Simulating%20Social%20Networks - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Simulating%20Social%20Networks

Description:

An Answer to the Macro-Micro Link? September 27, 2006, NIH ... presentation has been supported by NIH grants DA12831, HD41877, and AG024050. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:136
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 69
Provided by: James9
Learn more at: https://people.duke.edu
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Simulating%20Social%20Networks


1
Simulating Social Networks
James Moody Duke University
The Population Sciences and Agent Based
Methodology An Answer to the Macro-Micro
Link? September 27, 2006, NIH
Work reported in this presentation has been
supported by NIH grants DA12831, HD41877, and
AG024050. Thanks to the Center for Advanced
Study in the Behavioral Sciences (CASBS) for
office and tech support for this work.
2
Introduction Network Structure Puzzles
Distribution of Popularity
By size and city type
Why are high school popularity distributions
constant across vastly different communities ?
3
Introduction Network Structure Puzzles
Add Health relational change statistics
How can the global structure remain constant
given massive changes at the dyad level?
4
Introduction Network Structure Puzzles
What rules can account for adolescent romantic
network structure?
5
Introduction Network Structure Puzzles
Why are academic PhD exchange markets
(hiring/placing) strongly centralized
Han, S-K. Social Networks 2003251-280. Figure 1
6
Introduction Network Structure Puzzles
Burris, ASR 2004
and positions within systems stable over
generations?
7
Introduction Network Structure Puzzles
  • In each case, the interdependent activity of
    each actor affects the conditions shaping action
    for everyone else in the setting.
  • History matters in a deterministic (rather than
    stochastic) sense
  • The process shaping actors choices are locally
    bounded
  • The resulting network structure is often very far
    from a random null.
  • Statistical Models fail for either data or deep
    endogeneity reasons.
  • Actor-oriented simulation methods
  • Provide a way of thinking about interdependent
    action
  • Create multiple replications with known variation
    on independent variables.

8
Introduction outline
  • Introduction
  • Micro Macro elements in social networks
  • Colemans boat
  • Structural correlates of micro macro
  • Linking rules to structures
  • Simulation Network Structure
  • Dynamics of adolescent friendship structure
  • Adolescent romantic exogamy
  • Inequality in PhD exchange networks
  • Network Diffusion Disease Spread
  • Degree mixing models
  • Relational timing
  • Promises Pitfalls
  • Good Theoretical rigor, clarity, elegance
  • Bad How to test against observed data
  • Ugly Rule proliferation specification

9
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Colemans Boat
Contextual State
Global Outcome
Macro
1
Resulting Action
Micro
Individual Response
1) Macro ? Micro Typically contextual
conditions that enable/constrain individual
action.
10
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Colemans Boat
Contextual State
Global Outcome
Macro
1
Resulting Action
2
Micro
Individual Response
  1. Macro ? Micro Typically contextual conditions
    that enable/constrain individual action.
  2. Micro ? Micro A direct-action correlate of the
    contextually constrained behavior in (1)

11
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Colemans Boat
Contextual State
Global Outcome
Macro
3
1
Resulting Action
2
Micro
Individual Response
  • Macro ? Micro Typically contextual conditions
    that enable/constrain individual action.
  • Micro ? Micro A direct-action correlate of the
    contextually constrained behavior in (1)
  • Micro ? Macro An aggregation or interaction
    process that can account for the new global-level
    outcome.

12
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Colemans Boat
4
Contextual State
Global Outcome
Macro
3
1
Resulting Action
2
Micro
Individual Response
  • Macro ? Micro Typically contextual conditions
    that enable/constrain individual action.
  • Micro ? Micro A direct-action correlate of the
    contextually constrained behavior in (1)
  • Micro ? Macro An aggregation or interaction
    process that can account for the new global-level
    outcome.
  • The observed macro-level correlation is thus
    accounted for by actors capable of intent and
    action.

