Title: Introductory Microeconomics EC10006
1Introductory Microeconomics (EC10006)
- Topic 4 Perfect Competition Monopoly
2I. Introduction
- MR MC rule requires knowledge of market
structure - One of the major influences on MR, and thus on
its supply decision, is the degree of
competitiveness the firm faces in the market. - That is, the number of actual and potential
competitors
3I. Introduction
- This makes sense! If firm is the only player in
the market, then we would expect it to behave
differently than if it were one of (very) many - In what follows we will examine the causes and
effects of market structure
4II. Taxonomy of Competition
- Microeconomics has tended to categorise the
degree of competition a particular firm faces
into three very precise and distinct categories - A lot
- A bit
- None!
5Figure 1 Taxonomy of Competition
Perfect Competition
Monopoly
Imperfect Competition
More Competition
Less Competition
Monopolistic Competition
Oligopoly
Collusive (i.e. Cartel)
Non-Collusive
6III. Perfect Competition
- Market structure where competitive forces are at
their greatest - Definition A Perfectly Competitive (PC) market
is one in which both buyers and sellers believe
that their own buying or selling decisions have
no effect on the market price - Sometimes referred to as an atomistic market
7III. Perfect Competition
- Formal Characteristics
- 1. (Very) Large number of buyers and sellers
- 2. Homogenous product
- 3. Free entry and exit (in long-run)
- 4. Perfect knowledge.
- Implication All firms face same, perfectly
elastic, demand curve
8Figure 2 Perfectly Elastic Demand
p
S0
E0
d0
p0
D0
0
Q0 Q
q
Industry
Representative Firm
9III. Perfect Competition
- Why would firm not raise or lower price above or
below p0? - If p gt p0, then it would sell nothing because
consumers have perfect knowledge and good is
homogenous - Conversely, no point in setting p lt p0 since it
can sell as much as it wishes at p0
10III. Perfect Competition
- Firms demand curve is also its AR and MR curve
- Recall
- AR TR / q
- MR ?TR / ?q
- Since demand is perfectly elastic, AR MR p
11Figure 3 Demand AR MR
p
E0 E1
p0
d AR MR
q
q0 q1
0
12III. Perfect Competition
- Consider short-run profit maximising rule
- First, we know that to maximise profit we need to
set SMR SMC - But, SMC must also be rising
- otherwise, profit (loss) is minimised
(maximised)
13Figure 4 Optimal Output
p
SMC
? min ? max
E0
E1
p0
d AR MR
q
0
q0 q1
14III. Perfect Competition
- Thus, short-run profit maximising rule
- (1) MR SMC
- (2) SMC is rising
- But, it could always be in firm's interest to
produce nothing! - Is there a shut-down price?
15Figure 5 Demand AR MR ? gt 0
p
SMC
Eo
SAC
p0
AR MR
PROFIT
SAVC
SAC0
q
0
q0
16Figure 6 Demand AR MR ? 0
p
SMC
SAC
SAVC
E1
p1
AR MR
q
0
q1
17Figure 7 Demand AR MR - TFC lt ? lt 0
p
SMC
SAC
E2
SAVC
SAC2
LOSS lt - TFC
p2
MR
q
0
q2
18Figure 8 Demand AR MR ? - TFC lt 0
p
SMC
SAC
E3
SAVC
SAC3
LOSS TFC
p3
AR MR
q
0
q3
19Figure 9 Demand AR MR ? lt - TFC lt 0
p
SMC
SAC
SAVC
SAC4
LOSS gt TFC
p4
AR MR
E4
q
0
q4
20III. Perfect Competition
- Thus, short-run profit maximising rule
- MR SMC
- SMC is rising
- p gt SAVC
- Supply curve of the firm is that part of its SMC
curve above minimum SAVC
21III. Perfect Competition
- Note, short-run shutdown price p3
- ? (p3) p3q3 SAC(q3)q3
- SAVC(q3) SAC(q3)q3
-
- -AFC(q3)q3
- -TFC
22III. Perfect Competition
- Thus, short-run supply curve of firm is that part
of its SMC above minimum AVC - Similarly, long-run supply curve is that party of
LMC above minimum LAC - i.e. long-run shutdown option is to leave the
industry
23Figure 10 Long-Run Shut-Down
p
LMC
LAC
p0
AR MR
q
0
q0
24III. Perfect Competition
- Compare SR and LR supply curves
- SR supply curve of firm is that part of its SMC
above minimum AVC similarly, long-run supply
curve is that part of LMC above minimum LAC - i.e. LR shutdown option is to leave the
industry - Note that SR supply curve lays below LR supply
curve (recall Envelope) and is steeper
25Figure 11 Long-Run Short-Run Supply
p
SSR
Min LAC
SLR
p1
p0
Min AVC
q
0
26III. Perfect Competition
- SSR lays below SLR because LAC is envelope of
SACs and SAVCs lay below SAC since SAC includes
AFC - SSR is steeper than SLR because it will always be
