Title: Economics of Abortion
1Economics of Abortion
Economics of Leisure Recreation, and Sports Econ
29120 Roberto Martinez-Espiñeira Winter 2007
21 Introduction to Economics of Abortion
- Moral and emotional dimensions of abortion
dominate the debate on abortion - But over last several decades, economists have
carried out research on issue, e.g. - supply of and demand for abortion
- effects of availability of abortion on crime
rates - abortions effect on incidence of shotgun
marriages - We examine how economists have analysed abortion
in a number of ways
32 Terminology and demographics of abortion
- Earlier the procedure, the greater the variety
and simplicity of methods to end pregnancy - (1) RU-486 abortion pill - lt 9 weeks pregnancy,
can use this drug developed and made available in
France (1988). Legalised in UK (1991), Sweden
(1992), and US (2000) - (2) Uterine Evacuation - up to 14 weeks
pregnancy. More invasive method involving uterine
evacuation using a vacuum - (3) Partial birth abortion - gt13 weeks
pregnancy, most controversial method involving
dilation, destruction and removal of fetus
(President Bush signed into law the Partial Birth
Abortion Ban Act of 2003)
43 Abortion usage - number of abortions and
abortion rate (1995)
54 Abortion Rate in England Wales and US
(1969-2000)
6An Overview of Abortion in the United States
(Guttmacher Institute)
- Half of all pregnancies to American women are
unintended four in 10 of these end in abortion - About half of American women have experienced an
unintended pregnancy, and at current rates more
than one-third (35) will have had an abortion by
age 45 - Overall unintended pregnancy rates have stagnated
over the past decade, yet unintended pregnancy
increased by 29 among poor women while
decreasing 20 among higher-income women - In 2002, 1.29 million abortions occurred, down
from 1.36 million abortions in 1996
7- Nine in 10 abortions occur in the first 12 weeks
of pregnancy - A broad cross section of U.S. women have
abortions - 56 of women having abortions are in their 20s
- 61 have one or more children
- 67 have never married
- 57 are economically disadvantaged
- 88 live in a metropolitan area and
- 78 report a religious affiliation.
8Canada
- In Canada
- http//www40.statcan.ca/l01/cst01/health43.htm
95 Availability of abortion services
- About 61 of worlds population live in countries
that have legalized abortion (Rahman et al.,
1998) - Numbers of providers - downward trend in US. 37
decline between 1982 (peak) and 2000 (Finer and
Henshaw, 2003). Why? - Greater awareness of contraception affecting
demand and then supply in turn - Direct discouragement of supply due to activities
of those who oppose abortion - Three types of provider hospitals, clinics, and
physicians offices
106 Availability of abortion services
- Finer and Henshaw (2003) surveyed 1819 abortion
providers in 2001 in US - (1) 95 of all abortions in non-hospital
facilities - (2) Mean price at gestation of 10 weeks 468
- (3) Price increases as gestation increases (20
weeks 1179) - - greater gestation, greater the complication of
procedure (more time-consuming and requires
greater skill, hence higher price) - (4) As gestation increases, fewer facilities
offer abortions (only 33 for 20 weeks). Greater
the complications, the fewer the number of
providers with expertise and facilities -
117 Availability of abortion services
- Finer and Henshaw (2003) survey (cont.)
