Title: Introductory Microeconomics EC10006
1Introductory Microeconomics (EC10006)
- Topic 2 The Theory of Consumer Choice
2I. Introduction
- We have seen how demand curves may be used to
represent consumer behaviour. - But we said very little about the nature of the
demand curve why it slopes down for example. - Now we go behind the demand curve
- i.e. we investigate how buyers reconcile what
they want with what they can get
3I. Introduction
- N.B. We can use this theory in many ways - not
simply as household consumer buying goods. - For example
- Modelling decision of worker as regards his
supply of labour (i.e. demand for leisure) - Allocation of income across time (saving and
investment)
4II. Theory of Consumer Choice
- Four elements
-
- (i) Consumers income
-
- (ii) Prices of goods
-
- (iii) Consumers tastes
-
- (iv) Rational Maximisation
5III. The Budget Constraint
- The first two elements define the budget
constraint - The feasibility of the consumers desired
consumption bundle depends upon two factors - (i) Income
- (ii) Prices
- Note We assume, for the time being, that both
are exogenous (i.e. beyond consumer's control)
6III. The Budget Constraint
- Example (N.B two goods)
- Two goods - films and meals
- Student grant 50 per week (p.w.)
- Price of meal 5
- Price of film 10
7III. The Budget Constraint
- Thus student can consume maximum p.w. of 10
meals or 5 films by devoting all of his grant to
the consumption of only one of these goods. - Alternatively, he can consume some combination of
the two goods - For example, giving up one film a week (saving
10) enables student to buy two additional meals
(costing 5 each) - .
8III. The Budget Constraint
9Figure 1 Budget Constraint
Films
5
A
4
B
1
Meals
0
2 8
10
10III. The Budget Constraint
- The budget constraint defines the maximum
affordable quantity of one good available to the
consumer given the quantity of the other good
that is being consumed. - N.B. Trade-off!
- Trade-off is represented slope of budget
constraint.
11III. The Budget Constraint
- Intercepts
- Determined by income divided by the appropriate
price of the good - Define maximum quantity of a particular good
available to an individual - Slope
- Independent of income
- Determined only by relative prices
- .
12III. The Budget Constraint
- If consumer is devoting all income to films (qf
50/10 5), then 1 meal can only be obtained by
sacrificing consumption of some films. - How many films must consumer give up?
- pm 5 thus to obtain that 5, the consumer
must give up 1/2 a film
13III. The Budget Constraint
- The slope of the budget constraint in this
example is thus
14Figure 2 Slope of Budget Constraint
Films
?qm 1
5
?qf - 0.5
4.5
Meals
0
1
10
15III. The Budget Constraint
- More generally
- Two goods (x,y), prices (px, py) and money income
(m) - m pxx pyy
- Slope of budget constraint - px/py
16III. The Budget Constraint
17III. The Budget Constraint
18Figure 3 Budget Constraint y m/py - (px/py)x
y
m/py
?x
A
?y -(px/py) ?x
B
x
0
m/px
19III. The Budget Constraint
- Intuition
- If additional units of x costs px
- Then their purchase requires a change in
consumption of y of (px/py) (i.e. a sacrifice of
y) in order to maintain the budget constraint.
20IV. Preferences
- Consider now the consumer preferences
- Given what consumer can do, what would he like to
do? - Four assumptions
- (i) Completeness
- (ii) Consistency
- (iii) Non-satiation
- (iv) Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution
21IV. Preferences
- Completeness
- Consumers can rank alternative bundles according
to the satisfaction or utility they provide - Thus given two bundles a and b, then a gt b, a lt
b or a b - Preferences assumed only to be ordinal, not
cardinal i.e. consumer simply has to be able to
say he prefers a to b, not to say by how much. -
22IV. Preferences
- Consistency
- Preferences are also assumed to be consistent
- Thus if a gt b and b gt c, then we would infer
that - a gt c
- We assume consumer is logically consistent
23IV. Preferences
- Non-satiation
- Consumers assumed to always prefer more goods
to less. - We can accommodate economics bads (e.g.
pollution) in this assumption by interpreting
then as negative goods - We can illustrate the first three assumptions
graphically as follows
24Figure 4a Preferences
y
a
b
c
x
0
25Figure 4b Preferences
y
d
a
e
g
b
c
f
x
0
26Figure 4c Preferences
y
d
h
a
e
g
b
c
i
f
x
0
27 Figure 4d Preferences
y
d
h
a
e
g
b
c
i
Indifference Curve
f
x
0
28IV. Preferences
- Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
- The quantity of y (i.e. the vertical good) the
consumer must sacrifice to increase the quantity
of x (i.e. the horizontal good) by one unit
without changing total utility. - We generally assume (smooth) diminishing MRS
- To hold utility constant, diminishing quantities
of one good must be sacrificed to obtain
successive equal increases in the quantity of the
other good.
