expects to receive
dividends and hopefully benefit from a price
increase, as well. - In other words, P0 PV(D1) PV(P1)
- However what determines P1?
- Again, using the previous logic, we must say that
its the expectation of a dividend in period 2
and hopefully a further price rise. Continuing,
in this vein, we see that the stock price must be
the sum of the present values of all future
dividends.
43Dividend Mechanics
- Declaration date The board of directors declares
a paymentRecord date The declared dividends are
distributable to shareholders of record on this
date.Payment date The dividend checks are
mailed to shareholders of record. - Ex-dividend date A share of stock becomes
ex-dividend on the date the seller is entitled to
keep the dividend. At this point, the stock is
said to be trading ex-dividend.
44Dividend Discount Model
- What is the price of a stock on its ex-dividend
date? - Using the previous logic, we see that its simply
- where k is the appropriate discount rate to
discount the dividends consistent with their
riskiness. - We assume that the one-period ahead discount rate
is the same for all periods. That is, we use the
same rate to discount D1 to time 0, as we use to
discount D2 to time 1.
45Gordon Growth Model
- If we assume that the dividend is growing at a
rate of g per annum forever, this formula
simplifies to
- We see that the price of a stock is higher, the
higher the level of dividends, the higher the
growth rate of dividends and the lower the
required rate of return or the discount rate, k.
46Two essential concepts
- Cash flows at different points in time cannot be
compared and aggregated. All cash flows have to
be brought to the same point in time, before
comparisons and aggregations are made. - The concept of a Time Line
47Cash Flow Types and Discounting Mechanics
- There are five types of cash flows -
- simple cash flows,
- annuities,
- growing annuities
- perpetuities and
- growing perpetuities
48I. Simple Cash Flows
- A simple cash flow is a single cash flow in a
specified future time period. - Cash Flow CFt
- ____________________________________________
- Time Period t
- The present value of this cash flow is-
- PV of Simple Cash Flow CFt / (1r)t
- The future value of a cash flow is -
- FV of Simple Cash Flow CF0 (1 r)t
49Application The power of compounding - Stocks,
Bonds and Bills
- Between 1926 and 1998, Ibbotson Associates found
that stocks on the average made about 11 a year,
while government bonds on average made about 5 a
year. - If your holding period is one year,the
difference in end-of-period values is small - Value of 100 invested in stocks in one year
111 - Value of 100 invested in bonds in one year
105
50Holding Period and Value
51The Frequency of Compounding
- The frequency of compounding affects the future
and present values of cash flows. The stated
interest rate can deviate significantly from the
true interest rate - For instance, a 10 annual interest rate, if
there is semiannual compounding, works out to- - Effective Interest Rate 1.052 - 1 .10125 or
10.25 - The general formula isEffective Annualized Rate
(1r/m)m 1where m is the frequency of
compounding ( times per year), andr is the
stated interest rate (or annualized percentage
rate (APR) per year
52The Frequency of Compounding
53II. Annuities
- An annuity is a constant cash flow that occurs at
regular intervals for a fixed period of time.
Defining A to be the annuity, - A A A A
-
- 0 1 2 3 4
54Present Value of an Annuity
- The present value of an annuity can be calculated
by taking each cash flow and discounting it back
to the present, and adding up the present values.
Alternatively, there is a short cut that can be
used in the calculation A Annuity r
Discount Rate n Number of years
55Example PV of an Annuity
- The present value of an annuity of 1,000 at the
end of each year for the next five years,
assuming a discount rate of 10 is - - The notation that will be used in the rest of
these lecture notes for the present value of an
annuity will be PV(A,r,n).
56Annuity, given Present Value
- The reverse of this problem, is when the present
value is known and the annuity is to be estimated
- A(PV,r,n).
57Computing Monthly Payment on a Mortgage
- Suppose you borrow 200,000 to buy a house on a
30-year mortgage with monthly payments. The
annual percentage rate on the loan is 8. - The monthly payments on this loan, with the
payments occurring at the end of each month, can
be calculated using this equation - Monthly interest rate on loan APR/12 0.08/12
0.0067
58Future Value of an Annuity
- The future value of an end-of-the-period annuity
can also be calculated as follows-
59An Example
- Thus, the future value of 1,000 at the end of
each year for the next five years, at the end of
the fifth year is (assuming a 10 discount rate)
- - The notation that will be used for the future
value of an annuity will be FV(A,r,n).
60Annuity, given Future Value
- If you are given the future value and you are
looking for an annuity - A(FV,r,n) in terms of
notation -
Note, however, that the two formulas, Annuity,
given Future Value and Present Value, given
annuity can be derived from each other, quite
easily. You may want to simply work with a
single formula.