13
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Colemans Boat
Of these 4 links, the 3rd is often the trickiest.
Here we face questions about emergent
properties features of the macro system that
cannot be seen as simple (mean, sum, proportion)
aggregations of individual action, but instead
are seen as some interactive effect of the
combined action.
Social facts assume a shape, a tangible form
peculiar to them and constitute a reality sui
generis vastly distinct from the individual facts
which manifest that reality Durkheim
Rules Of Sociological Method
14
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Network micro features Anything you can measure
on a local ego-network.
Ego-Net
15
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Local-romantic Networks
16
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Complete Network
17
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Network micro features Anything you can measure
on a local ego-network.
Purely local information on ego about egos
contacts Number of ties (degree) node
attribute mixing
1
2
e
3
4
18
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Network macro features Features resting on (a)
paths of length gt 2.
The key element that makes a network a system is
the path its how sets of actors are linked
together indirectly. A walk is a sequence of
nodes and lines, starting and ending with nodes,
in which each node is incident with the lines
following and preceding it in a sequence. A path
is a walk where all of the nodes and lines are
distinct. Paths are the routes through networks
that make diffusion possible, they govern
connectivity, clustering and reflect clump
structure as well.
19
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Network macro features Features resting on (a)
paths of length gt 2.
B
A
These two graphs have the exact same local
properties, but very different global properties.
20
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Network macro features Features resting on (b)
the distribution of local features.
Distribution of Popularity
By size and city type
21
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Network macro features Features resting on (b)
the distribution of local features.
22
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Network macro features Features resting on (b)
the distribution of local features.
23
Micro-Macro elements in social networks
Structural correlates of micro and macro
Network macro features Features resting on (c)
outcomes distributed across nodes.
Define as a general measure of the diffusion
susceptibility of a graph as the ratio of the
area under the observed curve to the area under a
random baseline curve. As the ratio ? 1.0, you
get effectively faster diffusion.
24
Micro-Macro elements in social networks Linking
actor rules to network structure
  • For most simulation settings, we are often
    interested in identifying behavioral rules that
    (a) fit the micro network features of interest
    and (b) give rise (in combination) to the global
    features of interest.
  • Types of network rules
  • Node volume features (number of ties)
  • Dyadic Interaction features (reciprocity,
    race-mixing rules)
  • Indirect interaction features (Social balance,
    relational exogamy rules)
  • Timing rule (relation duration, concurrency, and
    order)

25
Micro-Macro elements in social networks Linking
actor rules to network structure
For most simulation settings, we are often
interested in identifying behavioral rules that
(a) fit the micro network features of interest
and (b) give rise (in combination) to the global
features of interest. Two ways to think of
rule-action links for network modesl Explanatio
n Identifying a (small) set of rules that, when
applied, account for feature difficult to explain
otherwise. Examples Adolescent friendship
dynamics Romantic network structure PhD
Exchange network structure Stability Explorati
on Start with a set of local rules you are
confident in, then apply to a setting to learn
what system-level features emerge.. Examples D
iffusion potential of low-degree
networks Diffusion constraints resulting from
relational timing
26
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
  • Sociologist revel in the diversity of social
    settings, but a primary motivation for theories
    of social structure is to explain common features
    across settings and account for social
    differentiation endogenously. Consider
  • Cartwright, Harary, Davis, Leinhardt Clustering
    in social networks
  • Axelrod Social Cooperation in competitive
    settings
  • Chase The development of hierarchy
  • Johnsen Process agreement models for social
    hierarchy
  • Gould Peer influence embellishments on quality
    stratification
  • Mark Social Differentiation from first
    principles
  • McFarland Development of ritualized structure in
    dynamic networks
  • Adolescent school networks vary on myriad
    exogenous factors, such as the distribution of
    race, SES, grades, health behaviors and so forth.
    But what features are common across these
    diverse settings and how can we explain them?

27
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
  • Data
  • I use the National Longitudinal Survey of
    Adolescent Health (Add Health). This is a
    nationally representative survey of adolescents
    in school (7th through 12 grade), with
    (approximately) complete network data in 129
    schools, including data over time for a smaller
    subset of schools.
  • These data are available through the Carolina
    Population Center
  • Methods
  • Features of the global network structure are
    identified through triad distribution methods and
    block models
  • Specific hypotheses about social balance are
    tested with exponential random graph models
  • Dynamic implications for these models are derived
    from simulation studies grounded in the observed
    data.

