Title: Economics of HumanEnvironment Interactions, Lecture 3
1The political economy of environmental
regulationContent from Hackett 2001, Hackett
2006, and Keohane et al. 1998
Sept. 10, 2008
2What is the New Political Economy?
- Rational choice models which develop linkages
between - Institutional structures of the political process
- Preferences and influence of decision makers
- Preferences and influence of those affected by
regulations - Political economy models are expressed in terms
of both supply and demand and game-theoretic
frameworks
3Why develop political economy models?
- Understand government failure--when policy
makers fail to implement economically mandated
policies - Explain and predict particular policy outcomes
- Understand what factors may influence adoption or
rejection of particular policies - Develop legislative and regulatory proposals that
are politically as well as economically feasible
4Positive Political Economy (Hackett)
- Investigates how observed policy outcomes can be
explained by political institutions, policymaker
preferences, and the relative power of interest
groups. - Policy outcomes will often be quite different
than what a benign social planner would choose.
5Example of Positive Political Economy
- Investigate the role of campaign contributions in
explaining post-election voting.
6Normative political economy (Hackett)
- Identifies good policy outcomes (consistent
with a particular value system) and investigates
how, given the existing political constraints,
these good policy outcomes can be realized. - Focus on optimal governance and regulatory
structures
7Example of Normative Political Economy
- Lumber companies (or labor unions if you prefer)
form a political action committee, construct a
set of desired policy outcomes, and contribute to
those candidates most likely to support the
desired policy outcomes.
8Early work The Public Choice school
- Assumes that policy makers are motivated by
incentives such as ideology, wealth, reelection,
and power, rather than only the well-being of
their constituents - From this framework, develops a model of the
supply of legislation and/or administrative rules - For example, Kalt Zupan (1984) explain voting
behavior in terms of both ideology and the need
to gain support of voters to remain in office.
9Early work the Capture Theory of Regulation
- Develops one model of demand for regulatory
policy - Based on the work of Stigler and Pelzman
- An individual firm may bear high costs of
regulation, while an individual member of the
public may bear low costs - Cost of organizing firms is low due to low
numbers - Individual firms or industries may therefore
capture the regulatory process
10What makes for an effective interest group?
(Stigler and Petlzman)
- The amount that each individual has at stake.
Having more at stake means the individual will
invest more money and effort. - The size of the group. Smaller groups are easier
to organize and can more quickly come to
agreement than large groups.
11Support for this theory
- Revolving door deal employment of former
legislators by regulated firms - Analysis of political contributions LA Times
report found the most heavily regulated firms
tended to be largest political contributors
12Putting the pieces together Keohane et al.
- Regulators (legislators or administrators)
participate in production of legislation (supply) - Interest groups (firms, consumers,
environmentalists) demand regulation - Level of regulation is determined through
intersection of supply and demand - A purely competitive market is assumed
13Keohane Fig. 1
14The demand side
- Legislation is a public good therefore, group
WTP is expressed as the vertical sum of
individual members marginal benefit from
regulation - Public good nature of regulation also implies
incentive for free-riding therefore, demand
curve represents the upper limit of support - Organization into interest groups can overcome
some free-ridership issues - Political support may be expressed in terms of
financial contributions, endorsements, votes, and
volunteer effort
15Examples of interest groups
- Trade asc. Organize to reduce costs, gain
subsidies and barriers to entry, constrain
substitutes, and create an environment conducive
to collusion - Environmental groups lobby to preserve or restore
environment and natural resources - Consumer groups seek lower product prices and
product quality assurance - Workers seek more jobs, higher pay, trade
restrictions, and better working conditions
16The supply side
- Legislators supply function depends on three
components - Opportunity cost of effort of support (depends on
payoffs to alternative legislation) (increasing
marginal cost) - Psychological cost of support (depends on
ideology may be positive) (constant marginal
cost) - Cost of lost (or gained) votes from electoral
constituents (constant marginal cost)
17Keohane et al., figure 4
18Keohane, Figure 5
19Political equilibrium
20Equilibria, cont.
- Figure assumes aggregated demand and supply among
interest groups and legislators - In certain cases (Figure 7), the shape of supply
and demand curves imply no legislation will be
provided. - In other cases legislation will be provided
without lobbying - The institutional structure of legislation may
determine the ultimate outcome
21What might shift equilibrium? (Hackett)
- Addition of an interest group could shift the
demand curve upwards, resulting in higher
political currency and effective support - An increase in electoral constituent support for
regulation would shift the supply for legislation
upwards, also resulting in a higher level of
political currency and effective support - Other examples?
22Demand-side explanations for preference for CC
regulations
- Firms oppose instruments that shift costs to
industry (ex pollution taxes) - Some regulations can create barriers to entry,
reduce production, and increase profits (ex
environmental standards) - Individual firms may support regulations that
increase their costs, if the costs of other firms
are increased more
23Demand-side explanations for preference for CC
regulations, cont.
