Title: COS 444 Internet Auctions: Theory and Practice
1COS 444 Internet AuctionsTheory and Practice
Spring 2009 Ken Steiglitz
ken_at_cs.princeton.edu
2the bigger picture, all single item
Myerson 1981 optimal, not efficient asymmetric
bidders
3Moving to asymmetric bidders
- Efficiency item goes to bidder with highest
value - Very important in some situations!
- Second-price auctions remain efficient in
asymmetric (IPV) case. Why? - First-price auctions do not
4Inefficiency in FP with asymmetric bidders
5New setup Myerson 81, also BR 89
wins Nobel prize for this and related work, 2007
- Vector of values v
- Allocation function Q (v )
- Qi (v ) is prob. i wins item
- Payment function P (v )
- Pi (v ) is expected payment of i
- Subsumes Ars easily (check SP, FP)
- The pair (Q , P ) is called a
- Direct Mechanism
6New setup Myerson 81
- Definition When agents who participate in a
mechanism have no incentive to lie about their
values, we say the mechanism is incentive
compatible. - The Revelation Principle In so far as
equilibrium behavior is concerned, any auction
mechanism can be replaced by an
incentive-compatible direct mechanism.
7Revelation Principle
- Proof Replace the bid-taker with a direct
mechanism that computes equilibrium values for
the bidders. Then a bidder can bid equilibrium
simply by being truthful, and there is never an
incentive to lie. ? - This principle is very general and includes
any sort of negotiation!
8(No Transcript)
9Asymmetric bidders
- We can therefore restrict attention to
incentive-compatible direct mechanisms! - Note In the asymmetric case, expected surplus is
no longer vi F(z) n-1 - P(z) - (bidding as if value z )
- Next we write expected surplus in the
asymmetric case
10Asymmetric bidders
- Notation v-i vector v with the i th
- Value omitted. Then the prob. that i wins is
- Where V-i is the space of all vs except vi and
- F (v-i ) is the corresponding distribution
11Asymmetric bidders
- Similarly for the expected payment of bidder i
- Expected surplus is then
12A yet more general RET
- Differentiate wrt z and set to zero when z
vi - as usual
- But now take the total derivative wrt vi when z
vi - And so
13 yet more general RE
- Integrate
- Or, using S vQ P ,
- ?In equilibrium, expected payment of every bidder
depends only on allocation function Q !
14Optimal allocation
- Average over vi and proceed as in RS81
- where
?no longer a common F
15Optimal allocation, cont
- The total expected revenue is
- For participation, Pi (0 ) 0, and seller
chooses Pi (0) 0 to max surplus. Therefore
16Optimal allocation, cont
When Pi (0 ) 0 we say bidders are individually
rational They dont participate in auctions if
the expected payment with zero value is positive.
17Optimal allocation
- The optimal allocation can now be seen by
inspection! - For each vector of vs, Look for the maximum
value of MRi (vi ). Say it occurs at i i , and
denote it by MR . - If MR gt 0, then choose that Qi to be 1 and all
the other Qs to be 0 (bidder i gets the item) - If MR 0, then hold on to the item (seller
retains item)
18Optimal allocation (inefficient!)
19Payment rule
- Hint must reduce to second-price when bidders
are symmetric - Therefore Pay the least you can while still
maintaining the highest MR - This is incentive compatible that is, bidders
bid truthfully! Why?
20Vickrey 61 yet again
21Wrinkle
- For this argument to work, MR must be an
increasing function. We call F s with increasing
MRs regular. (Uniform is regular) - Its sufficient for the inverse hazard rate
- (1 F) / f to be decreasing.
- Can be fixed See Myerson 81 (ironing)
- Assume MR is regular in what follows
22- Notice also that this asks a lot of bidders in
the asymmetric case. In the direct mechanism the
bidders must understand enough to be truthful,
and accept the fact that the highest value
doesnt always win. - Or, think of MRi(vi) as is bid
- As usual in game-theoretic settings,
distributions are common knowledge---at least the
hypothetical auctioneer must know them.
23In the symmetric caseArs are optimal mechanisms!
- By the revelation principle, we can restrict
attention to direct mechanisms - An optimal direct mechanism in the symmetric case
awards item to the highest-value bidder, and so
does any auction in Ars - All direct mechanisms with the same allocation
rule have the same revenue - Therefore any auction in Ars has the same
allocation rule, and hence revenue, as an optimal
(general!) mechanism
Includes any sort of negotiation whatsoever!