29IV. Preferences
- Diminishing MRS derives from underlying
assumption of diminishing marginal utility - Marginal utility of a good is defined as the
change in a consumers total utility from
consuming the good divided by the change in his
consumption of the good - Diminishing MRS assumes that the increase in
utility from consuming additional units of a good
is declining
30IV. Preferences
- Non-satiation implies downward sloping
indifference curves increases in one good
require sacrifices in the other good to hold
total utility constant. - However, we can go further diminishing MRS
implies that indifference curves are convex to
origin, becoming flatter as we move to the right. - Indeed, the MRS of x for y is simply the slope of
the indifference curve
31Figure 5 Indifference Curves
y
I0
x
0
32Figure 5 Indifference Curves
y
A
B
I0
x
0
33Figure 5 Indifference Curves
y
A
A
B
I0
B
x
0
34Figure 5 Indifference Curves
y
?x 1
A
?y
A
?x 1
B
?y
I0
B
x
0
35IV. Preferences
- Diminishing MRS implies consumers prefer
consumption bundles containing mixtures of goods
rather than extremes - i.e. Bundle C (5, 5) preferred to both Bundle A
(2, 8) and Bundle B (8, 2) - Diminishing MRS (i.e. diminishing marginal
utility)
36Figure 6 Indifference Curves
y
A
B
I0
x
0
37Figure 6 Indifference Curves
y
A
8
B
2
I0
x
0
2 8
38Figure 6 Indifference Curves
y
A
8
C
5
I1
B
2
I0
x
0
2 5 8
39IV. Preferences
- Note
- (i) Any point on the indifference map must lay
on an indifference curve. - (ii) indifference curves cannot cross
- Thus every point on the indifference map must lay
on one and only one indifference curve.
40Figure 7 Indifference Curves
y
I2
I1
I0
x
0
41Figure 8 Indifference Curves Cannot Cross
y
a ? b and a ? c ? b ? c But b gt c
a
b
I1
c
I0
x
0
42V. Utility Maximisation
- Budget line shows the consumers affordable
bundles given the market environment. - The indifference map shows the consumers desired
bundles - To complete the model we assume rational
maximisation - i.e. the consumer chooses the
affordable bundle that maximises his utility.
43V. Utility Maximisation
- This is a non-trivial point. We are implicitly
assuming that the consumer only derives utility
from the consumption of x and y. - Moreover, rational maximisation implies consumer
processes huge amount of information before
choosing his most preferred bundle - In reality, perhaps we satisfice
44V. Utility Maximisation
- The optimal choice bundle will be that point at
which an indifference curve just touches the
budget line - That is, where an indifference curve is tangent
to the budget line - In words, where the consumers marginal rate of
substitution (MRS) and economic rate of
substitution (ERS) are in accord
45V. Utility Maximisation
- Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
- Amount of y consumer willing to sacrifice for
one extra unit of x - Slope of indifference curve
- Economic Rate of Substitution (ERS)
- Amount of y the consumer is obliged to sacrifice
for one extra unit of x - Slope of budget line
46Figure 9 Equilibrium (MRS ERS)
y
E1
y1
I2
I1
I0
x
0
x1
47Figure 10 Disequlibrium (MRS ? ERS)
y
?x
E0
?yERS
?yMRS
I0
x
0
48V. Utility Maximisation
- Since preferences are unique, individuals will
not choose identical bundles, even when
confronted by same market environment - But they will all move to point where MRS ERS
- Even with different preferences, since ERS is the
same for everyone (i.e. we all face same relative
prices), it must be the case that in equilibrium - MRS1 ERS MRS2
49VI. Comparative Statics
- We now consider how the consumer responds to
changes in his market environment - That is, to changes in
- (i) Endowment income
- (ii) Prices.
- N.B, Comparative Statics / Dynamics
50VI. Comparative Statics
- Changes in Income
- An increase in endowment income causes a parallel
shift out of the budget constraint - A decrease in endowment income causes a parallel
shift in of the budget constraint
51Figure 11 Increase in Income m? gt m
y
x
0
52Figure 12 Increase in Income m? gt m
y
A
I1
x Normal y Normal
B
E1
C
E0
D
I0
x
0
53Figure 12 Increase in Income m? gt m
y
x Inferior y Normal
A
E1
I1
B
C
E0
D
I0
x
0
54Figure 12 Increase in Income m? gt m
y
A
B
I1
C
E0
x Normal y Inferior
E1
D
x
0
55Figure 12 Increase in Income m? gt m
y
x Inferior y Normal
A
B
x Normal y Normal
C
E0
x Normal y Inferior
D
I0
x
0
56VI. Comparative Statics
- Changes in Prices
- An increase in price causes a pivot inwards of
the budget constraint - An decrease price causes a pivot outwards of the
budget constraint.
