Title: Statistical Inference: Poverty Indices and Poverty Decompositions
1Statistical Inference Poverty Indices and
Poverty Decompositions
- Michael Lokshin
- DECRG-PO
- The World Bank
2Problem
- Poverty rate in urban areas declined by 25
Poverty rate in rural areas declined by 25. - Overall poverty rate in the country declined by
more than 50.
3Solution
4Steps in poverty analysis
- H, PG, SPG
- Change in inequality
- Growth in welfare aggregate
- Regional and Urban Rural statistics
- Decompositions
- Poverty profiles
- Simulations
- Robustness check
5 Decomposing changes in poverty
- Growth versus redistribution.
- What is the relative importance of growth vs.
redistribution? - Growth component holds relative inequalities
(Lorenz curve) constant redistribution component
holds mean constant - Gains within sectors versus population shifts.
- How important are different sectors to changes in
poverty? - Gains within sectors, hold initial populations
constant population shift effects, hold initial
poverty measures constant.
6Growth and Redistribution decomposition
Similar decomposition could be made for other
poverty measures
7Growth and Redistribution decomposition
- Example for Brazil in 1980s.
Very little change in poverty rising
inequality Decomposition
- No change in headcount index yet two strong
opposing effects growth (poverty reducing)
redistribution (poverty increasing). - Redistribution effect is dominant for PG and
SPG.
8Sectoral decomposition of a change in poverty
- Intra-sectoral effect the contribution of
poverty changes within sectors controlling for
base period population shares - Population shift effect how much of the poverty
in the first date was reduced by the changes in
the population shares of sectors between then and
the second date. - Interaction effect arises from the correlation
between sectoral gains and population shifts the
sign of the interaction effect tells whether
people tented to switch to the sectors where
poverty was falling or not.
9Sectoral decomposition Example for Indonesia
Population was moving out of the rural sector
where the poverty was falling faster negative
interaction effect.
10Poverty profiles Overview
- A decomposition of a single aggregate poverty
number into subgroup numbers in order to - - Begin to understand possible determinants of
poverty - - Help inform targeting of anti-poverty programs
and other policies - Additive poverty measures (e.g., FGT class) are
useful for profiles. Additivity guarantees
sub-group consistency - - when poverty increases (decreases) for any
sub-group of the population, aggregate poverty
will also increase (decrease).
11Poverty profiles Additivity
- Suppose population is divided into m mutually
exclusive sub-groups. - The poverty profile is the list of poverty
measures Pj for j1,,m. - Aggregate poverty for additive poverty measures
- Aggregate poverty is a population weighted mean
of the sub-group poverty measures.
12Additivity Example
- Urban population (2,2,3,4)
- Rural population (1,1,1.5,2,4)
- Zu3,Zr2,n9,nu4,nr5,
- Direct way n9 q7 Hq/n0.78
13Additive measures (Continued)
- Example of sub-group consistency
- Initial state, two equally sized groups
- Urban population Hu 0.20 Rural Hr 0.70
- Total poverty rate H 0.45
- Policy A
- Urban population Hu 0.10 Rural Hr 0.70
- Total poverty rate H 0.40
- Policy B
- Urban population Hu 0.20 Rural Hr 0.60
- Total poverty rate H 0.40
- Policy A gain goes to richer urban areas
- Policy B gain goes to poorer rural areas
- Overall poverty is unchanged but greater
inequality between groups under Policy A
14Additive measures (Continued)
- What about this example of Policy C?
- Urban population Hu0.05 Rural Hr 0.75
- Total poverty rate H 0.40
- Policy C enhanced gain goes to richer urban
areas, poverty in rural areas increases - Undesirable property of additive measures
insensitivity to the inequality between
sub-groups in the extent of poverty
15Poverty profiles Two types
- Two main ways to present poverty profiles
- Type A Incidence of poverty for sub-groups
defined by some characteristics (e.g., place of
residence) - Type B Incidence of characteristics defined by
the poverty status.
16Poverty profiles
- Which type is more useful will depend on the
policy question addressed. - Geographic targeting. Select the target region
for poverty alleviation. If one chooses South
more money will go to poor. So Type A is
preferable. Minimizes the poverty gap. - Growth promotion On the other hand, if pro-poor
growth policies can only be implemented in one
region, the reduction in overall number of poor
is likely to be greater if applied to the North.