24Efficiency
- Second-price auctions are efficient --- i.e.,
they allocate the item to the buyer who values it
the most. (Even in asymm. case, truthful is
dominant.) - Weve seen that optimal (revenue-maximizing)
auctions in the asymmetric case are in general
inefficient. - It turns out that second-price auctions are
optimal in the class of efficient auctions. They
generalize in the multi-item case to the
Vickrey-Clark-Groves (VCG) mechanisms. More
later.
25Laboratory Evidence
- Generally, there are three kinds of empirical
methodologies - Field observations
- Field experiments
- Laboratory experiments
- ?Problem people may not behave the same way in
the lab as in the world - ?Problem people differ in behavior
- ?Problem people learn from experience
26Laboratory Evidence
- Conclusions fall into two general categories
- Revenue ranking
- Point predictions (usually revenue relative to
Nash equilibrium)
For more detail, see J. H. Kagel, "Auctions A
Survey of Experimental Research", in The Handbook
of Experimental Economics, J. Kagel and A. Roth
(eds.), Princeton Univ. Press, 1995.
27Best revenue-ranking results for IPV model
- Second-Price gt English Kagel et al. (87)
- English ? truthfulNash Kagel et al. (87)
- First-Price ? Second-Price
- First-Price gt Dutch Coppinger et al. (80)
- First-Price gt Nash Dyer et al. (89)
- Thus, generally,
- sealed versions gt open versions!
28- A violation of theory is the
scientists best news! - Lets discuss some of the violations
- Second-Price gt English. These are (weakly)
strategically equivalent. But - English ? truthful Nash.
- What hint towards an explanation does the
weakly give us?
29- First-Price gt Dutch. These are strongly
strategically equivalent. But recall
Lucking-Reileys pre-eBay internet test with
Magic cards, where Dutch gt FP by 30! - Whats going on here?
30- See also Kagel Levin 93 for experiments with
3rd-price auctions that test IPV theory - More about experimental results for common-value
auctions later - We next focus for a while on a widely accepted
point prediction - One explanation, as weve seen, is
- risk aversion
- But is here is an alternative explanation
First-price gt Nash
31Spite MSR 03 MS 03
- Suppose bidders care about the surplus of other
bidders as well their own. - Simple example Two bidders, second-price,
values iid unifom on 0,1. Suppose bidder 2 bids
truthfully, and suppose bidder 1s utility is not
her own surplus, but the difference ? between
hers and her rivals.
32Spite
- Now bidder 1 wants to choose her bid b1 to
maximize the expectation of - where I is the indicator function, 1 when
true, 0 else. - Taking expectation over v2
33Spite
- Maximizing wrt b1 yields best response to
truthful bidding - Intuition?
34Spite
- Maximizing wrt b1 yields best response to
truthful bidding - Intuition by overbidding, 1 loses surplus when
2s bid is between v1 and her bid. But, this is
more than offset by forcing 2 to pay more when he
wins. - Notice that bidder 2 still cannot increase his
absolute surplus. (Why not?) He must take a hit
to compete in a pairwise knockout tournament.
35Spite
- Some results from MSR 03 take the case when
bidders want to maximize the difference between
their own surplus and that of their rivals.
Values distributed as F, n bidders. Then - ? FP equilibrium is the same as in the
risk-averse CRRA case with ? ½ (utility is t1/2
). Thus there is overbidding. - ? SP equilibrium is to overbid according to
36Spite
- ? Revenue ranking is SP gt FP.
- (Not a trivial proof. Is there a simpler
one?) - Thus, this revenue ranking is the opposite of the
prediction in the risk-averse case, where there
is overbidding in FP but not in SP. (Testable
prediction.) - This explains overbidding in both first- and
second-price auctions, while risk-aversion
explains only the first. (Testable prediction.) - Raises a question do you think people bid
differently against machines than against people?
37Spiteful behavior in biology
- This model can also explain spiteful behavior in
biological contexts, where individuals fight for
survival one-on-one MS 03. Example - This is a hawk-dove game.
- Winner type replaces loser type.
- In a large population where the success of an
individual is determined by average individual
payoff, there is an evolutionarily stable
solution that is 50/50 hawks and doves. - If winners are determined by relative payoff in
each 1-1 contest, the hawks drive out the doves. - Thus, there is an Invasion of the Spiteful
Mutants!
38Invasion of the spiteful mutants
- To see this, suppose in the large population
there is a fraction ? of Hs and (1-? ) of Ds. - The average payoff to an H in a contest is
- and to a D
- The first is greater than the second iff ?lt1/2. A
50/50 mixture is an equilibrium. - But if the winner of a contest is determined by
who has the greater payoff, an H always replaces
a D!