28
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
A periodic table of social elements
(0)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
003
012
102
111D
201
210
300
021D
111U
120D
021U
030T
120U
021C
030C
120C
29
Dynamic Social Balance Adolescent Friendship
Networks Triad distributions
A periodic table of social elements
Type Number of
triads ---------------------------------------
1 - 003 21 ----------------------
----------------- 2 - 012 26
3 - 102 11 4 - 021D
1 5 - 021U 5 6 -
021C 3 7 - 111D
2 8 - 111U 5 9 - 030T
3 10 - 030C 1
11 - 201 1 12 - 120D
1 13 - 120U 1 14 -
120C 1 15 - 210
1 16 - 300
1 --------------------------------------- Sum (2
- 16) 63
30
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
Triads encapsulate local behavior rules
(0)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
003
012
102
111D
201
210
300
021D
111U
120D
021U
030T
120U
021C
030C
120C
31
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
  • Traditional social balance models tested the
    theory against observed triad distributions. If
    there were more of the all balanced triads and
    fewer of the contradictory triads, then the
    data were (more or less) consistent with the
    theory.
  • Lots of evidence in the cross section supporting
    balance models, but almost always unable to
    account for the over-representation of mixed
    triad types.
  • Cross-sectional models assume a dynamic system
    that has finished where there are no
    actor-level incentives to make further change.
  • But while observed networks often fit a balance
    model, they also have massive amounts of change
    at the local level and thus cant possibly fit
    the finished state proposed by the model.

32
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
For the 129 Add Health school networks, the
observed distribution of the tau test statistic
for various triad distribution models is
Suggesting that the ranked-cluster models beat
random chance in all schools.
33
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
Triads observed in excess
Eugene Johnsen (1985, 1986) specifies a number of
structures that result from various triad
configurations
Ranked Cluster
34
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
  • These results (w. more detail) suggest that
  • Most of the school networks have a rank-strata
    structure
  • The structure remains even though nearly half of
    all relationships are new
  • Peoples position in the popularity distribution
    is fluid
  • What models allow us to explain a stable
    macro-structure in the face of dynamic relations?

35
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
  • Two crucial insights help inform a (slightly)
    modified approach to social balance
  • Triples instead of triads. Operationalizing
    balance theory as transitivity allows us to
    simplify the behavioral assumptions (cf. Hummel
    and Soduer (1987, 1990)), but at the cost of
    divorcing the behavior from the macro-structure
    implications of previous triad based models.
  • Structural implications differ depending on your
    point of view. Because transitivity is directed
    from a particular egos point of view, the same
    structure will be experienced differently by each
    person in the network.
  • Carley and Krackhardt (1996) show this clearly at
    the relationship level, and we would expect
    similar effects at the triple level. This implies
    that changes made by one person to alleviate
    strain, can create strain for others.
  • We can also distinguish transitivity seeking from
    the intransitivity avoidance.

36
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics
030C
120C
102
111U
021C
201
012
111D
300
003
210
021D
120U
vacuous transition
Increases transitive
Decreases intransitive
030T
Decreases transitive
Increases intransitive
021U
Vacuous triad
120D
Intransitive triad
Transitive triad
(some transitions will both increase transitivity
decrease intransitivity the effects are
independent they are colored here for net
balance)
37
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics Triad transition state-space
simulation
TRIAD
16
TRIAD
16
15
15
14
14
13
13
12
12
11
11
10
10
9
9
8
8
7
7
6
6
5
5
4
4
3
3
2
2
1
1
0
100
200
300
0
100
200
300
Avoid Intransitivity only (strong)
Favor Transitivity only (strong)
38
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics Testing model on observed
data
Standardized Coefficients from an Exponential
Random Graph Model
0.8
Endogenous
Focal Orgs.
Dyadic Similarity/Distance.
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
-0.2
-0.4
-0.6
GPA
SES
Fight
College
Drinking
Same Sex
Transitivity
Same Race
Both Smoke
Same Clubs
Intransitivity
Same Grade
Reciprocity
39
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics Actor-oriented simulation
model
  • Based on these results, I simulate network
    dynamics controlling the extent to which actors
    seek transitivity and avoid intransitivity.
  • This simulation builds on the empirical models in
    specifying separate effects for transitivity and
    intransitivity based on egos returns to a change
    in relations.
  • Adds a parameter to limit the marginal returns to
    forming new relations, that effectively dampens
    (but does not hard-code) out-degree. Plus a
    parameter that punishes continued asymmetry
    (Gould parameter).
  • Reciprocity dyad attribute parameters are held
    constant across all simulations.
  • Time is encoded as each nodes opportunity to
    change relations as iterations pass.

