Title: 4-day course on Agricultural Trade Policy and the WTO
14-day course on Agricultural Trade Policy and the
WTO
- Tehran, Iran, 15-18 May 2005
2Outline of 4-day course
- Principles each morning practical, hands-on
analytical tools each afternoon - Day 1 WTOs contribution to economic growth and
nature of protection patterns still in place and
accessing trade protection data - Day 2 WTO accession processes and experiences
and partial equilibrium analysis - Day 3 Doha progress, prospects implications
for Iran and general equilibrium analysis - Day 4 Scope for CGE modelling for Iran
3Facilitators
- Kym Anderson, Development Research Group, World
Bank, USA - Convener of morning sessions
- Frank van Tongeren, LEI, Netherlands
- Convener of afternoon sessions
- Shuby Soamiely Andriamananjara, World Bank
Institute, USA - Overall coordinator
4Day 1 Gains from trade, patterns of trade and
protection, and WTOs contributions to growth of
open economies
5Outline of first morning
- The gains-from-trade arguments
- Key reason why trade barriers remain
- WTOs role in providing a counterforce
- WTOs other benefits for governments seeking to
reform their economies - The patterns of protection that still remain in
the world, despite huge reductions since the
formation of GATT (1947) and WTO (1995)
6Arguments for removing trade barriers and
subsidies
- Standard gains-fromtrade argument allows
nations resources to be used to exploit its
comparative advantages by specializing its
production in what it does best - That in turn can increase (esp. in small
economies) - scope for exploiting economies of scale,
- capacity to deal with natural disasters
- competitiveness of domestic markets,
- variety of products available to producers and
consumers, - enhanced learning and technological catch-up
(esp. via FDI) - less wasteful rent-seeking lobbying activities by
protectionist groups
7Arguments for removing trade barriers and
subsidies (continued)
- Empirical evidence there are many examples of
reformed economies that have boomed - and none of booming closed economies
- Not to say openness is sufficient for sustained
rapid economic growth, but it is a necessary
condition - Other necessary conditions include
- macroeconomic and political stability,
- rule of law and establishment of property rights,
- efficient provision of public goods (incl. safety
nets), and - absence of distorting domestic policies
8Developing countries arguments for retaining
agric protection include
- Stabilize food prices
- Provide food security/self sufficiency, esp. in
the case of food-deficit countries - Offset terms of trade deterioration
- Slow the depopulation of rural areas
- BUT, all those policy objectives can be achieved
more efficiently by means other than protection
from import competition, none of which are
prevented by WTO
9So why do most governments still retain
protectionist policies?
- Because some workers and owners of some
productive resources, and less-competitive
farmers, fear that they will lose from reform,
and that social safety nets will not fully
compensate them - Any losses would be concentrated in the hands of
a few, while gains will be small per capita for
the many benefitting firms or consumers, so the
latter have less incentive to counter the
formers lobbying - ? A political equilibrium can involve protection
10What can alter the political equilibrium level of
protection?
- Wider dissemination of information on the gains
from trade - Technological innovations that lower trade costs
(e.g. ICT revolution), or increased openness
abroad, both of which increase the incentive for
exporters to lobby for reduced protectionism by
their home government - such globalization forces raise the rewards from
good economic governance -- and raise the cost of
poor economic governance (e.g., via FDI) - ?more countries are looking to open up, and that
is easier if done when others do likewise
11Why WTO trade negotiations make reform easier
- They offer scope for exchange of market access
- And more so the larger the number of countries
taking part in a negotiating round and the
broader the product and issue coverage - ? Hence, WTO negotiations offer far more scope
than regional or bilateral negotiations
12What else does WTO offer to make accession
worthwhile?
- Exporters receive MFN treatment in markets abroad
- A major improvement for those now facing
sanctions - Access to WTOs dispute settlement process
- Opportunity to bind tariff commitments so as to
avoid future policy back-sliding - a means of warding off protectionist domestic
vested interests (the Ullyses effect) - Requirements to make policies more transparent
- All of which reduce business uncertainty and so
encourage more investment
13Expanded opportunities for Iranian food exporters
- WTO accession will lead to fewer barriers to
Iranian exports - Provides scope for greater specialization in
those products in which Iran is most competitive
internationally - Making the most of those opportunities also
requires reducing distortions within Irans own
economy - That will happen as Iran responds to WTO members
requests during accession negotiations, but
better to be pro-active and reform for the
countrys own sake
14How WTO increases policy transparency
- Protocol of Accession document
- Single enquiry point
- Annual notifications of policy changes
- Periodic trade policy review by WTO Secretariat
(every 4-6 years) - gt All of which lower the cost to
consumers/exporters of becoming informed about
protection policies
15Reading for this topic
- See the note entitled Why the WTO exists and
what accession involves (from K. Andersons
Vietnams Transforming Economy and WTO Accession
Implications for Agriculture and Rural
Development, Singapore Institute for Southeast
Asian Studies, 1999)
16Patterns ofAgricultural Protection
- The long history (very briefly)
17Why bother to reduce sensitive agric subsidies
and trade barriers at WTO
- when agriculture contributes lt4 of global GDP
and lt9 of international trade? - Because while manufacturing import tariffs are
now low, agric protection has risen and its
applied (bound) import tariffs now average nearly
five (ten) times manufacturing tariffs globally - Which means a lower mean and higher variance of
prices of farm products in international markets
18Why bother to reduce agric subsidies and trade
barriers at WTO
- That in turn means the vast majority of the
worlds poor, who rely on farming for a living,
are less able to trade their way out of poverty
19Why reform agric policies (cont.)