57Figure 13 Fall in Price
y
x
0
58VII. Income Substitution Effects
- Price changes affects the optimal choice bundle
in two distinct ways - First, there is a change in relative prices as
represented by a change in the slope of the
budget constraint. - Second, there is a change in purchasing power
(i.e. real income). The same level of money
income is now worth more to the consumer in terms
of its ability to purchase both goods.
59Figure 13 Fall in Price
y
x
0
60Figure 14 Effects of Fall in Price
y
Fall in price of good x reduces slope of budget
constraint (ERS) - i.e. fall in the relative
price of good x
Fall in price of good x increases consumers
real income - i.e. expansion of the budget set
x
0
61Figure 15 Effects of a Fall in Price
y
E1
E0
x
0
62Figure 15 Effects of a Fall in Price
y
E0
E1
x
0
63Figure 15 Effects of a Fall in Price
y
E1
E0
x
0
64Figure 15 Effects of a Fall in Price
y
A
Good x is Giffen
B
Good x is Non-Giffen
E0
C
x
0
65VII. Income and Substitution Effects
- We decompose total effect of price change into
-
- (i) Income Effect
- (ii) Substitution Effect
- The income effect is the adjustment of demand to
the change in real income. - The substitution effect is the adjustment of
demand to the change in relative prices.
66Figure 14 Income and Substitution Effects (Fall
in px)
y
A
E0
I0
x
0
A
67Figure 14 Income and Substitution Effects (Fall
in px)
y
A
E0
E1
I1
I0
x
0
A
B
68VII. Income and Substitution Effects
- We decompose the overall change in demand into
income and substitution effects by
(hypothetically) adjusting the consumers income
to restore him to the level of real income he
enjoyed before the price change - Given the fall in px and the subsequent increase
in real income, we therefore reduce the
consumers real income mechanically, we drag the
new budget line back until it is just tangent to
the original indifference curve.
69Figure 14 Income and Substitution Effects (Fall
in px)
y
A
E0
E1
I1
I0
x
0
A
B
70Figure 14 Income and Substitution Effects (Fall
in px)
y
A
C
E0
E1
E2
I1
I0
x
0
A C B
71Figure 14 Income and Substitution Effects (Fall
in px)
y
A
C
E0
E1
E2
I1
I0
x
0
A C B
72Figure 14 Income and Substitution Effects (Fall
in px)
y
E0-E1 Total Effect (x0-x1) E0-E2 Substitution
Effect (x0-x2) E2-E1 Income Effect (x2-x1)
A
E0
E1
E2
I1
I0
x
0
A
B
x0 x2 x1
73VIII. Inferior and Giffen Goods
- In a two good model, a price change always
induces a substitution effect in the opposite
direction of the change in price - i.e a rise (fall) in px induces a substitution
away (towards) good x ceteris paribus - We usually say that the own price substitution
effect is always negative.
74VIII. Inferior and Giffen Goods
- The income effect, however, can be positive (i.e.
normal good) or negative (i.e. inferior good) - A rise in the price of a normal good induces a
negative substitution effect and a negative
income effect, both of which act to reduce the
demand for good x - A rise in the price of an inferior good, however,
induces a negative substitution effect but a
positive income effect, thus the overall effect
is ambiguous
75VIII. Inferior and Giffen Goods
- If, when the price of an inferior good rises, the
positive income effect dominates the negative
substitution effect, we have the case of a Giffen
Good - That is, a good for which demand rises (falls)
when price rises (falls) - Giffen goods are very inferior good
76Figure 15 Income and Substitution Effects Good
x Normal / Non-Giffen
y
A
I0
C
E1
E0
I1
E2
x
0
A C
B
77Figure 15 Income and Substitution Effects Good
x Inferior / Non-Giffen
y
I1
A
I0
E1
C
E0
E2
x
0
A C
B
78Figure 15 Income and Substitution Effects Good
x Inferior / Giffen
y
I1
A
E1
C
E0
E2
I0
x
0
A C
B
79VIV. Measuring Real Income
- When we decomposed the change in demand resulting
from a change in price into an income and
substitution effect, we did so by varying money
income - Specifically, when the price of good x fell, we
varied the consumers money income to hold his
real income constant, where real income was
defined as the consumers ability to enjoy a
particular level of utility
80VIV. Measuring Real Income
- Varying money income is this way is known as a
Hicks Compensating Variation in money income
(HCV) - HCV allows consumer to enjoy original level of
utility at the new relative price ratio - We compensate the consumer for the change in
price - Sounds odd in respect of a price fall.