40
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics Actor-oriented simulation
model
Final Graph Transitivity
R2 0.82
Mean over the state space
41
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics Actor-oriented simulation
model
Structural Stability Correlation of network
structure at tfinal with t-5
R2 0.52
Mean over the state space
42
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics Actor-oriented simulation
model
Total Graph Transitivity At moderate
transitivity/intransitivity
A single simulation run, showing the wide swings
in graph transitivity. Similar trends evident in
reciprocity, though the number of arcs and
general shape (variance/skew) of the popularity
distribution does not fluctuate much.
43
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics Actor-oriented simulation
model
  • I think part of this process is affected by not
    paying close enough attention to the dyadic
    implications of repeated asymmetry. Consider
    these triads

As currently specified, the model rewards
reciprocation, but does not penalize asymmetry.
So if i?j, then j is more likely to nominate i,
but if j does not reciprocate, i has no
(independent) reason to change tie
patterns. Gould (AJS 2002), builds a model of
emergent hierarchy based (partially) on the
notion that people will not maintain a relation
that is not reciprocated. Building this
feature into the model will make these triads
temporarily attractive, but unstable in the long
run, which should lessen the tendency for
structures to lock-in on largely asymmetric
hierarchical structures.
44
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent
Friendship Dynamics Actor-oriented simulation
model
Dynamic simulation movie, representative
parameter weights.
Green ties are reciprocated, blue asymmetric.
45
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent Romantic
Networks
Explanation problem 1 Romantic relations at
Jefferson high school
Source Bearman, Moody and Stovel (2004) AJS
46
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent Romantic
Networks
Is the network typical? How does it compare to
random networks with the same micro-features?
Circle observed, boxplots simulated networks
w. same volume.
47
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent Romantic
Networks
Is the network typical? How does it compare to
random networks with the same micro-features?
The network is decidedly not random. Moreover,
typical network mixing features dont take us
very far (homophily on number of prior partners
helps constrain component size, and smoking
homophily is evident by inspection). We propose
a network exogamy rule a prohibition on cycles
of length 4
48
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent Romantic
Networks
We propose a network exogamy rule a prohibition
on cycles of length 4
Introduce a prohibition on forming 4-cycles in
the randomly simulated networks.
49
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent Romantic
Networks
We propose a network exogamy rule a prohibition
on cycles of length 4
Here we get a much closer match between the
simulated networks and the observed in each of
our test statistics
50
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent Romantic
Networks
We propose a network exogamy rule a prohibition
on cycles of length 4
and the simulated components have similar
qualitative structures as well.
51
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent Romantic
Networks
  • Evaluation
  • This single rule addition more than any other
    dyadic feature such as homophily on behavior or
    age mixing generates networks with the
    structure we observe in reality. Its
    theoretical simplicity is the strongest strength
    of the model. From a simulation methods
    standpoint, this is a very simple rule set
  • Constrain each actor to make the same number of
    partners observed in the real world
  • If a partner choice would close a 4-cycle, choose
    somebody else.

52
Simulating Network Structure Adolescent Romantic
Networks
Evaluation From an implementation standpoint,
the simulation is complicated by an empirical
identification problem there are many possible
configurations where these two constraints cannot
be met simultaneously. In the process of
making choices, we effectively run out of degrees
of freedom where any new choice would lead to a
violation in the degree distribution or create a
4-cycle. - Theoretically, this implies that the
real-world graph is coming from a fairly small
region of the overall graph space. -
Methodologically it means that using only a
simple rule-based simulation was computationally
inefficient. We solved this by adding graph
identification procedures that forced choices
once prior choices implied them. - This
difficutly followed from our desire to fit the
distributions exactly.
53
Simulating Network Structure Academic Castes
inequality in PhD exchange Networks
Explaination problem 2 Academic Caste Systems
I (N52)
II-a (N4)
II-b (N15)
II-c (N22)
II-d (N81)
III (N384)
Why is this network so hierarchical and stable?
Han, S-K. Social Networks 2003251-280. Figure 1
54
Simulating Network Structure Academic Castes
inequality in PhD exchange Networks
Particularly in settings, such as science, where
unversalism and meritocracy define the system
ethos?
  • Merton (1942,1968)
  • Two key features that shape the academic market
  • Universalistic criteria to evaluate quality
  • Mathew effect the cumulative advantage of
    prestige
  • Burris (2004239) states as fact that prestige is
    ascribed rather than achieved, arguing that
  • Moreover, through a process of cumulative
    advantage, academic scientists and scholars who
    secure employment in the more prestigious
    departments gain differential access to resources
    and rewards that enhance their prospects. This
    cycle results in a stratified system of
    departments and universities, ranked in terms of
    prestige, that is highly resistant to change.
    (p.239)