less costly for firm to increase output when it
can alter all inputs (i.e. K an L) appropriately
(i.e. when it is in LR) - Now, consider MR MC condition
-
27III. Perfect Competition
- TR0 p0q0
- TR1 p1q1
- Thus
- ?TR ? TR1 - TR0 p1q1 - p0q0
- p1q1 - p0q0 (p1q0 - p1q0)
- p1q1 - p1q0 p1q0 - p0q0
- p1(q1 - q0) (p1 - p0)q0
28III. Perfect Competition
- ?TR p1(q1 - q0) (p1 - p0)q0
- p1?q ?pq0
- Thus
- Consider small changes in (p, q) such that
p1?p0, q1?q0 , and so (p0, p1) p and (q0, q1)
q
29III. Perfect Competition
30III. Perfect Competition
- Thus
- Under perfect competition, E?? such that MR p
- Also, since MR MC in equilibrium, then
31III. Perfect Competition
32III. Perfect Competition
- Lerner (1934) Index of Monopoly Power
- Note that under perfect competition, E?? such
that p?MC - Firms can only mark-up p over MC iff E lt ?
33Figure 12 Elasticity of Demand and Slope of
(Inverse) Demand Curve
p
E0
dc
db
da
q
0
34III. Perfect Competition
- Industry Supply
- SR industry supply curve (when factor prices are
given) is the horizontal summation of each firms
SMC curve above minimum AVC - Similarly, LR industry supply curve (when factor
prices are given) is horizontal summation of each
firms LMC curve above minimum LAC -
35Figure 13 SR Industry Supply
p p p
p2
p1
p0
qa qb
Q
0
0
0
q0 q1 q2
q0 q1 q2 Q0
Q1 Q2
Firm A Firm B Industry
36III. Perfect Competition
- Consider effect of an exogenous increase in
industry demand for the good - Increase in demand will increase each existing
firms profit - Existing firms increase SR supply by moving up
their SMC curves -
-
37Figure 14a SR Industry Supply
p
p
SMC
SAC
e0
d0
E0
p0
D0
0
Q0
Q q0
q
Industry
Representative Firm
38Figure 14b SR Industry Supply
p
p
SMC
SAC
e1
d1
E1
e0
d0
E0
p0
D1
D0
0
Q0 Q1
Q q0 q1
q
Industry
Representative Firm
39III. Perfect Competition
- But, the existence of super-normal profits will
attract other firms into the industry - This will shift out industry (SR) supply curve
and lead to a fall in the (perfectly elastic)
demand facing individuals firms - Industry supply is higher because of entry of new
firms each firm produces same amount in new
equilibrium (E2) as original firms produced in
original equilibrium (E0) -
40Figure 14c SR Industry Supply
p
p
SMC
SAC
e1
d1
E1
e2 e0
d0
E0 E2
p0
D1
D0
0
Q0 Q1 Q2 Q
q0 q1
q
Industry
Representative Firm
41III. Perfect Competition
- LR supply curve of industry is horizontal /
perfectly elastic - LR supply price of industry is equal to minimum
LAC of constituent firms - Thus, demand only determines quantity price is
supply (i.e. cost) determined) -
42Figure 15 LR Industry Supply
p P
LMC
LAC
e
E
SLR
p
D
0 q
q 0 Q
Q
Representative Firm
Industry
43III. Perfect Competition
- LR supply curve of industry is upward sloping in
two situations - 1. Factor prices increase with usage
- 2. Heterogeneous firms
- Consider each in turn
-
44III. Perfect Competition
- Consider first the SR response of a
representative firm and the industry to an
increase in demand - If factor prices increase with usage, then
increase in demand induces each firm to increase
output along its SMC curve - But, increase in industry supply of output
increases demand for / price of the variable
input
45III. Perfect Competition
- Increase in price of variable input shifts up
vertically each firms SMC curve - The expansion of output by each firm can thus be
interpreted as a combination of a movement
along and a shift of its SMC curve - Similarly, the expansion of output by the
industry - combination of a movement along /
shift of the aggregation of constituent firms
SMC curves
46Figure 16 SR Industry Supply Factor prices
increase with usage
p
p
D1
?SSR
SSR
?SMC1
E1
e1
p1
?SMC0
SMC0
D0
SMC1
E0
p0
e0
0
q0 q1
q Q0 Q1
Q
Representative Firm
Industry
47III. Perfect Competition
- In LR, free entry / exit implies each firm
produces at minimum LAC - If firms are equally efficient, then firms have
same minimum LAC and industry supply is perfectly
elastic - Intuitively, whatever happens to demand, SR
supply, and thus price, competitive forces ensure
a normal-profit LR equilibrium such that LR
supply is perfectly elastic at minimum LAC
48III. Perfect Competition
- But this presumes factor prices are fixed
- What if factor prices increase with their usage?