17Poverty profiles Egypt regions
18Poverty profiles Egypt (Type A)
19Poverty profiles Egypt (Type B)
20Poverty profiles by sector Brazil, 1996
- Sector of Activity fk P0k P1k P2k sk
- Agriculture 22.02 54.17 26.87 16.85 49.88
- Manufacturing 13.83 16.03 6.06 3.13 9.27
- Construction 9.64 19.49 6.70 3.36 7.86
- Services 31.92 10.79 3.45 1.58 14.41
- Public Sector 8.13 9.96 3.25 1.42 3.39
- Other/Not Specified 14.46 25.12 10.93 6.51
15.19 - fk Share in total population
- sk Share in population of poor
21Precision of poverty estimates
- Poverty profiles imply a comparison across
poverty measures of sub-groups. - How do we know if observed differences in survey
measures reflect true differences in population?
Some potential sources of errors in surveys
include - Sampling error selected sample is not
representative of underlying population or sample
size very small in reference to total population. - Refusal bias certain sub-groups are more likely
to refuse survey interview than other groups. - Instrument mis-design survey instrument misses
relevant dimension of welfare.
22Measurement Errors
- Poverty measures could be sensitive to certain
sorts of measurement errors in underlying
parameters and quite robust to others. - Case 1 If welfare indicator contains an additive
random error with zero mean then the expected
value of headcount index will be unbiased. One
will predict the same H with the noisy data as
with a precise data. However, this will not be
true for other indicators. Any distribution-sensit
ive measures (P2) will be affected
23Measurement Errors (cont.)
- Case 2 Errors in the mean of the distribution.
Its being estimated that often the elasticity of
H with respect to the mean is around 2.
(Indonesia for Urban elasticity of H is 2.1, of
PG is 2.9 and for SPG is 3.4). Thus 5
underestimation of the mean of consumption
translates into 10 overestimation of the H and
gt 10 more poor. - Case 3 Change in the distribution. Surveys might
overestimate consumption of the poor and
underestimate consumption of the rich. Hard to
say about H. For PG and SPG, under-estimation of
consumption of the poor -gt higher PG, SPG.
24Measurement Errors (cont.)
- Case 4. Comparison over time. Errors in rate of
inflation. This may affect consumption of
everyone in the same way (No change in the
distribution). Affects both the mean and the
poverty line gt measures of poverty will be
unaffected. - Head count index is usually less sensitive to
some common forms of the measurement errors
25Hypothesis testing
- Straight-forward for additive poverty measures
and simple random samples. - Standard error of the sample distribution of the
head-count index (given by binomial normal
distribution standard for population
proportions) is - So, there is a 95 chance that the true value of
H lies in the interval
26Hypothesis testing (cont.)
- Example (11,22,33,44), z3, H0.75, n4000
- Calculate 95 confidence interval
- On very small samples, the approximation might
not be the best.
27Comparison of two headcount indexes
- Suppose you measure poverty in these two samples.
How to test whether poverty in the first sample
is different from the poverty in the second
sample. - Two distributions A and B. nA and nB
- Null hypothesis HAHB
- Need to calculate t-statistic
28Comparison of two headcount indexes (cont.)
where s denotes the standard error of the
sampling distribution of HA-HB and given by
if tlt1.96(2.58) the difference in H cannot be
considered statistically significant at the 5
(1) level.
29Comparison of two headcount indexes (cont.)
- Example
- Case 1 A(1,2,3,4) B(1,3,4,5,6) z3
- HA0.75 HB0.4
- Test HA HB
- Conclusion Reject that HAHB at 1 level.
30Comparison of two headcount indexes (cont.)
- Example
- Case 2 A(1,2,3,4) B(1,3,3,5,6) z3
- HA0.75 HB0.6
- Test HA HB
- Conclusion Cannot reject that HAHB at 5 level.
31Precision of poverty estimates
- Recommendation Quantitative poverty comparison
which fails the above test must be considered
ambiguous. - These methods could be extended to other additive
poverty measures. - Kakwani (1990) has derived formulae for the
standard errors for other additive measures
including FGT. Limitations - - One might prefer to treat the poverty line as a
random variable - - These formulae ignore the imprecision that
arises when used on grouped data - There are no general results to handle these
problems
32Alternative estimates of standard errors
Bootstrapping
- A computationally intensive method that generates
asymptotically valid standard errors for many
test-statistics. - Example of H0 for Indonesia, 1984-1999
Year 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 Headcount 0.41
51 0.2920 0.2647 0.2013 0.1625 0.3508 Standard
error 0.0065 0.0053 0.0037 0.0048 0.0034 0.0046