55
Simulating Network Structure Academic Castes
inequality in PhD exchange Networks
  • Two types of evidence are used to demonstrate
    non-universalistic effects
  • A less-than-perfect association between measures
    of faculty productivity and department rank /
    hiring (Long, Hargens, Jacobs, Baldi, Burris,
    Conrad-Black)
  • Burris shows that between 30 and 50 of the
    variance in NRC rankings can be accounted for
    with standard productivity measures
  • A strong correlation between simple number of
    faculty and prestige (r 0.63 in sociology).
  • Probability / prestige of first job due to origin
    of PhD over publication record (but see
    Cognard-Black, 2004 and below).

56
Simulating Network Structure Academic Castes
inequality in PhD exchange Networks
Two types of evidence are used to demonstrate
non-universalistic effects 2. An extreme
stability of department rankings over time
Burris, ASR 2004
The correlation in NRC faculty quality scores in
Sociology from 1982 to 1993 is 0.92
57
Simulating Network Structure Academic Castes
inequality in PhD exchange Networks
The resulting status-based network has a strong
correlation between centrality in the hiring
network quality ranking
Social Capital Bonacich Centrality on
symmetric version of the PhD exchange Network
58
Simulating Network Structure Academic Castes
inequality in PhD exchange Networks
How can we square universalistic scientific norms
with these facts?
First, research on markets and cultural
consumption suggests that quality is accurately
perceived particularly when external measures
show small differences (White 2002, J. Blau,
Bourdieu). Quality exists, whether
it's defined or not. - Robert Pirsig
(1972) That is, we know quality even if our
systematic measures of quality are poor, which is
reflected (in part) through market convergence on
particular candidates (see below).
59
Simulating Network Structure Academic Castes
inequality in PhD exchange Networks
How can we square universalistic scientific norms
with these facts?
Second, most data on the market structure
systematically selects on the dependent variable,
as only those who are eventually hired are
observed. This has the effect of a) limiting
variation on observed quality measures b) makes
it impossible to disentangle PhD volume from
placement Recent dissertation work by
Cognard-Black, for example, shows that the
independent effect of PhD institution on
placement is often lower than publication quality
measures, once you expand the sample of PhDs
beyond those hired to major research
universities.
60
Simulating Network Structure Academic Castes
inequality in PhD exchange Networks
Given the difficulty getting data on the general
process (rather than historically accidental
draws from that general process), a simulation is
an ideal way to explore the exchange market. In
systems with open markets, merit-based hiring
rational actors 1) How stable will quality
rankings be? 2) Will size and quality be
correlated? 3) Will network exchange centrality
predict quality? Each has been used as evidence
for non-meritocratic prestige systems, but we
dont know how the observed cases match the
expected cases, because we have no reasonable
null distribution. A key advantage of using a
simulation is to identify a range of reasonable
null distributions.
61
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Simulation
Setup
  • The purpose of this simulation is to examine the
    effect of market-relevant behavior under
    ideal-typical conditions. This involves
    simplifying the real world as much as possible,
    to isolate how particular factors affect outcomes
    of interest.
  • Key real-world properties of interest
  • Stable quality rankings
  • Strong correlation between size and quality
  • Centralized hiring networks
  • Strong correlation between centrality and
    prestige
  • Currently, all actors follow the same strategy,
    and I vary the strategy set across simulation
    runs.
  • Future work will vary department strategies
    within runs to see how these affect competitive
    advantage.

62
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Simulation
Setup
  • Actors
  • Departments Collections of faculty who hire
    applicants produce new students. (N100).
    Initial department size is drawn from a normal
    distribution with mean 25, std12, but I
    re-draw if size is less than 10, so the actual
    distribution is slightly skewed.
  • Applicants Students from (other) departments who
    apply for jobs.
  • Departments seek to hire the best students,
    students want to work at the best departments.
  • These actors are rational, honest, and
    risk-averse. But all actors have individual
    preferences errors in vision.
  • The simulation does not include tenure or senior
    moves. So you can treat this as the realized
    or final position outcomes.

63
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Simulation
Setup
  • Attributes
  • Quality. Each faculty member and student has an
    overall quality score.
  • Initial faculty quality is distributed as random
    normal(0,1).
  • Implies that departments are effectively equal at
    time 1with only minor differences due to random
    chance.
  • Student quality is a (specifiable) random
    function of faculty quality.
  • Department quality is the mean of faculty
    quality.
  • While each person has a given quality score,
    actor choices are made based on an evaluation of
    quality, which differs across actors.
  • This variation reflects both differences in
    preferences and ability to discern quality.