61Application Saving for College Tuition
- Assume that you want to send your newborn child
to a private college (when he gets to be 18 years
old). The tuition costs are 16000/year now and
that these costs are expected to rise 5 a year
for the next 18 years. Assume that you can
invest, after taxes, at 8. - Expected tuition cost/year 18 years from now
16000(1.05)18 38,506 - PV of four years of tuition costs at 38,506/year
38,506 PV(A ,8,4 years) 127,537 - If you need to set aside a lump sum now, the
amount you would need to set aside would be - - Amount one needs to set apart now
127,357/(1.08)18 31,916 - If set aside as an annuity each year, starting
one year from now - - If set apart as an annuity 127,537
A(FV,8,18 years) 3,405
62Valuing a Straight Bond
- You are trying to value a straight bond with a
fifteen year maturity and a 10.75 coupon rate.
The current interest rate on bonds of this risk
level is 8.5. - PV of cash flows on bond 107.50 PV(A,8.5,15
years) 1000/1.08515 1186.85 - If interest rates rise to 10,
- PV of cash flows on bond 107.50 PV(A,10,15
years) 1000/1.1015 1,057.05 - Percentage change in price -10.94
- If interest rate fall to 7,
- PV of cash flows on bond 107.50 PV(A,7,15
years) 1000/1.0715 1,341.55 - Percentage change in price 13.03
63III. Growing Annuity
- A growing annuity is a cash flow growing at a
constant rate for a specified period of time. If
A is the current cash flow, and g is the expected
growth rate, the time line for a growing annuity
looks as follows
64Present Value of a Growing Annuity
- The present value of a growing annuity can be
estimated in all cases, but one - where the
growth rate is equal to the discount rate, using
the following model - In that specific case, the present value is equal
to the nominal sums of the annuities over the
period, without the growth effect.
65The Value of a Gold Mine
- Consider the example of a gold mine, where you
have the rights to the mine for the next 20
years, over which period you plan to extract
5,000 ounces of gold every year. The price per
ounce is 300 currently, but it is expected to
increase 3 a year. The appropriate discount rate
is 10. The present value of the gold that will
be extracted from this mine can be estimated as
follows
66IV. Perpetuity
- A perpetuity is a constant cash flow at regular
intervals forever. The present value of a
perpetuity is-
67Valuing a Consol Bond
- A consol bond is a bond that has no maturity and
pays a fixed coupon. Assume that you have a 6
coupon console bond. The value of this bond, if
the interest rate is 9, is as follows - - Value of Consol Bond 60 / .09 667
68V. Growing Perpetuities
- A growing perpetuity is a cash flow that is
expected to grow at a constant rate forever. The
present value of a growing perpetuity is - - where
- CF1 is the expected cash flow next year,
- g is the constant growth rate and
- r is the discount rate.
69Valuing a Stock with Growing Dividends
- Southwestern Bell paid dividends per share of
2.73 in 1992. Its earnings and dividends have
grown at 6 a year between 1988 and 1992, and are
expected to grow at the same rate in the long
term. The rate of return required by investors on
stocks of equivalent risk is 12.23. - Current Dividends per share 2.73
- Expected Growth Rate in Earnings and Dividends
6 - Discount Rate 12.23
- Value of Stock 2.73 1.06 / (.1223 -.06)
46.45
70What are bonds?
- A borrowing arrangement where the borrower issues
an IOU to the investor.
Time
0
Price
Coupon Payments Coupon Rate x FV/ 2 Paid
semiannually
1
Investor
Issuer
2
.
.
Face Value (FV)
T
71Bond Pricing
- A T-period bond with coupon payments of C per
period and a face value of F. - The value of this bond can be computed as the sum
of the present value of the annuity component of
the bond plus the present value of the FV, where
is the present value of an - annuity of 1 per period for T periods, with a
discount rate of r per period.
72Bonds with semi-annual coupons
- Normally, bonds pay semi-annual coupons
- The bond value is given by
- where the first component is, once again, the
present value of an annuity, and y is the bonds
yield-to-maturity.
73Bond Pricing Example
- If F 100,000 T 8 years the coupon rate is
10, and the bonds yield-to-maturity is 8.8,
the bond's price is computed as -
-
-
106,789.52
74The Relation between Bond Prices and Yields
- Consider a 2 year, 10 coupon bond with a 1000
face value. If the bond yield is 8.8, the price
is 50 1000/(1.044)4 1021.58. - Now suppose the market bond yield drops to 7.8.
The market price is now given by 50
1000/(1.039)4 1040.02. - As the bond yield drops, the bond price rises,
and vice-versa.
75Bond Prices and YieldsA Graphic View
76Bond Yield MeasurementDefinitions
- Yield to MaturityA measure of the average rate
of return on a bond if held to maturity. To
compute it, we define the length of a period as 6
months, and then calculate the internal rate of
return per period. Finally, we double the
six-monthly IRR to get the bond equivalent yield,
or yield to maturity. This is more commonly used
in the marketplace. - Effective Annual YieldTake the six-monthly IRR
and annualize it by compounding. This measure is
less commonly used.