- In this case, then LR expansion of output by the
industry will increase the price of all factors
such that each constituent firms LAC and LMC
will shift-up -
49III. Perfect Competition
- Thus, LR industry response to increase in demand
when factor prices increase with their usage is a
combination of -
- (i) a movement along a perfectly elastic LR
supply curve (i.e. one determined by minimum LAC
of equally efficient constituent firms, but
where factor prices are held constant) -
- (ii) a shift-up of such a curve (i.e. where
factor prices are allowed to increase)
50Figure 17 LR Industry Supply Factor prices
increase with usage
p
E1
E0
D1
D0
Q
0
51III. Perfect Competition
- Consider also heterogeneous firms
- i.e. inter-firm differences in efficiency
- The earlier firms enter into an industry, the
lower their cost curves subsequent firms are
increasingly less efficient
52III. Perfect Competition
- At any particular LR equilibrium price, p, the
least efficient (i.e. marginal) firm is that
firm which can make just normal profit at p - The more efficient (i.e. intra-marginal) firms
make positive profits at p and, thus, produce in
the region of DRS -
53Figure 18 LR Industry Supply Heterogeneous Firms
p p p
LMC2
SLR
LMC1
LAC2
LAC1
E
e2
e1
p
LAC1
D
0
0
0
q1 q
q2 q Q
Q
(Intra-Marginal) Firm 1 (Marginal) Firm
2 Industry
54IV. Monopoly
- Consider now the other extreme market environment
- Monopoly single seller
- The monopolist is the industry no distinction
between firm and industry less need to
distinguish SR and LR since entry / exit is less
of an issue - Consider monopolist's AR and MR curves
55IV. Monopoly
- As with PC firm, demand curve is also the AR
curve - But since AR curve is downward sloping, MR curve
lays below AR curve - Intuitively, to sell more Q, monopolist has to
cut p on all units of Q -
56Figure 19a AR and MR
p
TR1 p1 TR2 2p2 MR2 2p2 - p1 p2
- (p1-p2) lt p2
A
p1
B
p2
C
MR2
D AR
MR
Q
0
1 2
57Figure 19b AR and MR
p
TR1 p1 TR2 2p2 MR2 2p2 - p1 p2
- (p1-p2) lt p2
A
p1
B
p2
p2
C
MR2
D AR
MR
Q
0
1 2
58Figure 19c AR and MR
p
TR1 p1 TR2 2p2 MR2 2p2 - p1 p2
- (p1-p2) lt p2
A
p1
(p1-p2)
B
p2
p2
C
MR2
D AR
MR
Q
0
1 2
59IV. Monopoly
- We will assume that the monopolist, like PC firms
and industries, faces increasing and then
decreasing returns to both factors and scale
i.e. U-Shaped SAC / LAC - N.B. Monopoly that faces IRS always is termed a
Natural Monopoly - Monopolist's profit can be supernormal (most
likely), normal or negative -
60Figure 20a Monopolist LR Equilibrium p gt 0
p
LMC
p0
LAC
Profit
LAC0
D AR
MR
Q
0
Q0
61Figure 20b Monopolist LR Equilibrium p lt 0
p
LMC
LAC
LAC0
Loss
p0
D AR
MR
Q
0
Q0
62Figure 20c Monopolist LR Equilibrium p 0
p
LMC
LAC
p0 LAC0
D AR
MR
Q
0
Q0
63IV. Monopoly
- Consider efficiency
-
- Allocative Efficiency (AE)
- p MC
- Productive Efficiency (PE)
- IRS are exhausted such that LAC is minimised
64IV. Monopoly
- (Non-Discriminating) monopolist is never AE and
(extremely) unlikely to be PE - PE would require MR curve to cross MC at minimum
AC - It can happen, but infinitely small chance!