64
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Simulation
Setup
  • Action Departments
  • Departments hire produce students.
  • For each of 100 years
  • Every department produces students (conditional
    on size).
  • A (random) subset of departments have job
    openings based on (a) prior retirements current
    size relative to a target size.
  • Departments rank applicants by their evaluation
    of applicant quality, and make offers to their
    top choices.
  • If a departments 1st choice goes elsewhere, they
    go to next for a specifiable number of rounds to
    a specifiable depth into the pool.
  • Jobs can go unfilled, which means that
    departments can both grow and shrink.

65
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Simulation
Setup
Action Departments The probability a job opening
in any given year is a function of size
66
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Simulation
Setup
Action Departments Faculty size decreases
through retirement
67
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Simulation
Setup
  • Action Students
  • Students rank departments that make them an offer
    by their evaluation of department quality, and
    take the best job they are offered.
  • If a student does not receive a job offer in a
    given year, they move out of the system
  • Lots of students dont get jobs (at PhD granting
    universities)
  • Students are not strategic they do not forego a
    good offer while waiting for a better one --
    this is the risk averse quality, though this
    could be changed.

68
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks parameter
summary
Parameter Description Specification
Hiring probability Likelihood of a job opening beyond retirement replacement. Cubic function of department size. 3 levels
Student production Probability of each faculty member putting a student on the market in a given year. Binomial (0,1), p (0.06 to 0.08). 2 levels. X1 165 X2 220
Faulty - Student Quality Correlation The correlation between student and faculty quality. Specify as a correlation from 0.37 to 0.91 3 levels
Applicant Quality Evaluation Used by departments to rank applicants. Each department assigns applicants an observed quality score based on this function. Observed (Student quality) b(N(0,1)). b 0.3 to 0.9. 3 levels
Department Quality Evaluation Used by applicants to rank job offers. Each student assigns departments an observed quality score based on this function. Observed (Department quality) b(N(0,1)). B 0.1 to 0.25. 2 levels
Hiring Rounds Number of offer rounds made. Approximates time by limiting opportunity to make alternative offers. Specify as number. 3 or 4 2 levels
Depth of Search
How deeply into the pool of candidates
departments are willing to go.
Specify as max depth. 10 to 30 3 levels
There are 3233223 648 points in the
parameter space 30 draws from each set ? 19,440
observations
69
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks parameter
summary
A look under the hood
70
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Non-network
outcomes
Disagreement on Candidate Quality
0.3
0.6
0.9
10
20
Depth of Search
30
All results are presented around the competitive
field
71
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
  • Initial Conditions
  • 100 departments
  • Size distributed normally with mean of 25 std of
    12 and an initial floor of 10. This is the
    resource-based target size for departments.
  • Faculty quality is distributed normally (N(0,1))
  • Age is initially distributed uniformly from 0 to
    40 (starting with a distribution means that
    retirements dont go in waves)
  • Parameter Settings
  • Hiring curve Medium
  • Student Production 0.06 (150 applicants per
    year)
  • Student-Faculty Quality Correlation 0.67
  • Disagreement on applicant quality 0.60
  • Disagreement on department quality 0.1
  • Hiring Rounds 4
  • Depth of Search 20

72
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Market Size
  • Over the first 10 years
  • 66 to 104 positions advertised
  • 147 to 169 students on the market
  • 59 to 72 people were hired each year

