Robust Multidimensional Poverty Comparisons - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 29
About This Presentation
Title:

Robust Multidimensional Poverty Comparisons

Description:

What if the poverty incidence curves cross? see next . cost of generality ... for 3,3 is red. Standard errors show in cells. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:65
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 30
Provided by: StephenD166
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Robust Multidimensional Poverty Comparisons


1
Robust Multidimensional Poverty Comparisons
Jean-Yves Duclos Université Laval David E.
Sahn Cornell University Stephen D.
Younger Cornell University
2
Credits and Advertisements
This research is supported by the SAGA project,
funded by USAID. For more information, see
http//www.saga.cornell.edu.
3
Motivation and Goals
  • Poverty is a multidimensional phenomenon
  • Widely accepted in principle
  • Rarely applied in practice
  • We want to explore how to compare
    multidimensional poverty in two different samples
  • sub-groups
  • or two points in time

4
Methodological Approach
  • Poverty dominance approach
  • Poverty comparisons should be
  • Robust to choice of poverty measure (index)
  • (including aggregation procedure)
  • Robust to choice of poverty line
  • Statistical

5
Specific Application
  • Spatial poverty comparisons in Uganda
  • Regions (four)
  • Urban/rural
  • Well-being/poverty measures in two dimensions
  • Household expenditures per capita
  • Childrens standardized heights

6
Methods
Robust Univariate Poverty Comparisons Poverty
incidence curves (cdfs)
7
Methods
  • If one poverty incidence curve is everywhere
    below another, then poverty is lower for that
    group for any poverty line and for any poverty
    index (measure) in a large class of indices, viz.
    those that are
  • non-decreasing (non-satiation)
  • anonymous
  • continuous at the poverty line
  • This is a robust (very general) comparison with
    respect to the poverty line and the poverty index
  • We call this poverty dominance

8
Methods
  • What if the poverty incidence curves cross?
  • see next slide
  • cost of generality
  • possibility of defining a maximum poverty line
    for which we can establish poverty dominance
  • Restrict the set of poverty indices for which the
    dominance result is valid higher orders of
    poverty comparisons

9
Methods
10
Methods
  • Second-order poverty dominance
  • The poverty incidence curves establish
    first-order poverty dominance
  • Now consider a smaller class of poverty indices
  • All the above characteristics (non-decreasing,
    anonymous, and continuous at the poverty line),
    plus
  • The Dalton transfer principle
  • We can get a dominance result for any poverty
    index in this class and for any poverty line by
    comparing the integral of the poverty incidence
    curves

11
Methods
  • Third-order poverty dominance
  • Now consider an even smaller class of poverty
    indices
  • All the above characteristics plus
  • The principle of transfer sensitivity
  • In theory, we can keep going, although this is
    the highest order for which we have a ready
    intuition
  • Relation to FGT(a) poverty measures

12
Methods
  • Bivariate poverty comparisons
  • We want to extend the univariate comparisons to
    two (and more) dimensions or measures of
    well-being
  • Much of the intuition is the same
  • Rather than comparing two-dimensional curves, we
    will compare three- (and more) dimensional
    surfaces (see next slide)
  • There are a couple interesting complications when
    we move to multiple dimensions

13
Figure 3 Bidimensional Poverty Surface
14
Methods
Intersection, Union, and Intermediate Poverty
Measures
  • Intersection poverty must be poor in both x and
    y dimensions
  • Union poverty must be poor in either dimension
  • Intermediate poverty see Figure 1

15
Figure 1 Poverty Domains
16
Theorem 1
  • Consider a class of bidimensional poverty
    indices
  • defined by

Then
17
Theorem 1 (continued)
  • So we compare the dominance surfaces over the
    domain in Figure 1.
  • Note that in this case of first-order dominance
    in both dimensions, we are just comparing the
    bivariate, intersection headcount, but at every
    point in the relevant test domain defined by
    ?(?).
  • The test is conceptually the same for union,
    intersection, and intermediate poverty
    comparisons. Only the test domain varies.
  • Tests at higher orders of dominance, in either
    dimension or both, are possible, analogous to the
    univariate case, for increasingly restricted
    classes of poverty measures
  • Main limitation the correlation increasing
    switch assumption.

18
Figure 4 Poverty Surface Difference
19
Relevance of the methods
  • First, note that we can integrate out one
    dimension of the poverty dominance surface to get
    a univariate dominance curve
  • So on Figure 4, univariate comparisons are
    possible at the extremes of the surface
  • One-at-a-time comparisons vs. bivariate
    comparisons
  • Could have univariate dominance in one or both
    dimensions, but no bivariate dominance. (Shift
    Figure 4 down.)
  • Could have no dominance in one or both univariate
    dimensions, but (intersection) bivariate
    dominance. (See Figure 4.)

20
Relevance of the methods (continued)
  • Comparison with Human Development-type indices
  • The HDI takes each dimension individually,
    integrates it to get a scalar, and then takes a
    weighted sum of those scalars
  • A more general approach would be to first sum
    each individuals values and then integrate over
    the (unidimensional) weighted Sum. This has an
    interpretation in Figure 1 -- ?(?) is a ray from
    the origin.

21
Table 1 Basic Data for Uganda
Stunted height-for-age z-score lt 2. We
generated a poverty line internal to this dataset
of children only in such a way that it yields a
national poverty headcount of 0.35, equal to that
calculated by the Uganda Bureau of Statistics.
22
Table 3 Central vs. Eastern regions
Source Uganda 1999 NHS and authors
calculations Blue shading indicates a
significantly positive t-statistic. Yellow
shading indicates a significantly negative
t-statistic. All tests are at the 5 percent
level of significance.
23
Table 6 Eastern vs. Western regions
Source Uganda 1999 NHS and authors
calculations Blue shading indicates a
significantly positive t-statistic. Yellow
shading indicates a significantly negative
t-statistic. All tests are at the 5 percent
level of significance.
24
Table 8 Western vs. Northern regions
Source Uganda 1999 NHS and authors
calculations Blue shading indicates a
significantly positive t-statistic. Yellow
shading indicates a significantly negative
t-statistic. All tests are at the 5 percent
level of significance.
25
Table 10 Rural Central vs. Urban Eastern
Source Uganda 1999 NHS and authors
calculations Blue shading indicates a
significantly positive t-statistic. Yellow
shading indicates a significantly negative
t-statistic. All tests are at the 5 percent
level of significance.
26
Table 12 Rural Central vs. Urban Northern
Source Uganda 1999 NHS and authors
calculations Blue shading indicates a
significantly positive t-statistic. Yellow
shading indicates a significantly negative
t-statistic. All tests are at the 5 percent
level of significance.
27
Critical Poverty Frontiers
  • Rather than testing for dominance over an
    arbitrary ?(?), search for a maximum set ?(?)
    for which multidimensional dominance holds
  • Analogous to a maximum poverty line in one
    dimension
  • Note that this is not necessary if one surface is
    everywhere above the other. ?(?) is the entire
    domain.

28
Table 27 Rural Eastern vs. Urban
Northern Critical Poverty Frontiers
Source Uganda 1999 NHS and authors
calculations Critical frontier for ?1,1 is pink
for ?2,2 is purple for ?3,3 is red. Standard
errors show in cells.
29
(No Transcript)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com