65Figure 21 Monopolist LR Equilibrium Productive
efficiency is possible, but very unlikely!
p
LMC
pmes
LAC
LACmes
D AR
MR
Q
0
Qmes
66IV. Monopoly
- Allocative Efficiency requires marginal (social)
benefit (MSB) to equal marginal (social) cost
(MSC) - Define MSC MPC MEC
- MSB MPB MEB
- i.e. marginal social benefit (cost) equals
marginal private benefit (cost) plus marginal
external benefit (costs)
67IV. Monopoly
- Private benefits (costs) are those enjoyed
(incurred) by agent producing or consuming) the
good - External benefits (costs) are the non-price
effects on the production or consumption of other
members of society - Assume (for now!) that MEC MEB 0 such that
allocative efficiency requires MPC MPB
68IV. Monopoly
- Now
- MPC LMC of monopolist
- MPB price consumers willing to pay for good
- Thus, the MPB can be derived from the
monopolist's Demand AR curve - Recall, the (inverse) demand curve sets out
consumer's reservation price vis. the maximum
price the consumer is willing to pay
69Figure 22 D MPB
p
A
p1
B
p2
C
p3
D MPB
Q
0
Q1 Q2
Q3
70IV. Monopoly
- It is apparent that the monopolist produces less
output than the socially optimal (allocatively
efficient) level - Monopolist maximises profit by setting MR MC
- Allocative efficiency is achieved when p MC
- Since p lt MR, it must be the case that monopolist
output is less than socially optimal
71Figure 23 Monopolist LR Equilibrium DWL ABC
p
Privately Optimal
LMC MPC
Socially Optimal
A
p0
B
LAC
LAC0
D AR MPB
C
MR
Q
0
Q0 Q1
72IV. Monopoly
- Consider the (overnight) monopolisation of a PC
industry - The constituent firms of the industry become
manufacturing plants for the monopolist - Assume that the SLR ?LMC of the PC industry
becomes the monopolist's LMC curve (N.B.
heterogeneous firms thus SLR is upward sloping)
73IV. Monopoly
- Define social welfare (SW) as sum of consumer
surplus (CS) and producer surplus (PS) - SW PS CS
- Note No concern with equity!
- Define CS as excess of what consumers are willing
to pay over what they actually pay PS as excess
of what producers actually receive over what they
are willing to receive
74Figure 22a Monopoly and PC
p
A
SLR
CS
Perfect Competition CS ABC PS BCD SW ABD
B
C
pc
PS
D
D AR
Q
0
Qc
75Figure 22a Monopoly and DWL
p
A
LMC
E
G
pm
Monopoly CS AEG PS GEFD SW AEFD DWL EBF
B
C
pc
F
D
D AR
MR
Q
0
Qm Qc
76Figure 22a Monopoly and DWL
p
A
LMC
E
G
pm
Monopoly ?CS -GEHC - EBH ?PS GEHC - BHF ?SW
-EBF - BHF
B
C
H
pc
F
D
D AR
MR
Q
0
Qm Qc
77IV. Monopoly
- But this is a static analysis - i.e. the
instantaneous effects of monopolisation what
happens to cost over time, i.e. dynamic effects? - Two scenarios
- (i) Liebenstein X-Inefficency (pessimistic)
- (ii) Schumpeter RD (optimistic)
- Balance of argument - empirical issue
78Figure 22a Monopoly and DWL
p
A
LMC
Liebenstein
E
B
pm
B
C
pc
Schumpeter
F
D
D AR
MR
Q
0
Qm Qc
79IV. Monopoly
- To summarise monopolies would appear to be
harmful to society in sense that they lead to DWL
(i.e. consumers lose more than producers gain) - Perhaps some benefits over time (RD), but that
is an empirical issue - There is an argument, however, that if we are to
have monopolies, then we should make them as
powerful as possible!