73
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Student-Faculty Quality Correlation
Student Quality
r0.65
r0.49
Faculty Quality
Department Quality
74
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Distribution of size over time
75
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Correlation between final size and target size
Quality gt Mean 1std
Quality lt Mean 1std
Target Equality
Final Size
Target Size
76
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Distribution of quality over time
77
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Correlation of Size and Quality over time
Burris reports the correlation between size and
prestige as 0.63
78
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Correlation of Quality 10 years prior
79
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Non-network
outcomes
Size Quality Average Department Quality
Calculated at final year ( y100)
80
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Non-network
outcomes
Size Quality Correlation of Size and Quality
Calculated at final year ( y100)
81
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Correlation of Size and Quality over time
A single example run taken from the middle
competition cell.
Burris reports the correlation between size and
prestige as 0.63
82
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Non-network
outcomes
Quality Stability 10 Year Correlation of Quality
Calculated at final year ( y100)
83
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks A single
example run
Correlation of Quality 10 years prior
A single example run taken from the middle
competition cell.
84
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Non-network
outcomes
Calculated at final year ( y100)
85
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Network
outcomes
The production and hiring of PhDs generates an
exchange network, connecting the sending
department to the hiring department. Note that,
unlike many simulations, here the edges in the
network are actors (rather than simply the result
of node action). I record this network for all
hires in the last 10 years of the simulation
history, and construct two measures a) The
network centralization score b) The correlation
between network centrality quality size.
86
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Network
outcomes
For what follows, working within one region of
the parameter space
Disagreement on Candidate Quality
Depth of Search
A preliminary regression over the entire space
shows that hiring rates quality correlation
matter most for centralization
87
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Network
outcomes
Network Centralization by Quality Correlation
Job Openings
88
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Network
outcomes
Correlation of Centrality Department Size
Bonacich Centrality
89
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Network
outcomes
Correlation of Centrality Department Quality
Bonacich Centrality
90
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Network
outcomes
Most Productive Line (first sort selects here!)
OLS line
Real data from a all applicants for an open
position at a large Midwestern university
91
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Network
outcomes
92
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Tentative
conclusions
  • The very simple market model proposed here can
    account for many of the features we see in real
    PhD exchange markets
  • Stable quality rankings
  • Strong Correlation between Size Quality
  • Highly Centralized Networks
  • Correlation between Quality ranking and
    Centralization
  • Qualitatively, it is appears that you can order
    most of these networks with a pretty clear
    distinction between top or core departments
    and a periphery, characterized by asymmetric flow
    of students.

93
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Tentative
conclusions
  • There is still some room for non-market effects
    here, however, since the resulting hierarchies
    are not perfect
  • Self-selection effects
  • Students avoiding applying out of their league
  • Adjusting depth of search to be linked to current
    quality
  • Social Network Effects
  • Give a positive weight to students who come from
    departments where current faculty received their
    PhDs
  • Market Segmentation Effects
  • Add a dimension of substantive fit to the
    market model.
  • Should act as (a) an interaction boost for market
    competition effects
  • Will give sending advantages to large diverse
    departments.

94
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Tentative
conclusions
  • There are two broad features that shape these
    networks.
  • Market competition
  • Market competition factors (mainly agreement on
    quality depth of search, but also simple
    student production hiring rates) have a huge
    effect on the mean levels of department
    characteristics seen across the simulation
    settings.
  • When the competition for students is high, offers
    converge on small numbers of market stars. This
    generates a sellers market, where a small
    number of market stars dominate hiring patters,
    take jobs at the most prestigious institutions,
    leaving many departments with failed searches,
    and ultimately lowering the quality for the
    discipline as a whole.
  • This mechanism can account for much of the
    observed stability, growth and quality outcomes
    observed over the simulation runs

95
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Tentative
conclusions
  • There are two primary factors that drive system
    outcomes in this market simulation
  • The development of a hierarchical network
    exchange structure depends on a correlation
    between faculty and students, and though the
    effect appears not to be linear.
  • For the most part, a quality correlation
    re-inforces quality rankings due to the main
    reinforcement mechanism sketched below

96
Simulating Network Structure Persistent
inequality in PhD exchange Networks Tentative
conclusions
  • There are two primary factors that drive system
    outcomes in this market simulation
  • The development of a hierarchical network
    exchange structure depends on a correlation
    between faculty and students, though the effect
    is most evident in tight markets.
  • But when the correlation is too high, the
    inequality in student production starts to
    dominate. This has the result of
  • (a) flooding the market with relatively
    low-quality students, that
  • (b) has the effect of mirroring tight-market
    competition factors.
  • Since the hiring practices in this simulation
    were tied to quality ranks instead of cardinal
    values (or values relative to self), this means
    departments are forced by retirements to dig too
    deep in the pool, resulting in a lowering of
    overall quality, which then gets magnified.