- (5) Economies of scale - 30 abortions/year mean
price of 787/abortion and 400-990/year mean
price of 368/abortion. But EOS diminish - 5000
abortions/year mean price of 356 per abortion - (6) 8 of women having abortion in non-hospital
facilities had to travel gt 100 miles. 16 travel
between 50 and 100 miles. - - travel distance a barrier to service as it
adds to overall cost of abortion -
-
128 Abortion as an outcome vs. abortion as a cause
- Economic theory and empirical methods used on
topic of abortion in two ways - (1) abortion as an outcome - abortion (usually
demand) is the dependent variable to be explained
and is hypothesised to be a function of various
explanatory variables (abortion as an outcome) - (2) abortion as a cause - abortion is an
explanatory variable and economist considers how
incidence of abortion may be a determining factor
of something else
139 Abortion as an outcome demand
- The basic model of demand
- theory of demand for abortion draws upon work of
Becker (1960, 1965), Mincer (1962, 1963) and
Michael (1973) - in above, fertility control governed by expected
net benefit of birth of additional child - if net benefit is positive, then fecund couple
may seek to increase number of children they have
- if net benefit is negative, then fecund couple
may seek to prevent birth of child, using various
birth control methods, including abortion
1410 Abortion as an outcome demand
- So, when modelling demand for abortion, both
direct and implicit (opportunity costs) are
considered - Abortion demand f (price, income, education,
moral or cultural differences, marital status,
other measures)
1510 Abortion as an outcome demand
- Most empirical research considers aggregate
demand, usually across time and/or regions - most common approach is to use US state-level
data to determine factors explaining differences
in abortion demand across the states - virtually all empirical research on abortion by
economists estimating demand is from US
1611 Abortion as an outcome supply
- Abortion supply
- Abortion supply f (price, physicians relative
to population of women of child-bearing age,
average hospital costs, average wage of employees
in physicians offices) - supply assumed to be positively related to price
of abortion and availability of those capable of
performing abortion - supply assumed to be negatively related to input
costs proxied by average cost of day in hospital
and wages of employees
1712 Abortion as an outcome demand
- Several points of consistency from research on
abortion demand - (1) law of demand is upheld
- (2) most research reports that price elasticity
of demand is less than one - (3) abortion is a normal good - women earning
greater income find that opportunity cost from
having additional child is too great and so have
abortion to avoid costs - (4) education has ambiguous effect - on one hand,
demand for abortion positively related to
education (same argument as (3). On other hand,
demand negatively related (better educated more
aware of methods of contraception etc.)
1813 Abortion as an outcome demand
- Research on abortion demand (cont.)
- (5) several proxies for moral and cultural views
(racial composition, religion) - racial composition - controlling for income
differences, non-white women have historically
greater abortion rates implying some cultural
differences. Empirical results show expected
positive and statistically significant
coefficient - religion - expect a negative coefficient
(individuals of a faith which opposes abortion
likely to have moral aversion to abortion and
hence lower demand, all else equal). But
empirical results show insignificant effects - (6) marital status - single women more likely to
terminate pregnancy given greater costs (direct
and indirect). But empirical research has found
only weak empirical support for this
1914 Abortion as an outcome demand
2015 Abortion as an outcome anti-abortion
activities
- One of the other measures in abortion demand
equation is effects of anti-abortion activities - Kahane (2000) - uses cross-section data for US
states in 1992 and estimates both supply and
demand functions - an independent variable included in both
functions is of clinics that had experienced
picketing - hypothesised effect states where clinics
experience greater anti-abortion activities would
tend to have reduced demand and supply - estimated equations suggest that anti-abortion
activities did reduce both supply and demand
leading to reduction in equilibrium quantity of
19 and raising price by 4.3
2116 Abortion as an outcome anti-abortion
activities
22Part III Abortion as a cause
2317 Abortion as a cause endogenous pregnancy
- Variation in availability services may lead to
changes in sexual behavior of women, such as use
of contraception - Idea can be extended to issue of pregnancy itself
- i.e. contrary to common view, where pregnancy is
treated as exogenous and the pregnancy resolution
is then considered, pregnancy may in fact be
endogenous
2418 Abortion as a cause endogenous pregnancy
- Kane and Stigler (1996) model
- women get information during early months of
pregnancy and choose abortion if birth turns out