- True, the harm to some poor farmers from OECD
agric protection is reduced via non-reciprocal
trade preference schemes - But those discriminatory market access schemes,
like agric. export subsidies, rely on undesirable
exceptions to worthy WTO rules - And they exclude some significant developing
countries (China, India, Indonesia, Iran,
Vietnam) and so may harm more poor farmers,
through trade diversion, than they help globally
20Nationally, too, poor farmers can be harmed by
own-country interventions
- despite the presence of large agricultural
subsidies - See, e.g. the CGE analysis for Iran by Jensen and
Tarr (RDE, 2003) - to be examined on Day 4
21Why the UR (but not earlier GATT rounds)
addressed agriculture
- The long history of government interventions that
distort agricultural markets - Distinctive features of distortions across
countries and over time - Reasons for those features, for agriculture
being neglected by GATT prior to 1986 - Why agriculture was included in the Uruguay Round
22History of government interventions in
agricultural markets
- Been going on for millennia
- Sometimes to raise tax revenue (discouraging
farmers) - Sometimes to boost food self-sufficiency (which
some view as boosting food security), thereby
encouraging some farmers - Sometimes to reduce domestic price fluctuations
- helping consumers concerned with price peaks, or
- helping producers concerned with price troughs
23Three past features of agricultural distortion
patterns
- 1. The domestic-to-border price ratio tended to
be greater for agriculture relative to that for
manufacturing, the higher a countrys per capita
income - i.e. poor (rich) countries tended to depress
(raise) incentives for farmers relative to
manufacturers vis-a-vis international market
price ratios
24Three past features of agricultural distortion
patterns (continued)
- 2. Agricultural protection tended to be greater,
the higher a countrys comparative disadvantage
in agric, other things equal - i.e. countries that would be net food exporters
(importers) under free trade tended to depress
(raise) incentives for farmers relative to
manufacturers
25Three past features of agricultural distortion
patterns (continued)
- 3. All countries tended to use trade policy
measures to reduce fluctuations in domestic food
prices and quantities - with agricultural protectionist countries mainly
reducing troughs in farmer prices - and agricultural-taxing countries mainly reducing
peaks in consumer prices of food
26Implications for agricultural protectionism
- As economies grew and their agric. comparative
advantage declined, they tended to gradually
reduce their discouragement of farmers (and
support for food consumers), and to replace it
with increasing support for farmers (at the
expense of consumers and/or taxpayers)
27Implications for food prices in intl markets
- Over time, the decline in agric taxation and
growth in agric protectionism that accompanied
economic growth put downward pressure on prices
of farm products in international markets - And the use of trade policy to stabilize domestic
food markets exacerbated fluctuations in
international food prices
28Reading
- For more on how economists have improved their
monitoring and analysis of trade policies, see K.
Andersons Measuring Effects of Trade Policy
Distortions How Far Have We Come? The World
Economy 26(4) 413-40, April 2003.
29Political economy of agricultural protection
- Why was this pattern observed across countries
and over time for many decades? - Since each countrys policy choice exacerbates
the long-run downward trend and fluctuations in
intl food prices, it encouraged other countries
to follow suit - So why did it take until the 1990s for countries
to agree multilaterally to desist (or at least
slow the growth of agricultural protectionism)?
30What was different about the 1980s that brought
agric to the Uruguay Round?
- CAP-generated surpluses led to disposal via EU
export subsidies - US ( Canada) retaliated in kind
- Pushed real food prices in intl markets to
centurys lowest level by 1986 - which more than doubled the welfare costs of
agricultural protection over the 1980s (Tyers and
Anderson 1992)
31Who brought agriculture into the UR?
- US farmers were hurt more by EU policies than EU
farmers were by US policies - Australia/NZ and food-exporting developing
country farmers were affected hugely - led to formation of Cairns Group in 1986, whose
sole aim was to keep agriculture high on UR
agenda - its agric. exports Japans manufactures exports
32Current protection pattern
- Unilateral reforms by developing countries since
the 1980s have reduced their export taxes and
other negative incentives for farmers - But some developing countries have overshot and
become protectionist towards farmers - or could do in the future, because of their much
higher bound than applied tariffs
33Implications for those countries seeking WTO
accession
- Relatively wealthy and large acceding countries,
such as Iran (and China before it), are going to
be required to bind their agricultural tariffs at
low levels - Almost certainly at less than 20 on average