77Bond Yield Measurement Examples
- An 8 coupon, 30-year bond is selling at
1276.76. First solve the following equation -
- This equation is solved by r 0.03. (You will
see later how to solve this equation.) - The yield-to-maturity is given by 2 x 0.03 6
- The effective annual yield is given by (1.03)2 -
1 6.09
78Computing YTM by Trial and Error
- A 3 year, 8 coupon, 1000 bond, selling for
949.22 - Period Cash flow Present Value
- 9 11 10
- 1 40 38.28 37.91 38.10
- 2 40 36.63 35.94 36.28
- 3 40 35.05 34.06 34.55
- 4 40 33.54 32.29 32.91
- 5 40 32.10 30.61 31.34
- 6 1040 798.61 754.26 776.06
- Total 974.21 925.07 949.24
- The bond is selling at a discount hence the
yield exceeds the coupon rate. At a discount
rate equal to the coupon rate of 8, the price
would be 1000. Hence try a discount rate of 9.
At 9, the PV is 974.21, which is too high. Try a
higher discount rate of 11, with a PV of
925.07, which is too low. Trying 10, which is
between 9 and 11, the PV is exactly equal to
the price. Hence the bond yield 10.
79Computing YTM by Trial and Error A Graphic View
80Coupons and Yields
- A bond that sells for more than its face value is
called a premium bond. - The coupon on such a bond will be greater than
its yield-to-maturity. - A bond that sells for less than its face value is
called a discount bond. - The coupon rate on such a bond will be less than
its yield-to-maturity. - A bond that sells for exactly its face value is
called a par bond. - The coupon rate on such a bond is equal to its
yield.
81Non-flat Term Structures
- There is an implicit assumption made in the
previous slide that the annualized discount rate
is independent of when the cashflows occur. - That is, if 100 to paid in year 1 are worth
94.787 today, resulting in an implicit discount
rate of (100/94.787 -1) 5.5, then 100 to be
paid in year 2 are worth (in todays dollars),
100/(1.055)2 89.845. However, this need not
be so. - Demand and supply for year 1 dollars need not be
subject to the same forces as demand and supply
for year 2 dollars. Hence we might have the 1
year discount rate be 5.5, the year 2 discount
rate 6 and the year 3 discount rate 6.5
82Non-flat Term Structures
- If we now have a 10 coupon FV1000 three year
bond, which will have cash flows of 100 in year
1, 100 in year 2 and 1100 in year 3, its price
will be computed as the sum of 100/(1.055)
94.787, 100/(1.06)2 89.00 and 100/(1.065)3
910.634 for a total of 1094.421. - We could, at this point, compute the
yield-to-maturity of this bond using the formula
given above. If we do this, we will find that
the yield-to-maturity is 6.439 per annum. - This is not the discount rate for the first or
the second or the third cashflow. Rather, the
yield-to-maturity must, in general, be
interpreted as a (harmonic) average of the actual
discount rates for the different cashflows on the
bond, with more weight being given to the
discount rates for the larger cashflows.
83Yield Curves for Feb. 1-12, 2008
Date 1mo 3mo 6mo 1yr 2yr 3yr 5yr 7yr 10yr 20yr 30yr
02/01/08 1.75 2.10 2.15 2.13 2.09 2.22 2.75 3.13 3.62 4.31 4.32
02/04/08 2.15 2.27 2.22 2.17 2.08 2.23 2.78 3.18 3.68 4.37 4.37
02/05/08 2.22 2.19 2.13 2.06 1.93 2.08 2.66 3.08 3.61 4.32 4.33
02/06/08 2.12 2.10 2.10 2.05 1.96 2.11 2.67 3.08 3.61 4.36 4.37
02/07/08 2.19 2.17 2.13 2.08 1.99 2.21 2.79 3.21 3.74 4.50 4.51
02/08/08 2.24 2.23 2.12 2.05 1.93 2.10 2.69 3.11 3.64 4.41 4.43
02/11/08 2.35 2.31 2.13 2.06 1.93 2.10 2.67 3.09 3.62 4.38 4.41
02/12/08 2.55 2.31 2.12 2.06 1.94 2.13 2.71 3.13 3.66 4.43 4.46
84Yield Curves for Feb. 1-12, 2008
85Time Pattern of Bond Prices
- Bonds, like any other asset, represent an
investment by the bondholder. - As such, the bondholder expects a certain total
return by way of capital appreciation and coupon
yield. - This implies a particular pattern of bond price
movement over time.
86Time Pattern of Bond Prices Graphic View
Assuming yields are constant and coupons are
paid continuously
87Time Pattern of Bond Prices in Practice
- Coupons are paid semi-annually. Hence the bond
price would increase at the required rate of
return between coupon dates. - On the coupon payment date, the bond price would
drop by an amount equal to the coupon payment. - To prevent changes in the quoted price in the
absence of yield changes, the price quoted
excludes the amount of the accrued coupon. - Example An 8 coupon bond quoted at 96 5/32 on
March 31, 2008, paying its next coupon on June
30, 2008 would actually require payment of
961.5625 0.5(80/2) 981.5625