81Figure 16.1 Hicks Compensating
Variation (Price Fall)
y
A
C
B
I1
I0
x
0
82Figure 16.2 Hicks Compensating
Variation (Price Rise)
y
B
C
A
I1
I0
x
0
83VIV. Measuring Real Income
- An alternative definition of real income is the
ability to consumer not a particular level of
utility, but a particular bundle of goods - i.e. we vary the consumers money income
following a change in price to permit him to
consumer his original bundle of goods at the new
relative price ratio - The is know as the Slutsky Compensating
Variation (SCV) in money income.
84Figure 16.3 Slutsky Compensating
Variation (Price Fall)
y
A
C
I0
B
I2
I1
x
0
85Figure 16.4 Slutsky Compensating
Variation (Price Rise)
y
B
C
I2
A
I1
I0
x
0
86VIV. Measuring Real Income
- Both Hicks and Slutsky compensating variations
adjust the consumers new level of income (i.e.
the level following the price change) such that
he is able to enjoy either his original level of
utility (Hicks) or his original consumption
bundle (Slutsky) - An alternative approach is to adjust the
consumers original level of income in such a way
that he is able to enjoy the level of utility
(Hicks) or the consumption bundle (Slutsky) that
he would have been able to enjoy were he to face
the change in prices
87VIV. Measuring Real Income
- That is, we vary the consumers money income at
the original relative price ratio to enable him
to enjoy the level of real income (i.e. utility
or consumption bundle) that he would have been
able to enjoy from the price change - i.e. we provide the consumer with an Equivalent
Variation in money income - A variation in money income that will adjust the
consumers real income in a manner analogous to
the price change
88Figure 16.5 Hicks Equivalent Variation (Price
Fall)
y
B
A
C
I1
I0
x
0
89Figure 16.6 Hicks Equivalent Variation (Price
Rise)
y
C
A
B
I1
I0
x
0
90Figure 16.7 Slutsky Equivalent
Variation (Price Fall)
y
B
A
I2
C
I1
I0
x
0
91Figure 16.8 Slutsky Equivalent
Variation (Price Rise)
y
C
A
I0
B
I2
I1
x
0
92VIV. Measuring Real Income
- To summarise, we have eight cases
- Hicks / Slutsky
- Compensating Variation / Equivalent Variation
- Price Rise / Price Fall
93Figure 16.1 Hicks Compensating
Variation (Price Fall)
y
A
C
B
I1
I0
x
0
94Figure 16.2 Hicks Compensating
Variation (Price Rise)
y
B
C
A
I1
I0
x
0
95Figure 16.3 Slutsky Compensating
Variation (Price Fall)
y
A
C
I0
B
I2
I1
x
0
96Figure 16.4 Slutsky Compensating
Variation (Price Rise)
y
B
C
I2
A
I1
I0
x
0
97Figure 16.5 Hicks Equivalent Variation (Price
Fall)
y
B
A
C
I1
I0
x
0
98Figure 16.6 Hicks Equivalent Variation (Price
Rise)
y
C
A
B
I1
I0
x
0
99Figure 16.7 Slutsky Equivalent
Variation (Price Fall)
y
B
A
I2
C
I1
I0
x
0
100Figure 16.8 Slutsky Equivalent
Variation (Price Rise)
y
C
A
I0
B
I2
I1
x
0
101X. Applications
- Two key areas
- (i) Labour Supply
-
- (ii) Intertemporal Choice.