- Environmental groups preference may be affected
by donor contributions - Most env. Groups are hostile towards market-based
instruments, as they are seen as providing
license to pollute. - Market-based programs may be harder to change
than CC programs - Taxes are even harder to change
- Market-based instruments can create regional
hotspots of pollution
24Demand-side explanations for preference for CC
regulations, more
- Labor may oppose tradable permits because they
often lead to closure of less efficient firms - While consumer would theoretically favor
market-based approaches, since they lead to lower
product costs, consumers have not been strong on
environmental regulation
25Supply-side explanations for preferences for CC
regulations
- Legislators and staff may have a better
understanding of, and therefore favor, CC
policies - Support for market-based vs. CC may depend on
ideological bent--more vs. less government
intervention - Costs are more visible for market-based
approaches and may therefore lead to less
electoral constituent support - Legislators may engage in symbolic support
strict standards can be combined with less-public
exemptions - CC approaches involve less uncertainty for
risk-averse policy makers - CC approaches offer more control for congress
with respect to implementation
26Applications Downing (Hackett)
- 3 actors polluter, those bearing pollution, and
regulator - Regulators seeks jointly to maximize their power
and protect the environment - Model finds a relationship between lobbying by
firms and type of regulations (fees vs.
technology standards, for example)
27Applications Milliman and Price Hackett
- Studies firms incentives for RD and patenting
new technologies - Argue that successful innovators may push for
higher levels of regulation that put them at a
competitive advantage over other firms
28Applications Maxwell, Lyon, and Hackett
- Firms may self-regulate in order to placate
interest groups and stave off more stringent
regulations - Argued that provision of TRI data made
environment organization easier data provision
therefore induced voluntary abatement by firms - Data are consistent with the predictions of their
model emissions have fallen with TRI info
29Political Economy of the Montreal Protocol
(Hackett)
- The Montreal Protocol is an international treaty
that limits the use of halocarbons that harm the
stratospheric ozone layer.
In studying the political economy of the Montreal
Protocol and the role of DuPont and the British
chemical firm ICI, Oye and Maxwell developed the
concept of Olsonian and Stiglerian political
circumstances.
30Political Economy of the Montreal Protocol
(Hackett)
- In Olsonian political circumstances (named after
Mancur Olson), the benefits of environmental
regulation are more diffuse, spread thinly across
many entities, while regulatory costs are more
concentrated, weighing heavily on a few entities.
In Olsonian situations the many who receive
relatively small benefits from regulation have
little incentive to invest in policy influence
activities, and face high organizational and
coordination costs because of their large numbers.
31Political Economy of the Montreal Protocol
(Hackett)
- Thus in Olsonian situations it is more difficult
to get stable systems of regulation, meaning that
regulatory controls for protecting the
environment, for example, are relatively likely
to be overturned due to the lobbying efforts of
the few who bear the costs.
32Political Economy of the Montreal Protocol
(Hackett)
- In Stiglerian political circumstances (named
after George Stigler), the benefits of
environmental regulation are more concentrated,
heavily benefiting a few entities, while
regulatory costs are more diffuse, weighing
lightly on many entities.
In Stiglerian situations the few who receive
relatively large benefits from regulation have a
strong incentive to invest in policy influence
activities, and face low organizational and
coordination costs because of their small numbers.
33Political Economy of the Montreal Protocol
(Hackett)
- Thus in Stiglerian situations it is relatively
easier to get stable systems of regulation,
meaning that regulatory controls for protecting
the environment, for example, are relatively
likely to be created and maintained due to the
lobbying efforts of the few who receive the
benefits.
34Political Economy of the Montreal Protocol
(Hackett)
- Oye and Maxwell argue that the Montreal Protocol,
which outlawed CFC production by the year 2000,
gave a particularly strong advantage to firms
like Du Pont that came up with CFC alternatives
over their rivals that did not. In particular,
Oye and Maxwell state that
Du Pont and Imperial Chemical Industries, Ltd.
(ICI) experience with restrictions on CFCs
represents a classic Stiglerian illustration of
producers benefiting from regulations mandating
product substitution (pp. 19394).
35Social Choice Theory
- Social choice theory is a part of political
theory concerned with collective decision-making,
such as through voting in a democratic system of
self-governance.
The seminal work in this field is by Nobel prize
winning economist Kenneth Arrow in his 1951 book
Social Choice and Individual Values (NY John
Wiley)
36Social Choice Theory
- One of the most prominent advancements in social
choice theory is the Median Voter Theorem (aka
median voter model).
Consider an election with the following
characteristics
Political candidates can (at least to some
degree) commit to a political position in the
minds of the voters
37Median Voter Theorem More Assumptions
- Voters have single-peaked preferences, or policy
bliss points, and can be described by a
distribution function arraying them in a simple
two dimensional policy space (e.g., left vs.
right). If there is an odd number of voters, the
median voter lies in the middle of the
distribution.