80IV. Monopoly
- Price Discrimination (PD)
-
- Selling different units of the same good at
different prices - Two basic approaches to PD
- Charging different prices to different consumers
for same units of the good - Charging same consumers different prices for
different units of the good
81IV. Monopoly
- Three main types of PD
- First-Degree (Perfect)
- Second-Degree
- Third-Degree
- Consider each in turn
82IV. Monopoly
- First-Degree (Perfect) Price Discrimination
- Monopolist charges each consumer maximum price
willing to pay for each unit of the good thus
demand curve is also MR curve, since only reduce
p on additional units of Q - Monopolist produces socially optimal Q (i.e. p
MC) and is thus allocatively efficient (DWL 0)
but completely inequitable (CS 0)
83Figure 23 First Degree (Perfect) Price
Discrimination
p
A
p1
A'
LMC
p2
A''
Perfect PD CS 0 PS ABC SW ABC DWL 0
PS
B
p
C
D MR
Q
0
1 2 Q
84IV. Monopoly
- Second-Degree Price Discrimination
- Multipart tariff consumer chooses quantity of
good wishes to consume at a given price after
paying a rent for the right to receive any supply
at all - E.g. Utilities - gas, electricity, water
- Can (almost) replicate first-degree PD profit and
produce socially-optimal level of output
85Figure 23 Second-Degree Price Discrimination
p
A
LMC
Tariff
Multipart Tariff Rental Tariff ABD PS ABC SW
ABC DWL 0
B
D
p
C
D MR
Q
0
Q
86IV. Monopoly
- Third-Degree Price Discrimination
- Monopolist sells good at different prices to
different groups of consumers - Monopolist must be able to identify distinct
markets - Geographical, age, gender, race
87IV. Monopoly
- Assume monopolist sells identical good to two
markets (A and B) - Assume costs of producing and supplying good to
either market are identical - E.g. Cinema selling seats in Bath to students and
lecturers who have distinct reservations prices
and elasticities of demand from each other
88Figure 24a Third-Degree Price Discrimination
p p p
LMC
ARB
AR
MR
MRB
ARA
MRA
0
0
0
Market A Market B Market A B
Lecturers Students
89IV. Monopoly
- Assume first that price-discrimination is illegal
- The cinema will maximise profit by setting
(aggregate) MR LMC - Thus, sells seats in total at
a common price of - to lecturers and to students
90Figure 24b Third-Degree Price Discrimination
p p p
LMC
AR
ARB
MRB
MR
ARA
MRA
0
0
0
Market A Market B Market A B
Lecturers Students
91IV. Monopoly
- Assume now that price discrimination is legal
- Setting a common price implies that MRA ? MRB
- Thus, the monopolist can increase its revenue
(and since production costs are independent of
the market supplied, its profit) by transferring
Q from the low MR market to the high MR market
92Figure 24c Third-Degree Price Discrimination
p p p
LMC
ARB
AR
MR
MRB
ARA
MRA
0
0
0
Market A Market B Market A B
Lecturers Students
93IV. Monopoly
- As Q is withdrawn from the low MR market, p and
MR in that market rise - And vice versa, as Q is transferred to the high
MR market, p and MR in that market fall profit
is maximised when MRA MRB
94Figure 24d Third-Degree Price Discrimination
p p p
LMC
AR
ARB
MRB
ARB
MR
MRA
0
0
0
Market A Market B Market A B
Lecturers Students
95IV. Monopoly
- Intuitively, lecturers have relatively inelastic
demand, thus it is optimal to raise the price
they face, since relatively little demand is lost - Conversely, students have relatively elastic
demand, thus it is optimal to lower the price
they face since demand increases substantially
96IV. Monopoly
97IV. Monopoly
- Recall
- Thus
- If MRA MRB, but EA lt EB, then pA gt pB
98IV. Monopoly
- For all this to work
- Group making up sub-markets must have distinct
elasticities of demand - Third-degree price discrimination must be legal
- There must be no arbitrage between the groups
(i.e. usually used in service industries)
99IV. Monopoly
- Finally
- Note that the monopolist does not have a supply
curve - No one-to-one mapping between price and quantity
supplied
100Figure 23 Monopolist does not have a supply curve
p
LMC
E0
E1
p0
AR1
MR1
AR0
MR0
Q
0
Q0 Q1