102X.1 Labour Supply
- Consider individuals role as a supplier of
factor services - Individuals sell their labour to firms in return
for a wage. - Individual makes a choice between income and
leisure given the dual constraints of time and
the wage
103Figure 17 Budget Constraint
Y
Ymax
w
Y0
L
0
T
104 Figure 18 Preferences
Y
I2
I1
I0
L
0
105Figure 21 Labour Market Equilibrium
Y
Ymax
Y1 Y0 w(T L1) Ymax Y0 wT
E0
Y1
I1
w
A
Y0
L
0
L1
T
106Figure 22 Increase in Unearned Income
Y
E2
Y2
I2
E1
Y1
B
I1
A
Y0
L
0
L1 L2
T
107 Figure 23 Increase in Wage Rate
Y
E2
I2
E1
I1
L
0
T
L2 L1
108 Figure 23 Increase in Wage Rate
Y
E2
E3
I2
E1
I1
L
0
T
L3 L2 L1
109X.1 Labour Supply
- Note that the income and substitution effects
work against one another - Because leisure is a normal good, the income
effect from the increase in wage increases the
demand for leisure - But the wage rate is the opportunity cost, or
price, of leisure. Thus, an increase in the wage
rate / price of leisure induces a substitution
away from leisure
110 Figure 23 Increase in Wage Rate
Y
E1-E2 Total Effect (L1-L2) E1-E3 Substitution
Effect (L1-L3) E3-E2 Income Effect (L3-L2)
E2
E3
I2
E1
I1
L
0
T
L3 L2 L1
111Figure 24 Labour Supply Curve
w
Ls
E2
w2
E1
w1
(T-L)
0
(T-L1) (T-L2) T
112X.1 Labour Supply
- If the income effect dominates the substitution
effect, then we have a situation in which an
increase in the wage (i.e. the price of leisure)
leads to an increase in the demand for leisure - That is
- Leisure is Giffen
- but Normal!
113Figure 25 Increase in Wage Rate
Y
E1-E2 Total Effect (L1-L2) E1-E3 Substitution
Effect (L1-L3) E3-E2 Income Effect (L3-L2)
I2
I1
E3
E2
E1
L
0
L3 L1
L2 T
114Figure 26 Labour Supply Curve
w
Ls
E2
w2
E1
w1
(T-L)
0
(T-L2) (T-L1) T
115X.1 Labour Supply
- Empirically, we tend to see labour supply curves
bending backwards at high wage rates - i.e.
116Figure 27 Labour Supply Curve
w
Ls
H (T-L)
0
117X.1 Labour Supply
- Rather than at low wage rates
- i.e.
118Figure 28 Labour Supply Curve
w
Ls
H (T-L)
0
119X.1 Labour Supply
- Moreover, backward bending labour supply curves
are usually observed for males but nor females - i.e.
120Figure 29 Labour Supply Curve
w
H (T-L)
0
121X.1 Labour Supply
- Implications of backward bending labour supply
curve - Multiple equilibria
- Unstable equilibria
- What happens to w if it is perturbed slightly
above / below its equilibirum level, w? Do
forces of excess demand / excess supply force w
back to w
122Figure 29 Labour Supply Curve
w
Ld
Ls
Unstable Equilibrium
E1
Stable Equilibrium
E2
H (T-L)
0
123X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- Assume individual lives for two periods with a
lifetime income endowment of y (y1, y2) - Consumption over time is c (c1, c2)
- Now, x saved today (i.e. period 1) will yield
(1r)x tomorrow (i.e. period 2) - The future value of x today is thus (1r)x
124X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- Conversely, the present value of x received
tomorrow (i.e. period 2) is - Intuitively, if we receive x tomorrow, can
borrow z today, where
125X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- Thus, given an income endowment of
- Then the maximum period 1 income is
- And the maximum period 2 income is
126Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint
y2
y1
0
127X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- Assume individual consumes in both periods
- If the value of consumption in period 1 is ,
then can save in period 1 for period
2 consumption in excess of period 2 income, -
128Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
129Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
130Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
131X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- Note the effects of changes in income endowment
or interest rate - Change in income endowment shifts the
inter-temporal budget constraint parallel - Changes in interest rate pivot the budget
constraint around the initial income endowment
132Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2, y2
y1
0
133Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2, y2
y1
0
134Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
135Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget
Constraint Increase in Rate of Interest
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
136X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- Consider a borrower
- That is
- (c1 - y1) gt 0
- How does he react to changes in interest rate?
-
-
137Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint Period
1 Borrowing
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
138Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget
Constraint Borrower (Fall in Interest Rate)
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
139X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- Thus, if interest rate falls
-
- (i) Borrower remains a borrower
- (ii) Is better-off
- (iii) Increases borrowing is c1 a normal good
140- Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget Constraint
- Borrower (Fall in Interest Rate)
- Substitution Effect E0-E2
- Income Effect E2-E1
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
141X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- If interest rate rises
-
- (i) Borrower is definitely worse off
-
142Figure 30 Intertemporal Budget
Constraint Borrower Increase in Interest Rate
c2, y2
c1, y1
0
143X.2 Intertemporal Choice
- Conversely, for savers (c1 - y1) lt0
- Rise in interest rates (i) Remain savers (ii)
Better off (iii) Increase saving if c2 is a
normal good - Fall in interest rate (i) Definitely worse off
-
-