Title: Overview of Fisheries Management: An Economists Perspective
1Overview of Fisheries Management An Economists
Perspective
- Gordon Munro
- Fisheries Centre, University of British Columbia
- Vancouver, Canada
2Introduction
- In the discussion to follow, we shall focus
solely upon the management of marine capture
fisheries - Our objective is to give an overview that will
provide a foundation for the lectures to follow - consequently, we shall take a broad brush
approach, and leave the detailed discussion to
the following lectures.
3The Economists View of Natural Resources
- Economists view all natural resources as forms of
capital - Capital is any good, asset, capable of yielding
valuable services over a period of time - natural resources, such as fish stocks, clearly
fall under this definition - natural capital differs from capital made by
humans, only in that it comes to us an endowment
from nature
4Building Up and Depleting Stocks of Capital
- Building up, increasing, stocks of capital is a
process of positive investment - positive investment means incurring a cost,
sacrifice, today for the hope of a return, a
payoff, in the future - Many forms of capital can be depleted mined
- consequence is that we enjoy a lot today, at the
cost of having less tomorrow
5Links with Biology
- Does this capital theory approach to fisheries
economics have any links with biology? - the answer is a definite yes
- if we are to invest in a fishery resource, we
must understand the growth function of the
resource - A key principle every economic model of a
fishery has a biological model as its foundation - The link is so close that we now talk in terms of
Bioeconomics
6Marine Capture Fishery Resources as Common
Property
- Historically, marine capture fishery resources
have been common property (common pool)
resources - ineffective, or non-existent, property rights to
the resources - these resources are difficult to see and are
mobile difficult, costly, to set up property
rights. - a common property fishery, in which there is a
complete absence of property rights and
regulations, we refer to as a pure open access
fishery - e.g. high seas fisheries
7Common Property and Incentives
- Economists have made the point, for over 50
years, that common property results in
exploiters of the resources having incentives,
which are perverse from societys point of view - Fishermen have no incentive to invest in
(conserve) the resources. To the contrary, they
have a powerful incentive to disinvest -to mine -
the resources - everybodys property is nobodys property
8Perverse Incentives, Initially of Little Concern
- While overexploitation of local inshore fisheries
was a concern for centuries, little worry about
major ocean fishery resources, until first part
of 20th Century - mining of any resource limited by costs of
extraction. State of technology seemed to
protect ocean fisheries, until 20th Century - Thomas Huxley, 1883 Probably all great
sea-fisheries are inexhaustible----
9The Awakening
- With rapid advance in fishing technology, e.g.
steam power, fishing costs fell dramatically, and
resource overexploitation became a real concern - Experience of two World Wars convinced scientists
that fishing could have significant impact on
ocean fishery resources - reasons for - by late 1940s, management of major ocean
fisheries come to be taken seriously.
10Ongoing Mining of the Resources
- While fisheries management on a world wide basis
came to be taken seriously after World War II,
mining of world fishery resources has by no
means been eliminated. - The following is an example from the North
Atlantic, one of the most heavily exploited set
of fisheries in the world. - comparable examples can be found in other parts
of the world.
11Mining of Fishery Resources The Example of the
North Atlantic
Biomass
Biomass tkm-2
1.8-2.51.5-1.81.2-1.50.9-1.20.7-0.90.6-0.70.
4-0.60.3-0.40.2-0.30.1-0.20-0.10-0
Courtesy V. Christensen
12High Seas and Extended Fisheries Jurisdiction
- Pure open access fisheries the norm on the high
seas, aggravated by the coming of distant water
fleets - example of fisheries off Namibia before 1990.
- international attempts to control such fisheries
weak, or non-existent - Led to establishment of EEZ regime through UN in
1982 - now supplemented by 1995 UN Fish Stocks Agreement
13Approaches to Management
- The root of the problem, we have argued, lies in
the fact that common property fisheries
confront fishermen with a perverse set of
incentives - the obvious approach to resource management is
what the FAO calls an Incentive Blocking Approach
to Management - if fishermen have an incentive to overexploit a
resource, block them from doing so by imposing
TACs, gear restrictions, time limits etc.
14A New Form of Open Access (Common Property)
- Economists have argued that conserving the
resource, through the use of TACs etc., is not
sufficient - The fishermens incentives have not changed. The
restricted harvest now becomes the common
property. Fishermen compete for shares of
restricted harvest -Regulated Open Access
15Consequences of Regulated Open Access (ROA)
- ROA leads to excess fleet capacity, and hence
economic waste - even if resource is effectively conserved,
economic return from fishery to society (resource
rent) likely to be fully dissipated - example of Pacific halibut - off North America
- pure open access fishery, followed by US/Canada
management regime in 1920s - resource conservation big success
- but fishery was an economic disaster -negative
contributions to Canadian and US GDPs.
16Attempts to Control Capacity
- If fishermen have an incentive, under harvest
controls, to create excess capacity, obvious next
step is to block them by controlling vessel
number and sizes limited entry - results generally very disappointing number of
vessels controlled, but effective capacity still
increases reasons for - Fundamental Law impossible to overestimate
ingenuity of fishermen in circumventing
regulations
17Other Consequences of ROA
- Excess capacity increases difficulty of
controlling harvests - Setting TACs done under conditions of uncertainty
what is the correct TAC? - fishermen have every incentive to pressure
managers into setting very liberal TACs - In too many cases, overall result - fishery
resources continue to decline, if not collapse - examples from North America Northern Cod, New
England groundfish fisheries - Consider following figure from Michael
Sissenwine, US marine biologist (former senior
scientist NMFS)
18(No Transcript)
19Incentive Adjusting Approaches to Management
- Disillusionment with Incentive Blocking
Approaches has led to increased emphasis on the
Incentive Adjusting alternative - change fishermen incentives, rather than blocking
them - One way to do this is through use of taxes, on
harvests or fishing effort - not unknown, but, rightly or wrongly, little
used.
