Title: Sport Obermeyer Case
1Sport Obermeyer Case
- John H. Vande Vate
- Spring, 2006
2Issues
- Question What are the issues driving this case?
- How to measure demand uncertainty from disparate
forecasts - How to allocate production between the factories
in Hong Kong and China - How much of each product to make in each factory
3Describe the Challenge
- Long lead times
- Its November 92 and the company is starting to
make firm commitments for its 93 94 season. - Little or no feedback from market
- First real signal at Vegas trade show in March
- Inaccurate forecasts
- Deep discounts
- Lost sales
4Production Options
- Hong Kong
- More expensive
- Smaller lot sizes
- Faster
- More flexible
- Mainland (Guangdong, Lo Village)
- Cheaper
- Larger lot sizes
- Slower
- Less flexible
5The Product
- 5 Genders
- Price
- Type of skier
- Fashion quotient
- Example (Adult man)
- Fred (conservative, basic)
- Rex (rich, latest fabrics and technologies)
- Beige (hard core mountaineer, no-nonsense)
- Klausie (showy, latest fashions)
6The Product
- Gender
- Styles
- Colors
- Sizes
- Total Number of SKUs 800
7Service
- Deliver matching collections simultaneously
- Deliver early in the season
8The Process
- Design (February 92)
- Prototypes (July 92)
- Final Designs (September 92)
- Sample Production, Fabric Component orders
(50) - Cut Sew begins (February, 93)
- Las Vegas show (March, 93 80 of orders)
- SO places final orders with OL
- OL places orders for components
- Alpine Subcons Cut Sew
- Transport to Seattle (June July)
- Retailers want full delivery prior to start of
season (early September 93) - Replenishment orders from Retailers
Quotas!
9Quotas
- Force delivery earlier in the season
- Last man loses.
10The Critical Path of the SC
- Contract for Greige
- Production Plans set
- Dying and printing
- YKK Zippers
11Driving Issues
- Question What are the issues driving this case?
- How to measure demand uncertainty from disparate
forecasts - How to allocate production between the factories
in Hong Kong and China - How much of each product to make in each factory
- How are these questions related?
12Production Planning Example
- Rococo Parka
- Wholesale price 112.50
- Average profit 24112.50 27
- Average loss 8112.50 9
13Sample Problem
14Recall the Newsvendor
- Ignoring all other constraints recommended target
stock out probability is - 1-Profit/(Profit Risk)
- 8/(248) 25
15Ignoring Constraints
Everyone has a 25 chance of stockout Everyone
orders Mean 0.6745s
P .75 from .24/(.24.08) Probability of being
less than Mean 0.6745s is 0.75
16Constraints
- Make at least 10,000 units in initial phase
- Minimum Order Quantities
17Objective for the first 10K
- First Order criteria
- Return on Investment
- Second Order criteria
- Standard Deviation in Return
- Worry about First Order first
Expected Profit Invested Capital
18First Order Objective
Expected Profit Invested Capital
- Maximize t
- Can we exceed return t?
- Is
- L(t) Max Expected Profit - tInvested Capital
gt 0?
19First Order Objective
- Initially Ignore the prices we pay
- Treat every unit as though it costs Sport
Obermeyer 1 - Maximize l
- Can we achieve return l?
- L(l) Max Expected Profit - lS Qi gt 0?
Expected Profit Number of Units Produced
20Solving for Qi
- For l fixed, how to solve
- L(l) Maximize S Expected Profit(Qi) - l S Qi
- s.t. Qi ? 0
- Note it is separable (separate decision each Q)
- Exactly the same thinking!
- Last item
- Profit ProfitProbability Demand exceeds Q
- Risk Loss Probability Demand falls below Q
- l?
- Set P (Profit l)/(Profit Risk)
- 0.75 l/(Profit Risk)
Error here let p be the wholesale price,
Profit 0.24p Risk 0.08p P (0.24p
l)/(0.24p 0.08p) 0.75 - l/(.32p)
21Solving for Qi
- Last item
- Profit ProfitProbability Demand exceeds Q
- RiskRisk Probability Demand falls below Q
- Also pay l for each item
- Balance the two sides
- Profit(1-P) l RiskP
- Profit l (Profit Risk)P
- So P (Profit l)/(Profit Risk)
- In our case Profit 24, Risk 8 so
- P .75 l/(.32Wholesale Price)
- How does the order quantity Q change with l?