97
Simulating Network Structure Exploratory
Simulation Epidemic Potential from Low-degree
networks
Problem 3 Exploration of STD relevant networks
  • In this case, we motivate the work with 4
    observations
  • STD Epidemics have to travel across a connected
    network
  • The connectivity structure should be robust
    since transmission is a low probability result
  • Infectivity is temporally sensitive for
    bacterial STDs the window is very short, for
    virus like HIV, infectivity probability is
    highest early and late.
  • This implies that the connected set needs to
    occupy a short infectivity window, which severely
    limits the number of partners most people will
    have (i.e. lifetime partner distributions are
    largely irrelevant).
  • A great deal of recent attention has been placed
    on extremely heterogeneous (power law) activity
    levels, with implications suggesting that we can
    only hope to contain epidemics like HIV by
    targeting the high-activity hubs.
  • But what kind of networks emerge in settings
    where there are no high activity hubs? How do
    these compare to the high-activity distribution
    networks?

98
Simulating Network Structure Exploratory
Simulation Epidemic Potential from Low-degree
networks
Here we simulate networks with a single behavior
rule limiting the number of partners to a known
distribution. -- the weakest form of an ABM
model for networks. We vary the population level
constraint on the distribution of relation
volume, keeping a maximum of 3 partners and
changing the distribution from a mode of 1 to a
mode of 3. Population size of 10,000 nodes.
99
Simulating Network Structure Exploratory
Simulation Epidemic Potential from Low-degree
networks
100
Simulating Network Structure Exploratory
Simulation Epidemic Potential from Low-degree
networks
101
Simulating Network Structure Exploratory
Simulation Epidemic Potential from Low-degree
networks
102
Simulating Network Structure Exploratory
Simulation Epidemic Potential from Low-degree
networks
103
Simulating Network Structure Exploratory
Simulation Epidemic Potential from Low-degree
networks
Very small changes in degree generate a quick
cascade to large connected components. While not
quite as rapid, STD cores follow a similar
pattern, emerging rapidly and rising steadily
with small changes in the degree
distribution. This suggests that, even in the
very short run (days or weeks, in some
populations) large connected cores can emerge
covering the majority of the interacting
population, which can sustain disease, even when
nobody is particularly active. These results
occur faster for low-degree populations than for
the scale free populations, whose hub structure
makes it difficult to form large-reaching robust
sets.
104
Simulating Network Structure Promises and
Pitfalls the good
In both modes of simulation study (explanatory
and exploratory), it is possible to change the
macro conditions directly by affecting
micro-level rules. This is clearly the
strongest factor in bridging the micro-macro
problem.
This modeling strategy moves us from this
Contextual State
Global Outcome
Macro
3
1
2
Resulting Action
Micro
Individual Response
105
Simulating Network Structure Promises and
Pitfalls the good
In both modes of simulation study (explanatory
and exploratory), it is possible to change the
macro conditions directly by affecting
micro-level rules. This is clearly the
strongest factor in bridging the micro-macro
problem.
to this
Unstable (?) Conditions that further motivate
individual action
(feedback)
Initial Conditions
Macro
Aggregates of Action
Stable Equilibrium
Actor Rules
Micro
Action
Interaction
106
Simulating Network Structure Promises and
Pitfalls the bad
  • Still many questions about the empirical etiology
    of observed phenomena
  • Identifying a particular mechanism that works
    doesnt mean it is the mechanism active in the
    settings of interest.
  • Social life may be overdetermined in that
    sense.
  • The tradeoff between realism and simplicity
    carries a cost
  • Simplicity is best for identifying the
    implications of a theoretical mechanism, but
    tells us little about how the simplified
    assumption will work in other interactive
    contexts. Setting a parameter to 0 is still an
    assumption, even if left unexamined.
  • Realism is best for extending external validity,
    but often at the cost of knowing exactly why
    changes in one parameter affect an outcome in a
    given way.

107
Simulating Network Structure Promises and
Pitfalls the bad
Methodologically, simulation work still largely
works on a boutique production
manner Different modelers use different
programs, initial assumptions, etc. Making
replication difficult and increasing startup
costs for everyone. This is getting better with
NetLogo or Repast, widely distributed packages
that share modules (such as work in R), but still
little institutional support of generalized
simulation practice.
108
Simulating Network Structure Promises and
Pitfalls the ugly
  • Evaluating presenting results
  • Often more results than can reasonably be
    summarized in a single paper (or readable book).
  • Were often interested in the distribution of
    outcomes, rather than the central tendency, which
    makes sumation that much more challenging.
  • Results are not well suited for paper-journal
    distribution
  • Color, dynamics, interaction are best treated
    with web-based outlets, but these often lack
    status.
  • How do we extend these results to fit or predict
    in empirical settings where our simulated
    assumptions are not (cannot be) met?

109
(No Transcript)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com