Title: On the Origins of the State
1On the Origins of the State
- Anthropology 101
- Scott A. Lukas, Ph.D.
2The Issue
- The origins of the first civilizations, these
pristine states, have been the subject of much
interest and debate in anthropological literature
(Flannery 1972 400). Indeed, state formation
theory has been a theoretical mainstay of
anthropology for some time (Johnson Earle 1981
246). Around the time of 6000 b.c., in parts of
the Near East and in other locations, we begin to
see a great transformation in the quality and
scale of human life. We see more differences in
communities, forms of specialization and examples
of social stratification.
3The Issue
- In general, we see an interest in the variability
of increasing worldwide complexity (Binford
1983). Unfortunately, archaeologists have had
difficulty with the concept of complexity,
specifically what causes it (ibid).
Additionally, at a semantic level, the term
"complex" is wrought with difficulty (Flannery
1972 400). At the epistemic level, the origin
of the state and increasing sociocultural
complexity has often been misunderstood (Carneiro
1970 733) - with theories of state origins being
often unsatisfactory (Carneiro 1970 733,
Flannery 1972 399).
4Definition of the State
- The state is defined as a regionally-organized
society with a population (of hundreds of
thousands or millions) which is economically and
ethnically diverse (Johnson Earle 1981 246).
By 3500 b.c. we see some of the common
characteristics of civilization (inscription
cities full-time craft specialists monumental
architecture social stratification become even
more distinct and strong hierarchical systems of
centralized organization, what we traditionally
classify as being the state.)
Hierarchical, Centralized Political Systems
5(No Transcript)
6Characteristics of the State
- Other characteristics of the state (Brumfiel
1983 261, Carneiro 1970 733) include the
presence of a military, a bureaucratic level,
stratification, an emphasis on technology and
trade (Johnson Earle 1983 248), specifically
in regards to control over production and
distribution, and an institutionalized religion
(ibid.). The state has often been characterized,
perhaps metaphorically, by the pristine examples
discussed by Flannery (1972 400).
7(No Transcript)
8How Did it Develop?
- Having defined the 'ideal' state, the concern
becomes the origin of the state specifically how
did it develop?
9Those Early Vulgar Theories...
- Early theories of state formation were vulgar and
simplistic. The superimposition theory,
forwarded by F. Ratzel, P.W. Schmidt, A. Rüstow
and F. Oppenheimer, explains the emergence of a
political ruling class and the development of a
political order by "nomadic tribes of herdsmen
who subjugated sedentary farmers and set up a
rule of conquerors" (Habermas 1976 158).
Unfortunately, nomadism appeared later than the
emergence of first civilization. The emergence
of the state must have had "endogenous causes"
(ibid).
10Elizabeth Brumfiel
- Brumfiel (1983 261) discusses two origin
theories of the state
11Ecological Approach
- The ecological approach, suggesting that
demographic growth and resulting pressures
provide the impetus for state formation, is a
footnote to Steward and cultural ecology
(Flannery 1972). The ecological approach suggests
that the state arises in "socioenvironmental
contexts where effective management is either
necessary or especially beneficial" (Brumfiel
1983 262). -
12Ecological Approach
- Wrights model is represented below
-
13Ecological Approach
- According to this model, the interaction of the
two variables of population growth and
environmental setting will result in (1)
overpopulation, (2) decrease in resources (strain
on carrying capacity). These variables are in
turn accommodated by the "application of some
managerial strategy" (Brumfiel 1983). The
discussion of the ecological approach is relevant
along lines of environmental circumscription, as
discussed in Peru and the Amazonian basin
(Carneiro 1970). The theory of population
density (R. Coulborn and others) argues that the
state emerged chiefly through ecological and
demographic factors. As Habermas said, the
complexity of densely populated settlements
could be managed only through state organization
(Habermas 1976 159). -
14Ecological Approach
15Ecological Approach Critiques
- However, some criticism has been leveled against
the ecological approach. Flannery (1972), for
example, suggests that ecological variables may
indeed have implications for hunter-gatherer
adaptations, but he argues that such variables
might be irrelevant in the study of state
development. Additionally, Johnson Earle
(1981) suggest that the intensification of the
subsistence economy, along with corresponding
ecological variables, might not be the main
variable in state formation economic and
political integration must first take place
(ibid.), which suggests, perhaps, a more
structural-functional approach. -
16Ecological Approach Critiques
- Habermas critique of the ecological approach
- even if population problems of this type could
be demonstrated to have existed in all early
civilizations, this theorylike others, does not
explain why and how these problems could be
solved (Habermas 1976 159-160). -
17The Structural Approach
- The structural approach, suggesting that the
state results from "particular sociocultural
orders" while the relationship between the
environment and population is seen as relatively
stable, has roots in Marx and Engels (Brumfiel
1983). According to this approach, certain
sociocultural systems, because of inherent
structural principles, are dynamic (ibid.).