to be unwanted based on this new information - contraception and abstinence decisions made only
on basis of information available before
pregnancy occurs - abortion decision made with benefit of new
information. Unlike contraception or abstinence,
abortion works as an insurance policy to limit
downside risk when new information is negative
2518 Abortion as a cause endogenous pregnancy
- Kane and Stigler (1996) model
- increasing abortion cost increases cost of
insurance policy and discourages women from
becoming pregnant - some of these pregnancies would have resulted in
births, so model implies that increase in cost of
abortion results in decline of wanted births - more conventional effect - increased cost of
abortion discourages some women from aborting
unwanted pregnancies - net effect of restriction of abortion access on
birth rates is ambiguous
26Abortion as a cause endogenous pregnancy
2720 Abortion as a cause shotgun weddings
- Akerlof, Yellen, and Katz (1996)
- focus on way in which spread of effective
contraception and legalization of abortion
altered norms about reaction of single male to
unplanned and unwanted pregnancy of his unmarried
girlfriend - motivation behind paper - between 1965-69 and
1980-84, of out-of-wedlock births increased by
154 of whites and by 64 for blacks - over same periods, shotgun weddings (marriage
after pregnancy begins, but before 1st birthday
of child) decreased by 25 for white women and by
48 for blacks - AYK argue that availability of abortion may be
(at least partly) responsible. During same
periods, number of abortions among unmarried
women aged 15-44 increased from 88 000 in 1965-69
to 1.27 million in 1980-84
2821 Abortion as a cause shotgun weddings
2922 Abortion as a cause shotgun weddings
- AYK model - suppose two kinds of single women
- Type I (high pregnancy costs) - would terminate a
pregnancy via abortion if it were available at
reasonable cost. Willing to engage in premarital
sexual activity but only with a marriage promise - Type II (low or negative pregnancy costs) - they
want to have a baby. Would not terminate a
pregnancy via abortion even if it were available
at reasonable cost. Willing to engage in sexual
activity even without a marriage promise.
Preferred choice - marriage promise before
engaging in premarital sex, but would prefer a
baby without a husband to nothing at all. - Man - can either agree to womans request (make
implicit promise to have shotgun marriage in
event of pregnancy) or decide to end
relationship. Man would prefer not to make
marriage promise, but will do so if it is only
way to maintain relationship
3023 Abortion as a cause shotgun weddings
3124 Abortion as a cause shotgun weddings
- Situation without legal abortion in AYK model
(no abortion equilibrium) - Type I women demand marriage promises because
they are unwilling to proceed without them - Type II women also demand marriage promises, even
though they would be willing to have premarital
sex without them, because they know the men will
accept them and they (Type II women) prefer
marriage and birth to just a birth - Men provide marriage promises even though they
prefer not to, because they have no better
alternative - Shotgun marriages will occur with some frequency
since premarital sex is occurring and abortion is
unavailable
3225 Abortion as a cause shotgun weddings
- How does availability of abortion change
equilibrium? - AYK assume that cost of abortion is less than
cost of pregnancy and birth - Type I women no longer need to insist on promise
of marriage, since they can have abortion rather
than give birth (men no longer need to offer
marriage promise since there is no birth to
legitimize in first place) - Type II women can no longer insist on marriage
promise, since a man can now find a Type I woman
who will no longer insist on such a promise (and
who would not have a birth in any case) - But some Type II women will continue to have
unplanned pregnancies, but now in absence of
marriage promise, will have non-marital births
instead of shotgun marriages. They do not take
advantage of legal abortions because for them
costs of pregnancy are negative. So, non-marital
birth ratio will increase
3327 Abortion as a cause crime
- US witnessed big fall in crime during the 1990s
- Donohue and Levitt (2001) between 1973 and 1991
violent crime increased by 80, property crime
increased by 40 with the murder rate being
essentially unchanged - Following 1991, these rates dramatically reduced
by about 30 in the first two categories, and by
approximately 40 for murder - DL argue that a significant proportion of the
decrease may be due to the legalisation of
abortion in US
3428 Abortion as a cause crime
- What are the mechanisms through which abortion
may reduce crime? - Volume effect - increased abortion may reduce
the size of future cohorts of teenagers (who are
more likely to commit such crimes) - a volume
effect - Quality effect - it may reduce the birth-rate of
children who may be born into an environment that
produces teenagers who have a greater propensity
to commit crime
3529 Abortion as a cause crime
Volume effect
Fewer births
Fewer criminals
Abortion legal
Less Crime
Lower unwanted births
Lower criminals
Quality effect