38Median Voter Theorem More Assumptions
- There are two candidates seeking election to a
single member district (e.g., US House of
Representatives districts, CA State Senate or
Assembly districts). - The voting rule is that only one candidate can
win (winner-takes-all) based on a plurality
rule (candidate with the most votes wins).
39Median Voter Theorem
- Under these conditions, the plurality winner (or
for that matter a simple majority winner) will
position herself to advocate for the bliss point
of the median voter.
In other words, under these conditions the
candidates have a dominant strategy of advocating
a centerist platform consistent with winning the
median voter, as well as all the voters on either
one side OR the other of the median.
40Median Voter Theorem
If parties A and B want to capture the median
voter, they should move towards the center. The
red and blue areas represent the voters that A
and B expect they have already captured.
41Median Voter Theorem
- Most elections in the U.S. feature single member
district (winner-takes-all) plurality (or simple
majority) voting rules SMDP voting.
If the election can be described as a location
game in which the two politicians first commit
to a location in policy space, and then voters
vote for the candidate closest to their bliss
point, then the Nash equilibrium (and dominant
strategy equilibrium) is for both politicians to
commit to a location proximate to the median
voter.
42Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- Hackett studied voting rules in CPR systems in
which the appropriators are heterogeneous (e.g.,
fishermen wth large vs. small vessels). Suppose
that the CPR system has been abused from overuse,
and the appropriators have organized to reduce
overall appropriation levels in order to manage
the CPR more sustainably. The question is how the
overall reduction in use will be divided among
the individual appropriators.
43Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- Inclusive voting rules require a supermajority
agreement in order for a proposal to pass. They
are inclusive in that they require the consent of
a supermajority. Consensus and unanimity are
examples. - Exclusive voting rules allow proposals to pass
with plurality or simple majority agreement.
44Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- Rule systems that change the original status quo
shares of total resource appropriation
redistribute wealth from one type of appropriator
to another, and are therefore more likely to
generate conflict.
45Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- Hackett identified the following trade-off
heterogeneous CPR appropriator groups with highly
inclusive voting rules (such as consensus) will
take a longer time to reach agreement because
such voting rules make it easier to block
agreements. This delay allows the CPR to continue
to decline in productivity. Distributional rules
that are approved, however, are less likely to
result in large redistributions of wealth
relative to the status quo, and so individual
appropriators are less likely to fight and
violate such rules, reducing future monitoring
and enforcement costs.
46Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- In contrast exclusive voting rules, such as
plurality or simple majority, reach agreement
more rapidly, and so repair of the CPR system is
not delayed. Yet if the majority does manage to
impose rules that redistribute wealth from the
minority to the majority, the agreement is more
likely to be fought and violated by the minority
in the future, resulting in higher monitoring and
enforcement costs.
47Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- Hackett, Schlager, and Walker (1994) used
laboratory experimental techniques (controlled
and paid role-play exercises) to look at how
heterogeneous CPR appropriator groups resolve
this tradeoff. - They found that appropriators tended to select
allocation rules proportionate with historical
appropriation, and were able to reach agreements
without excessive delays or conflicts.
48Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- The effects of appropriator heterogeneity and
voting rules on the performance of CPR governance
structures have been looked at for the case of
oil and gas fields by Wiggins and Libecap (1985)
and Libecap and Wiggins (1985).
49Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- Oil and Gas
- Self-governance of oil fields is more likely to
succeed if there is minimal heterogeneity among
the appropriators (e.g., differences in
productivity). - Self-governance of oil fields is more likely to
succeed if voting rules are more exclusive (e.g.,
63 percent vs. unanimity voting rules).
50Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- Johnson and Libecap (1982) provide a similar
analysis of the Texas Gulf Coast shrimp fishery,
where shrimpers vary with regard to fishing
skill. Heterogeneity in fishing skill created
conflict over the type of government fishery
regulations the various fishermen preferred For
example, total fishing effort could be restricted
through uniform quotas for eligible fishermen.
But if fishermen are heterogeneous, uniform
quotas will be costly to assign and enforce
because of opposition from more productive
fishermen (p. 1010).
51Application of Social Choice Theory to
Self-Governance of Local CPRs
- Field research generally indicates that rules
linking CPR harvest shares to an appropriators
historical level of harvest (tons of fish landed,
acre-feet of irrigation water) or contribution
(contributions for CPR upkeep, monitoring, or
enforcement) are far more common than rules that
simply divide CPR output equally. There is an
aspect of fairness in rewarding greater
contributions with larger shares, and sharing
rules that differ markedly from historical use
patterns tend to undermine individual cooperation
with group efforts directed at sustaining the
commons.
52No short writing assignment for next week!
- Catch up on introductory readings
- Review any theory that you need to
- Get a head start on the sustainability and growth
model readings - Think about term projects