Receiving the most attention as far as state
origin theories are concerned, the structural
approach is an argument that the state emerged
when new industrial techniques made possible an
array of economic institutions, destined to
divide society into a variety of classes
(Engels) the state arose to mediate conflict
between these various classes. -
-
18The Structural Approach
- Many such structural theories of state
organization have relied on the (often reifying)
concepts of status contract, community
(Gemeinschaft) vs. society (Gesellschaft), social
forces productive forces, the legitimation and
monopoly of force, the hierarchical organization
of class and office (Peebles 1988). One must
question whether or not these concepts lead us
any further to an understanding of the state, or
if they simply serve to muddle our picture of it.
-
-
19The Structural Approach
- Or as Flannery (1972) suggests, the state is
necessitated by new problems and risks arising
from technological innovation, increased
complexity, trade (Rathje), and inherent
conflict (Wittfogel). Another variation of this
theory is the inequality theory, forwarded by
G.E. Lenski and to some extent Habermas in his
early years, which traces the emergence of the
state directly to problems of distribution
(Habermas 1976 159). With the productivity of
labor "there arose a surplus of goods and means
of production. The growing differences in wealth
resulted in social differences that a relatively
egalitarian kinship system could not manage. The
distribution problems required a different
organization of social intercourse" (Habermas
1976 159). -
-
20The Structural Approach
- The "classic Marxist" argument, namely that base
determines superstructure and social being
determines consciousness, has been appropriated
by the structural Marxists to explicitly
deterministic ends. The structural Marxist model
of the state (below) places complete reliance on
the relations of production its argument is that
these relations of production completely
determine the state. -
-
21The Structural Approach Critiques
- There have been numerous criticisms leveled
against the structural approach. Service argues
against the structural approach disputing notions
of economic inequality and wars between social
classes. Brumfiel (1983) adds that, like the
ecological model, the structural approach is also
dependent upon environmental factors. Others
have argued against its simple deterministic
nature. Habermas concludes that the structural
division of labor theory is "not coherent" (1976
158). A social division of labor implies
functional specification within the vocational
system however, vocational groups
"differentiated by knowledge and skill need not
per se develop opposing interests that result in
differential access to the means of production"
(Habermas 1976 158-9). Additionally, the
structural approach fails to address why the
functions of domination had to "emerge from the
contrast of interests rooted in vocational
specialization" (ibid 159). -
22The Structural Approach Critiques
- The Marxist Diakonov offers the following model
(Wright 1977) -
23Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Carneiro (1970) sees the evolution of states as
having been explained through either a
voluntaristic model or a coercive one. The first
is rooted in the Rosseauian idea of the social
contract.
24The Voluntaristic Model
- One representation of the voluntaristic model is
the "automatic theory" of Childe a food surplus
and agricultural development leads to free time,
craft specialization, and the eventual
integration of people into a state. Carneiro
doubts that this always takes place in this
manner.
25Voluntaristic Model Hydraulics
- Another manifestation of a voluntaristic model is
the hydraulic hypothesis (Habermas 1976 159)
proposed by Wittfogel as people got together,
the completion of large-scale irrigation works
led to the construction of the state. -
26Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Again, Carneiro suggests that the model
disregards many archaeological instances in which
the state developed prior to such irrigation
implements. Coercion models are exemplified by
the classic Mayan example - war lies at root of
the state. -
27Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- The documentation of political evolution in state
formation has gained significant attention. The
case of state formation in thirteenth and
fourteenth century Aztec civilizations in the
Valley of Mexico characterizes the role of
political evolution, specifically as seen in the
conflicts between small polities, militaristic
expansionism, and resulting internal political
structure. -
28Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Carniero's discussion of political evolution
includes variables of environment, demography and
circumscription the abundance of food in the
Peru coastal region led to population increase
the restrictedness of the food, however, resulted
in complete occupation of all exploitable areas
the carrying capacity reached a critical stage
competition resulted and thus internal evolution
took place. The evolution of political economy,
along other lines, often represents the erosion
of smaller aggregates, such as the family unit
(Johnson Earle 1981). At the highest level of
inclusion, elements such as symbolization
(perhaps a result of state religion) represent a
further erosion of smaller units. -
29Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Carniero's discussion of political evolution
-
30Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Johnson Earle (1981 24) suggest a multilineal
- evolutionary perspective in their various case
studies. Dispelling simple notions of "feudal"
societies, the authors embark on a
cross-continent comparison of Middle Age Japan
and France. They suggest many commonalties both
were influenced by external empires, both
represented a steady population growth at the