3630 Abortion as a cause crime
- This hypothesis met with considerable controversy
- In support, DL appeal to research of Gruber,
Levine, and Staiger (1999) - marginal child not born because of abortion would
have grown up in an adverse environment in
comparison to average child - marginal child 60 more likely to be brought up
in single-parent household, 50 more likely to be
born in poverty, 45 more likely to live in
household receiving welfare, 40 greater chance
of dying before the age of one - Bitler and Zavodny (2002) - find negative
relationship between legalization of abortion and
incidence of child abuse
3731 Abortion as a cause crime
- DL test hypothesis empirically by regressing
state-level crime on the effective legalized
abortion rate and a variety of other control
variables using data for 1985 to 1997 - Period chosen to allow children born after
legalization of abortion to have time to become
teenagers, an age where start of criminal
activity is most common - under their theory, children born in 1985 or
later would have faced the possibility of
abortion when they were conceived - because these pregnancies were not aborted,
however, means that these children were more
likely to be wanted and were likely raised in a
better home environment with end result being
lower criminal behavior
3832 Abortion as a cause crime
- The effective legalized abortion rate
- computed as a weighted average of the abortion
rate across previous years with the weights being
computed as the proportion of total arrests in a
given year (for a given crime category)
attributed to the age group of the cohort in
question - DL argue that this measure is appropriate since
effects of abortion rate on criminal activity (if
any) would be gradually felt as the cohort ages
and enters into age where criminal activity
typically begins
3933 Abortion as a cause crime
- The results of DL study
- in states where abortion rate was higher in 1970s
and 1980s, drop in crime was greater than in
states where abortion rate was lower - in five states (Alaska, California, Hawaii, New
York, and Washington) that made abortion legal in
advance of Roe Vs. Wade 1973 decision, drop in
crime commenced earlier - An increase in the effective abortion rate by
approximately one standard deviation reduces
violent crime by 13, property crime by 9 and
murder rate by 12
4034 Abortion as a cause crime
- DL further note
- Extrapolating our results out of sample to a
counterfactual in which abortion remained illegal
and the number of illegal abortions performed
remained steady at the 1960s level, we estimate
that crime was almost 15-25 lower in 1997 than
it would have been absent legalized abortion. - An impressive result that seemingly provides an
answer to the question of why crime rates fell
dramatically in the early 1990s
4135 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime?
4236 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime?
Changes in Violent Crime and Abortion rates,
1985-1997
43 37 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime?
Changes in Property Crime and Abortion
rates,1985-1997
4438 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime?
Changes in Murder and Abortion
rates,1985-1997
4539 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime?
4640 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime
- Joyce (2004, 2006) timing of crime reductions
does not work once you break down crime by age - Foote Goetz (2006) coding error in key DL
regression. Some equations mis-specified.
Standard errors wrong - DL (2004, 2006) responds to criticisms uses
better abortion data. Results for property crime
(but not violence) still hold
47 41 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime?
- Lott and Whitley (2001) find that legalizing
abortion has no significant effect on crime with
exception of murder which they estimate may have
increased following legalization of abortion - argue that DLs use of aggregated data along
with their effective abortion rate inadequately
links abortion and crime to specific cohorts of
individuals across time - DL assume that no abortions were performed in
states other than early legalizers in pre-Roe vs.
Wade period - LW provide evidence to the contrary
4842 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime?
- Lott and Whitley study includes abortion rates of
states other than five early legalizers. Reach
the following conclusion - There are many factors that reduce murder rates,
but the legalization of abortion is not one of
them. Of the over six thousand regressions that
we estimatedonly one regression implied even a
small reduction in murder rates. All the other
estimates implied significant if very small to
modest increases in murder rates legalizing
abortion would increase murder rates by around
0.5 to 7.
4943 Legalization of Abortion and a Reduction in
Crime?
- Research from other countries
- Canada (Sen, 2002) mixed evidence, questions
over data, no age-related regressions. - Romania (Pop-Eleches, 2006) abortion
legalisation associated with improved outcomes (
lower crime), but contamination with regime
change - Australia (Leigh Wolfers, 2000 Foote Goetz,
2006) mixed evidence, no formal tests