Error This was omitted. It is not needed later
when we calculate cost as, for example,
53.4Wholesale price, because it factors out of
everything.
22Q as a function of l
Doh! As we demand a higher return, we can
accept less and less risk that the item wont
sell. So, We make less and less.
Q
l
23Lets Try It
Min Order Quantities!
Adding the Wholesale price brings returns in line
with expectations if we can make 26.40 24 of
110 on a 1 investment, thats a 2640 return
24And Minimum Order Quantities
- Maximize S Expected Profit(Qi) - l SQi
- Mzi ? Qi ? 600zi (M is a big number)
- zi binary (do we order this or not)
If zi 1 we order at least 600
If zi 0 we order 0
25Solving for Qs
- Li(l) Maximize Expected Profit(Qi) - lQi
- s.t. Mzi ? Qi ? 600zi
- zi binary
- Two answers to consider
- zi 0 then Li(l) 0
- zi 1 then Qi is easy to calculate
- It is just the larger of 600 and the Q that gives
P (profit - l)/(profit risk) (call it Q) - Which is larger Expected Profit(Q) lQ or 0?
- Find the largest l for which this is positive.
For - l greater than this, Q is 0.
26Solving for Qs
- Li(l) Maximize Expected Profit(Qi) - lQi
- s.t. Mzi ? Qi ? 600zi
- zi binary
- Lets first look at the problem with zi 1
- Li(l) Maximize Expected Profit(Qi) - lQi
- s.t. Qi ? 600
- How does Qi change with l?
27Adding a Lower Bound
Q
l
28Objective Function
- How does Objective Function change with l?
- Li(l) Maximize Expected Profit(Qi) lQi
- We know Expected Profit(Qi) is concave
As l increases, Q decreases and so does the
Expected Profit
When Q hits its lower bound, it remains there.
After that Li(l) decreases linearly
29The Relationships
Capital Charge Expected Profit
Q reaches minimum
Past here, Q 0
l/110
30Solving for zi
- Li(l) Maximize Expected Profit(Qi) - lQi
- s.t. Mzi ? Qi ? 600zi
- zi binary
- If zi is 0, the objective is 0
- If zi is 1, the objective is
- Expected Profit(Qi) - lQi
- So, if Expected Profit(Qi) lQi gt 0, zi is 1
- Once Q reaches its lower bound, Li(l) decreases,
when it reaches 0, zi changes to 0 and remains 0
31Answers
Error That resolves the question of why we got a
higher return in China with no cost differences!
Hong Kong
China
32First Order Objective With Prices
- It makes sense that l, the desired rate of return
on capital at risk, should get very high, e.g.,
1240, before we would drop a product completely.
The 1 investment per unit we used is
ridiculously low. For Seduced, that 1 promises
2473 17.52 in profit (if it sells). That
would be a 1752 return! - Lets use more realistic cost information.
33First Order Objective With Prices
Expected Profit S ciQi
- Maximize l
- Can we achieve return l?
- L(l) Max Expected Profit - lSciQi gt 0?
- What goes into ci ?
- Consider Rococo example
- Cost is 60.08 on Wholesale Price of 112.50 or
53.4 of Wholesale Price. For simplicity, lets
assume ci 53.4 of Wholesale Price for
everything from HK and 46.15 from PRC
34Return on Capital
If everything is made in one place, where would
you make it?
Hong Kong
China
35Gail
Make it in China
Expected Profit above Target Rate of Return
Make it in Hong Kong
Stop Making It.
Target Rate of Return
36What Conclusions?
- There is a point beyond which the smaller minimum
quantities in Hong Kong yield a higher return
even though the unit cost is higher. This is
because we dont have to pay for larger
quantities required in China and those extra
units are less likely to sell. - Calculate the return of indifference (when
there is one) style by style. - Only produce in Hong Kong beyond this limit.
37Where to Make What?
That little cleverness was worth 2
Not a big deal. Make Gail in HK at minimum
38What Else?
- Kais point about making an amount now that
leaves less than the minimum order quantity for
later - Secondary measure of risk, e.g., the variance or
std deviation in Profit.