bases of their societies and a resultant change
in food production, both saw an intensification
of existing land or a use of marginal lands
through new techniques (irrigation). -
31Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Developing their notions of a dual evolution of
economic bases, the authors look at the Inka case
study in terms of political integration and
political economy with its interregional
institutions. Brumfiel's model of the birth of
the Triple Alliance looks at a variety of
conditions which were conducive to the rise of
political centralization in the Aztec case,
eventually resulting in the development of
bureaucratic complexity. Brumfiel's argument
addresses an "interplay of ecological variables
and political dynamics" (1983 278). -
32Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Carneiro (1970 733) provides that state origin
theories based upon notions of (1) race, (2)
genius, and (3) historical accidents are
unacceptable. The development of a state is not
a fortuitous act, but rather a result of "a
regular and determinate cultural process"
(ibid.). The early theories of socio-cultural
complexity, those of Morgan, Maine and Service,
offer little more than simplicity. Indeed, many
archaeologists have been vexed by the simplicity
of such models in turn, they have re-examined
them in a new light. Flannery, for instance,
addresses the notion of impetus of state
formation and suggests a prime-mover scheme
(1972 401). -
33Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Adopting the understood model of complexity (band
- tribe - chiefdom - state), Flannery is
interested in exactly how a band, for example,
might become a tribe, and eventually, perhaps, a
state. The author identifies various mechanisms
which may have lead to state formation
irrigation (Wittfogel), warfare (Carneiro),
population growth and social circumscription
(high population density produces effects similar
to environmental circumscription, Chagnon), trade
symbiosis (Rathje), cooperation and competition,
integrative power of art and religion -
34Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Johnson Earle (1981) provide some additional
mechanisms, or conditions it should be said,
including the necessity of (1) a high population
density (with need for a system of integration),
and (2) opportunities of economic control, thus
leading to class formation, and general
population control and stability functions
(Brumfiel 1983 277). -
35Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Habermas (1976) approaches the problem of the
state through a model of co-evolutionary
development of (1) technical knowledge, (2)
practical / moral knowledge. The evolution of
the state, and the rise of communicative action,
is related to the development of production which
is nourished through the application of these two
forms of knowledge.
36Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Habermas' model is an attempt to explain the
fundamental importance of communication within
the context of the state, and a call to put the
individual back in the center of the picture.
His model argues that Neolithic societies, with
complex kin organizations, eventually became
hierarchical ones. The initial infantile 'state'
was presented with particular systemic problems,
including population over-density and land
scarcity. The testing of new structures (the
administration of justice at a conventional
level, for example) lead to institutionalization.
-
37Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- As Ember suggests in Peebles (1988)
-
38Voluntaristic and Coercive Models
- Stabilization then occurred through the formation
of these new systems. In turn new class
structures emerged and the development of
productive forces occurred, i.e. the forces of
production discovered at the Neolithic Revolution
could now be used on a large scale (Habermas
1976 161-3). Unfortunately, Habermas' model
seems reminiscent of the ecological models
discussed earlier. -
39The Major Locations of States
- Southern Iraq
- Sumerian Civilization
- Mesoamerica
- Teotihuacan
- Monte Alba (Oaxaca)
- Africa
- Axum (Ethiopia)
- India
- Harappan
-
- China
- Shang dynasty
- South America
- Moche
- Nazca
- North America
- Cahokia
-
40The Theories
- The problems of state formation are tied to
deficiencies in the archaeological record and
deficiencies in the epistemic theories to which
the record is attached. It seems frivolous to
attribute state formation to a single variable
rather, we might look at a multitude of reasons
behind the apparent increase in social
complexity. As with the study of agricultural
origins, archaeologists need to re-evaluate
existing theories of the state (Gasser Bond
1988), as well as develop sound methods of
inquiry, including studies of chronology, from
cultural remains.
41References Cited
- Binford, Lewis R.
- 1983 In Pursuit of the Past Decoding the
Archaeological Record. - NY Thames and Hudson.
- Brumfiel, Elizabeth
- 1983 "Aztec State Making Ecology, Structure,
and the Origin of the - State." American Anthropologist 85(2)261-284.
- Carniero, Robert
- 1970 "A Theory of the Origin of the State."
Science 169733-738. - Flannery, Kent V.
- 1972 "The Cultural Evolution of Civilization."
Annual Review of - Ecology and Systematics 3399-426.
- Gasser, L. Bond, A.
- 1988 Readings in Distributed Artificial
Intelligence. Morgan - Kaufmann.
42References Cited
- Habermas, Jürgen
- 1976 Communication and the Evolution of Society.
Boston Beacon Press. - Johnson, Allen Earle, Timothy
- 1987 "The Archaic State," "Conclusion. " InThe
Evolution of Human Societies. Pps. 246-270,
313-325. Stanford Stanford University Press. - Peebles, Christopher
- 1988 Lecture on the origins of the state.
11-2-88. Bloomington - Indiana University
-
- Wright, Henry T.
- 1977 "Toward an explanation of the origin of the
state." In The - Explanation of Prehistoric Change. J. Hill,
ed. Pps. 215-230. - Albuquerque University of New Mexico Press.