20Use Rights
- Most common approach is to create de facto
property rights first to harvests, and then to
resource itself - individual harvest quotas (IQs and ITQs), but
also community based fisheries management schemes - Objective is to create a system in which it is in
the selfish interest of fishermen to invest in
the resource (natural capital) - fishermen assured both of enjoying some of
benefits of such investment, and of suffering
from consequences of excessive disinvestment of
the resource
21Two North American Examples
- ITQ schemes off Pacific Canada
- fishermen contributing funds to biological
research developing more conservationist
harvesting methods - improved conservation promptly reflected in
market values of their quota - North American Indian (First Nations) community
management of Pacific salmon pre European
settlement very effective - consequences of excessive disinvestment of
natural capitalstarvation!
22Biologists and Incentives
- Importance of fishermen incentives to management,
no longer stressed by economists only importance
coming to be recognized by marine biologists as
well - example - Prof. Ray Hilborn, U. of Washington -
paper prepared for the Royal Society (UK), with
fellow biologists J. Orensanz and Anna Parma -
Institutions, Incentives and the Future of
Fisheries
23Special Issue I Ecosystem Management
- Single species management no longer seen as
adequate ecosystem approach, which at a minimum
recognizes species interaction - A set of assets is referred to as a portfolio of
assets - Economics of fisheries in an ecosystem approach,
becomes a problem in portfolio management. - a very common problem to economists.
24Special Issue II Uncertainty
- All investment takes place under conditions of
uncertainty this is especially true in the case
of investment in fishery resources - Economists have various means of coping with
uncertainty, eg. insurance. One very important
way is through prudent portfolio management - this creates a case for Marine Protected Areas a
buffer against environmental shocks, and
inescapable resource management errors.
25Special Issue III Shared Fishery Resources
- Marine capture fishery resources are mobile.
Consequently, it is inevitable that, under the
EEZ regime, some fishery resources will be shared
between, and among, states, e.g. hake shared by
Namibia, South Africa and Angola - classes of shared stocks
- transboundary -stocks cross EEZ of one coastal
state into EEZ of another - straddling -stocks cross EEZ boundary into high
seas, where they are subject to exploitation by
distant water fishing states (DWFS). -
26(No Transcript)
27(No Transcript)
28Basic Economics of Shared Fish Stock Management
- There will be a strategic interaction
between/among states sharing a fishery resource. - e.g. states A and B share a fish stock. As
harvesting activities will have an impact on Bs
harvesting opportunities, and vice-versa. - A and B will, if rational, take this interaction
into account in their resource management
planning - Economics of shared stock management - a blend
of standard fisheries economics and theory of
strategic interaction, better known as theory of
games
29Theory of Games and Shared Fish Stock Management
- Theory of games divided into two broad categories
- (i) theory of competitive (non-cooperative)
games and (ii) theory of cooperative games - Two questions
- 1. what are the consequences of non-cooperative
management of shared stocks? - 2. what are the basic requirements for a stable
cooperative management regime? - we draw upon (i) to obtain answer to 1 and (ii)
to obtain answer to 2.
30Non-Cooperative Management of Shared Fish Stocks
- Theory of competitive games tells us that, under
non-cooperative management, there is a serous
risk that states sharing a resource will be
driven to adopting exploitation strategies each
recognizes as destructive - The Prisoners
Dilemma - examples from North America and Australia/New
Zealand - Other than in exceptional circumstances,
cooperation does matter!
31Cooperative Management of Shared Fish Stocks
- Key question what is being shared, the harvests,
or the economic benefits from the fishery? They
are not necessarily identical - First, what is NOT required for a stable
cooperative management arrangement - that states
sharing resource have identical management goals
-compromises can be established
32Requirements for Stable Cooperative Arrangement
- 1. every partner in the cooperative management
arrangement must be assured of receiving more
than it would under non-cooperation - obvious
requirement, but often ignored in practice - often requires flexibility in bargaining, and
doing more than just sharing harvests - economists stress on sharing the economic
benefits from the fishery, not simply the harvest - a famous North American example
33More on Requirements for Stable Arrangement
- 2. resiliency through time -less obvious
- every cooperative management arrangement can
expect to be subject to unpredictable shocks over
time -e.g. shifts in distribution of stock, due
to climate change, or other factors - if the cooperative arrangement lacks resilience,
good chance that it will not survive the shocks
-this carries with it the risk of reversion to
destructive non-cooperation - examples from North America, and North Atlantic
34Some Conclusions
- Economists view fishery resources as valuable
assets that should be capable of yielding
economic returns to society,now, and far off into
the future - economics of fisheries management seen as a
problem of asset management through time - Modern fisheries economics is not divorced from
marine biology -to the contrary! The link is so
strong that we now talk in terms of Bioeconomics
35Some Further Conclusions
- The basic management problem is to create a
system of incentives - (a) among fishermen within a state, and
- (b) among states sharing a resource
- that will cause them to be willing to invest in
the resource (natural capital), in the face of
uncertainty - perverse incentives lead invariably to resource
overexploitation